Skip to main content
Log in

Pricing of Loan Commitments for Facilitating Stochastic Liquidity Needs

  • Published:
Journal of Financial Services Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A bank loan commitment is often priced as a European-style put option that is used by a company with a known borrowing need on a known future date to lock in an interest rate. The literature has abstracted some of the important institutional features of a loan commitment contract. First, the timing, number, and size of the loan takedowns under such a contract are often random, rather than fixed. Second, companies often use loan commitment contracts to reduce the transaction costs of frequent borrowing and to serve as a guarantee for large and immediate random liquidity needs. Third, commercial banks maintain liquidity reserves for making random spot loans or random committed loans. Partial loan takedowns raise, rather than lower, the opportunity cost of a committed bank’s holding of excess capacity. This paper introduces a “stochastic needs-based” pricing model that incorporates these features. Simulations are conducted to illustrate the effects of various parameters on the fair price of a loan commitment.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Shockley and Thakor (1997) have classified the usage of committed bank loans into seven categories, namely, “commercial paper backup,” “liquidity,” “capital structure,” “general corporate purposes,” “takeover,” “leveraged buyout,” and “debtor-in-possession.”

  2. Recently, Agarwal et al. (2006) argue that a primary advantage of credit lines over term spot loans is that credit lines provide borrowers with financial flexibility. Sufi (2009) has refocused on the role of bank lines of credit as an instrumental component of corporate liquidity management. He suggests that according to Kashyap et al. (2002) and Gatev and Strahan (2006), banks are the most efficient liquidity providers in the economy, which implies that firms should rely on lines of credit over internal cash. However, there is a lack of interaction between the literature on cash and lines of credit for a bank’s liquidity provision.

  3. In practice, many loan commitment contracts have upfront commitment fees and/or usage fees on any undrawn portion of the committed loan that may serve to offset at least partly the costs of holding idle reserves.

  4. THG’s pricing model, on the contrary, takes into account a possible change in the credit risk of the borrower within the loan commitment period. Even though the credit risk of a spot loan is the same as that of a loan commitment contract at contract inception, it may differ significantly from that of a commitment loan when the contract is executed during the commitment period. Assumption (A2) holds only if a borrower’s credit risk does not change significantly during the loan commitment period.

  5. More precisely, if r(0) > 0 and 2 αm ≥ σ 2, then r(t) > 0 for all t ∈ (0,T], where σ is the standard deviation of Brownian motion Z(t). Non-negativity is often regarded as a desirable property for interest rate processes.

  6. Readers may consult Duan et al.’s (1995) article for a more detailed derivation of the non-liquid asset process. Duan et al. and others do not distinguish between liquid and non-liquid assets. In this paper, non-liquid assets involve long-term investments and, therefore, can be evaluated using the standard martingale pricing theory.

  7. A simple discussion of the integration of such a stochastic differential equation is provided by Øksendal (2003).

  8. In practice, a committed bank will hold a certain level of reserve and may rely on the interbank market occasionally. A committed bank that relies on the interbank market for obtaining liquidity when a committed bank loan is executed faces the risk of interbank borrowing rate fluctuation. On the other hand, there is an opportunity cost for holding idle liquidity reserve. The balance between holding a liquidity reserve and relying on the interbank market depends on the risk attitude and other operational characteristics of the committed bank. Taking such optimal behavior into account would introduce too much complication to the model.

  9. Interested readers may obtain the program from the author on request. The Java Development Kit required for running the program can be downloaded from Sun Microsystem’s website at http://www.sun.com.

  10. The random number generator Java program RngStream.java written by L’ecuyer et al. (2002) is available at http://www.iro.umontreal.ca/~lecuyer/myftp/streams00/java/RngStream.java. Accessed July 15, 2009.

  11. The patterns in the loan commitment charges are similar for loan commitments used for general corporate operations.

References

  • Agarwal S, Ambose BW, Liu C (2006) Credit lines and credit utilization. J Money, Credit Bank 38:1–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartter BJ, Rendleman RJ Jr (1979) Fee-based pricing of fixed rate bank loan commitments. Financ Manage 8:13–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger AN, Bouwman CHS (2009) Bank liquidity creation. Rev Financ Stud 22:3779–3837

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boot AWA, Thakor AV (1991) Off-balance sheet liabilities deposit insurance and capital regulation. J Bank Financ 15:825–846

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell TS (1978) A model of the market for lines of credit. J Finance 33:231–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chavez-Demoulin V, Embrechts P, Neslehova J (2006) Quantitative models of operational risk: extremes, dependence, and aggregation. J Bank Financ 30:2635–2658

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox JC, Ingersoll JE Jr, Ross SA (1981) A re-examination of traditional hypotheses about the term structure of interest rates. J Finance 36:769–799

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox JC, Ingersoll JE Jr, Ross SA (1985) The term structure of interest rate. Econometrica 53:363–384

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duan JC, Simonato JG (1999) Estimating and testing exponential-affine term structure models by Kalman filter. Rev Quant Financ Account 13:111–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duan JC, Yu MT (2005) Fair insurance guaranty premia in the presence of risk-based capital regulations, stochastic interest rate and catastrophe risk. J Bank Financ 29:2435–2454

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duan JC, Moreau A, Sealey CW (1995) Deposit insurance and bank interest rate risk: pricing and regulatory implications. J Bank Financ 19:1091–1108

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ergungor OE (2001) Theories of bank loan commitments. Econ Rev (Fed Reserve Bank Clevel) 37:2–19

    Google Scholar 

  • Faleye O (2004) Cash and corporate control. J Finance 59:2041–2060

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frenkel J, Jovanovic B (1980) On transactions and precautionary demand for money. Q J Econ 95:25–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fullbright, Jaworski LLP (2007) 2007 Litigation trends survey. Prepared by Greenwood Marketing Inc. Available via http://fulbright.com/index.cfm?fuseaction=correspondence.LitTrends07. Accessed 15 July 2009

  • Gatev E, Strahan P (2006) Banks advantage in hedging liquidity risk: theory and evidence from the commercial paper market. J Finance 61:867–892

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glasserman P (2004) Monte Carlo methods in financial engineering. Springer Science + Business Media Inc.

  • Greenbaum SI, Venezia I (1985) Partial exercise of loan commitments under adaptive pricing. J Financ Res 8:251–263

    Google Scholar 

  • Kashyap A, Rajan R, Stein J (2002) Banks as liquidity providers: an explanation for the co-existence of lending and deposit-taking. J Finance 57:33–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lang LHP, Stulz RM, Walkling RA (1991) A test of the free cash flow hypothesis—the case of bidder returns. J Financ Econ 29:315–335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • L’ecuyer P (1999) Good parameters and implementations for combined multiple recursive random number generators. Oper Res 47:159–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • L’ecuyer P, Simard R, Chen EJ, Kelton WD (2002) An object-oriented random-number package with many long streams and substreams. Oper Res 50:1073–1075

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin XS, Pavlova KP (2006) The Compound Poisson Risk Model with a Threshold Dividend Strategy. Insur Math Econ 38:57–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melnik A, Plaut SE (1986) The economics of loan commitment contracts: credit pricing and utilization. J Bank Financ 10:267–280

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton RC (1973) An intertemporal capital asset pricing mode. Econometrica 41:867–887

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton RC (1976) Option pricing when underlying stock returns are discontinuous. J Financ Econ 3:125–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Øksendal B (2003) Stochastic differential equations—an introduction with applications, 6th edn. Springer, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Santomero AM, Babbel DF (1997) Financial risk management by insurers: an analysis of the process. J Risk Insur 64:231–270

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scott LO (1996) Simulating a multi-factor term structure model over relatively long discrete tie periods. In: Proceedings of the IAFE first annual computational finance conference, Graduate School of Business, Stanford University

  • Smith GW (1986) A dynamic Baumol-Tobin model of money demand. Rev Econ Stud 53:465–469

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shockley RL (1995) Bank loan commitments and corporate leverage. J Financ Intermed 4:272–301

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shockley RL, Thakor AV (1997) Bank loan commitment contracts: data, theory and tests. J Money, Credit Bank 29:517–534

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sufi A (2009) Bank lines of credit in corporate finance: an empirical analysis. Rev Financ Stud 22:1057–1088

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sundt B, Teugels JL (1995) Ruin estimates under interest force. Insur Math Econ 16:7–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thakor AV (2005) Do loan commitments cause overlending? J Money, Credit Bank 37:1067–1099

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thakor AV, Udell GF (1987) Competition, risk neutrality and loan commitments. J Bank Financ 11:449–471

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thakor AV, Hong H, Greenbaum SI (1981) Bank loan commitments and interest rate volatility. J Bank Financ 5:497–510

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • US GAO (2005) Loan commitments—issues related to pricing, trading, and accounting. United States government accountability office report to agency officials. Available via http://www.gao.gov/new.items/d05131.pdf. Accessed 15 July 2009)

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Arthur Hau.

Additional information

The author is Associate Professor of the Department of Finance and Insurance at Lingnan University. Financial support from the University Research Grants and the Academic Programme Research Grants of Lingnan University is highly appreciated. The author would like to thank an anonymous referee for providing valuable suggestions that have led to significant improvements in the paper. All errors belong to the author.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Hau, A. Pricing of Loan Commitments for Facilitating Stochastic Liquidity Needs. J Financ Serv Res 39, 71–94 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10693-010-0083-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10693-010-0083-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation