Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The impact of taxes and wasteful government spending on giving

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Experimental Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We examine how taxes impact charitable giving and how this relationship is affected by the degree of wasteful government spending. In our model, individuals make donations to charities knowing that the government collects a flat-rate tax on income (net of charitable donations) and redistributes part of the tax revenue. The rest of the tax revenue is wasted. The model predicts that a higher tax rate increases charitable donations. Surprisingly, the model shows that a higher degree of waste decreases donations (when the elasticity of marginal utility with respect to consumption is high enough). We test the model’s predictions using a laboratory experiment with actual donations to charities and find that the tax rate has an insignificant effect on giving. The degree of waste, however, has a large, negative and highly significant effect on giving.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See http://www.gallup.com/poll/176102/americans-say-federal-gov-wastes-cents-dollar.aspx. The estimated rate of waste differs across Republicans and Democrats, with Republicans estimating 59 cents and Democrats estimating 42 cents per dollar. To isolate the effect of waste on giving, we consider a simple model with individuals being homogeneous with respect to their perceptions of the rate of waste.

  2. See http://www.huffingtonpost.com/2013/03/18/wasteful-spending-poll_n_2886081.html. Based on the survey responses the article argues that “for many, waste is indeed defined as ‘money spent on some government program I don’t like’.” Note that these perceptions may exogenously change over time depending on government actions or even through simple debates (e.g., discussions of wasteful government spending during elections may heighten individuals’ perceptions about waste).

  3. To our knowledge, previous theoretical and empirical models on the impact of tax rates on donations assume one of the two extreme cases. For example, when calculating the price of giving, empirical studies typically make the simplifying assumption that individuals do not receive any return from their paid taxes. Previous models are, therefore, special cases of our model.

  4. Field data suffer from measurement and identification challenges (e.g., Andreoni 2006; List 2011; Andreoni and Payne 2013; Vesterlund 2016; Duquette 2016). Itemizers have an incentive to overstate their donations to evade taxes, while non-itemizers have no incentive to report any donations at all. The price of giving is correlated with taxable income and might endogenously change with the donated amount. It is hard to disentangle the permanent impact of taxes on donations from the transitory impact. Wasteful government spending may provoke tax evasion which might in turn affect charitable donations (Barone and Mocetti 2011; Alm et al. 2016). There is also the possibility that tax rates affect labor supply decisions; see Saez et al. (2012) for a survey of this literature. Our design eliminates these types of measurement and identification challenges by: (1) exogenously varying the price of giving and the level of waste, (2) using actual donations data from our controlled laboratory experiment, (3) automatically taxing all participants in the experiment and (4) by assigning income to participants prior to informing them about the specifics of income taxation and the tax rate.

  5. Our paper also contributes to the literature on income inequality and public goods provision (e.g., Chan et al. 1996, 1999; Anderson et al. 2008; Uler 2011; Maurice et al. 2013; Duquette and Hargaden 2019). We find qualitative support for the neutrality result of Bergstrom et al. (1986).

  6. These predictions follow immediately from the crowding-out literature (e.g., Andreoni 1993; Bolton and Katok 1998; Eckel et al. 2005; Li et al. 2011), since this case implies governmental provision and charitable provision are perfect substitutes.

  7. One important example of public goods in which individuals make donations, but the government does not, is giving to religious organizations.

  8. See Sect. 2 for a discussion of the major findings of the empirical literature on this topic.

  9. Some of these papers study a related (but different) question. They ask, for a given tax rate, how responsive total giving is to tax-deductibility and focus on estimates of price-elasticity only. Theoretically, it is easy to show that the impact of tax-deductibility on donations is (unambiguously) positive, since tax-deductions make it cheaper to donate and individuals enjoy higher levels of spendable income for a given level of donation. In other words, there are no opposing forces when it comes to the effect of tax-deductibility on donations.

  10. This result would not hold if individuals are impure-altruists (Andreoni 1990). Impure altruism models explain why crowding-out is not complete when government provides public funds to charities. Interestingly, Hungerman (2014) shows that when individuals hide income, this creates a deadweight loss and leads to a surprising finding: warm-glow implies more crowding-out in a setting where individuals can evade taxes.

  11. Andreoni and Vesterlund (2001) focus on gender differences in altruism and show that men are more price sensitive. Andreoni and Miller (2002) show that preferences for altruism can be explained by rational models.

  12. They also find that subjects are sensitive to how a subsidy is framed. Other studies comparing subsidy types include Davis et al. (2005), Davis and Millner (2005), Eckel and Grossman (2006a, b) and Blumenthal et al. (2012).

  13. Duquette and Hargaden (2019), on the other hand, find a positive relationship between the match rate and donations even for very large values of the match rate.

  14. Auten et al. (2000) argue that the relationship between income and donations is U-shaped.

  15. Theoretically, assuming a concave consumption utility, when considering rebates or matches offered by a third party, an increase in the rebate or match rate always leads to higher total donations received by the charity (including the matches). To see why increasing the rebate/match rate does not lead to ambiguous effects on donations received by the charity the way increasing the rate of tax or waste does, consider the following examples. When the rebate (or match) rate increases, an individual might still choose to donate nothing and consume his/her available wealth. When a tax rate increases, however, the individual’s net income strictly decreases even when he/she does not donate anything to the charity. Alternatively, when the rebate (or match rate) increases, an individual can donate the same (total) level as before and enjoy a higher net income. In contrast, when the tax rate increases, if the individual donates the same level as before, then he/she will definitely have a lower net income.

  16. One can think of the “waste” as either the government funding programs that the individuals do not care for, or inefficient spending.

  17. Similar to Bergstrom et al. (1986), this result holds only when the set of contributors does not change as the initial income distribution changes. If the set of contributors changes when the initial income distribution changes, then the model would predict higher contributions when income inequality increases. Hence, similar to Bergstrom et al. (1986) and Uler (2009), there is a trade-off between contributions and (initial) income equality.

  18. This can be seen by using Eq. (1) and the fact that each individual consumes the same amount of the private good.

  19. Note that \(\frac{{u^{{\prime \prime }} \left( x \right)x}}{{u^{{\prime }} \left( x \right)}} = \frac{{\frac{{du^{{\prime }} \left( x \right)}}{dx}x}}{{u^{{\prime }} \left( x \right)}} = \frac{{\frac{{du^{{\prime }} \left( x \right)}}{{u^{{\prime }} \left( x \right)}}}}{{\frac{dx}{x}}}\). The elasticity of marginal utility with respect to consumption can also be interpreted as the sensitivity of the marginal rate of substitution between private consumption and public good consumption to price changes: the derivative of the marginal rate of substitution with respect to the price of private consumption (see Mirrlees 1971). We are grateful to Daniel Hungerman for this insight.

  20. For example, if \(\frac{\partial G}{\partial t} = 0\) and \(\frac{\partial G}{\partial w} = - 4\), then the partial derivative of G with respect to t is greater than the partial derivative of G with respect to w in the relative sense.

  21. In the experiment, we have three people in our experimental society. If this condition does not hold for \(n = 3\), then we do not expect it to hold with \(n > 3\).

  22. Note that \(\frac{1}{n} \le \frac{{\left( {1 - wt} \right)}}{{\left( {1 - at} \right)n}} < 1\) for any \(0 \le w \le 1\), and \(0 \le t \le 1\). \(\frac{{\left( {1 - wt} \right)}}{{\left( {1 - at} \right)n}}\) equals \(\frac{1}{n}\) when \(w = 1\).

  23. We assume individual \(i\)’s utility function is given by: \(\frac{{c_{i}^{1 - \theta } }}{1 - \theta } + \frac{{g_{i}^{1 - \theta } }}{1 - \theta }\) for \(0 < \theta \ne 1\) and \(\ln \left( {c_{i} } \right) + { \ln }\left( {g_{i} } \right)\) for \(\theta = 1\). We find that total public goods provision, \(G\), is equal to \(\frac{{\left( {1 - wt} \right)Y}}{{(1 - at)^{{\frac{1}{\theta }}} + \left( {1 - wt} \right)}}\). It is not difficult to calculate \(\frac{\partial G}{\partial t}\) and \(\frac{\partial G}{\partial w}\), and confirm that all of our results continue to hold. Future research could generalize our findings beyond a CRRA formulation.

  24. Our main results do not change when we allow for non-contributors. In particular, the sufficient conditions provided in Theorems 13 stay the same. For example, take Theorem 1. Under the sufficient condition provided in Theorem 1, for a given degree of waste, it is possible to show that (1) as t increases, the set of contributors (weakly) increases and (2) \(\frac{\partial G}{\partial t} > 0\) for any t. Similarly, all of our corollaries continue to hold. The only adjustment that needs to be done is for Theorem 4. While the threshold provided in Theorem 4 becomes larger when we allow for non-contributors, it can be shown that it is still strictly less than 1. In addition, it is not difficult to show that, for a given rate of tax, (1) as w increases, the set of contributors (weakly) decreases, and (2) \(\frac{\partial G}{\partial w} < 0\) for any \(w\).

  25. This can be easily seen from Eq. (1) and the fact that, in equilibrium, all individuals enjoy the same net consumption. In the case of corner solutions, total donations and average individual donations move in the same direction.

  26. Recall that the condition provided in Theorem 1 is very mild and that only three percent of subjects did not satisfy this condition.

  27. When the parameters of our experiment are used, \(\frac{{\left( {1 - wt} \right)}}{{\left( {1 - at} \right)n}}\) varies between 0.33 and 0.67. Therefore, if \(\theta > 0.67\), then giving is a strictly decreasing function of w. If \(0.33 < \theta < 0.67,\) then giving may sometimes increase and sometimes decrease depending on the parameters (see Tables C.1 and C.2 in Appendix C).

  28. See Selten and Ockenfels (1998) and Charness and Grosskopf (2001) for a review of this literature.

  29. The elasticity of marginal utility with respect to consumption may not be captured by the estimated relative risk aversion coefficient from the lottery task if agents are not expected utility maximizers or if the risk elicitation task used in the study does not correctly capture risk preferences. Nevertheless, in the absence of a better tool to capture the elasticity coefficient, approximating the curvature of the consumption utility based on our risk elicitation task allows us to test the model in a stronger fashion. Since, in our experiment, donation decisions and risk elicitation tasks are performed under very similar conditions (including payoff levels for a given subject), it is not unreasonable for the behavior in the risk elicitation task to shed light on subjects’ behavior regarding donation decisions.

  30. Specifically, participants were told that the amount earned “may be the same for everyone in this room, or each participant’s earnings may depend on their relative performance in the test.” We used this language to facilitate comparison between our two treatments: Equal versus Unequal. In addition, before the experiment started, subjects were told that they may lose part of the money they earn in part 1. They received explicit instructions for part 2 after they finished part 1 (see Appendix B).

  31. We used the following charities: American Cancer Society, American Red Cross, Doctors Without Borders, Feeding America, Food for the Poor, and Save the Children.

  32. Participants were told that, if requested, they would receive a confirmation email from the charity to verify that the experimenters sent their donations to the charity.

  33. As an alternative design, we could have used the collected money to fund a cause that would be perceived as wasteful by most subjects. Due to the difficulty of identifying a cause that would simultaneously be perceived as wasteful by subjects, while also not being a waste of limited research funds, we chose to avoid this alternative design.

  34. Tables C1 and C2 in Appendix C give theoretical predictions of giving for each t and w assuming specific utility functions.

  35. Seven participants (3 in the Equal and 4 in the Unequal treatment) received a score of zero in part 1. These subjects might have failed to submit their answers on time or simply chose not to work on the task. Our results are robust to inclusion or exclusion of these 7 participants and are available upon request from the authors.

  36. We choose to present Tobit regression analyses in the main text, since roughly half of the participants gave $0. Our qualitative results are robust to using OLS regressions (see Appendix D).

  37. Appendix D also provides an analysis of heterogeneity among individuals.

  38. The neutrality result relies on the assumption that the set of contributors stays the same as income inequality increases. Otherwise, Bergstrom et al. (1986), as well as our model, predict that total giving increases as initial income inequality increases. Therefore, a stronger test of neutrality result requires to have a within-subject variation of income (see Duquette and Hargaden 2019), but since this is not the main aim of the paper, our research design does not incorporate such variation.

  39. One participant in our experiment has missing data after part 2 due to health reasons. Therefore, when we add variables from parts 3 and 4 and the questionnaires to the regression analysis, this participant gets automatically dropped from the regression analysis.

  40. The negative impact of w on giving is robust to including the subjects with seven safe choices.

  41. As a robustness check (not shown here for brevity), we have repeated our analysis by eliminating the 14 subjects that made less than six safe choices. Our qualitative results do not change.

  42. We thank Charles Noussair, who suggested that studying repeated decisions with feedback is essential to understanding whether the failure of donations to respond to the tax rate is a transitory phenomenon that would go away with better comprehension of the task or whether it is a durable and solid pattern of behavior.

  43. Hence, we can effectively control for order effects and guarantee that the level of experience and different tax rates cannot be correlated.

  44. Note that there are 30 independent groups.

  45. To isolate the effects of tax and waste on donations, our paper focuses on the demand side of giving. A related literature studies the factors that affect the supply side (e.g., Krasteva and Yildirim 2016). Future research could incorporate how the supply side might also be affected from changes in the tax rate and the rate of waste.

  46. For each income distribution, we have run regressions (both Tobit and OLS) to study whether the impact of tax rate on donations is statistically significant when \(w = 1\). None of the regressions show a statistically significant effect of tax rate on donations at a 5% significance level. When the data from different income distributions are pooled, then a significant impact can be seen when using an OLS regression (p value = 0.04), but not when using a Tobit regression (p value = 0.79).

  47. Our experiment was not designed to differentiate between these alternative explanations. Future research could address this research question.

References

  • Alm, J., Martinez-Vazquez, J., & McClellan, C. (2016). Corruption and firm tax evasion. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 124, 146–163.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, L. R., Mellor, J. M., & Milyo, J. (2008). Inequality and public good provision: An experimental analysis. The Journal of Socio-Economics, 37(3), 1010–1028.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J. (1989). Giving with impure altruism: Application to charity and ricardian equivalence. The Journal of Political Economy, 97, 1447–1458.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J. (1990). Impure altruism and donations to public goods: A theory of warm-glow giving. Economic Journal, 100, 464–477.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J. (1993). An experimental test of public-goods crowding out hypothesis. American Economic Review, 83, 1317–1327.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J. (2006). Philanthropy: Handbook of giving, reciprocity and altruism (pp. 1201–1269). Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J., & Miller, J. (2002). Giving according to GARP: An experimental test of the consistency of preferences for altruism. Econometrica, 70, 737–753.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J., & Payne, A. (2013). Charitable giving. In A. Auerbach, R. Chetty, M. Feldstein, & E. Saez (Eds.), Handbook of public economics (pp. 1–50). Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J., & Vesterlund, L. (2001). Which is the fair sex? Gender differences in altruism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116, 293–312.

    Google Scholar 

  • Auten, G. E., Clotfelter, C., & Schmalbeck, R. L. (2000). Taxes and philanthropy among the wealthy. In J. Slemrod (Ed.), Does atlas shrug? The economic consequences of taxing the rich (pp. 392–424). New York: Russell Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Auten, G. E., Sieg, H., & Clotfelter, C. T. (2002). Charitable giving, income, and taxes: An analysis of panel data. American Economic Review, 92, 371–382.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bakija, J., & Heim, B. (2011). How does charitable giving respond to incentives and income? New estimates from panel data. National Tax Journal, 64, 615–650.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barone, G., & Mocetti, S. (2011). Tax morale and public spending inefficiency. International Tax and Public Finance, 18, 724–749.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrom, T., Blume, L., & Varian, H. (1986). On the private provision of public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 29, 25–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blumenthal, M., Kalambokidis, L., & Turk, A. (2012). Subsidizing charitable contributions with a match instead of a deduction: What happens to donations and compliance? National Tax Journal, 65, 91–116.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, G., & Katok, E. (1998). An experimental test of the crowding out hypothesis: The nature of beneficent behavior. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 37, 315–331.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buckley, E., & Croson, R. (2006). Income and wealth heterogeneity in the voluntary provision of linear public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 90, 935–955.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chan, K. S., Mestelman, S., Moir, R., & Muller, R. A. (1996). The voluntary provision of public goods under varying income distributions. Canadian Journal of Economics, 29, 54–69.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chan, K. S., Mestelman, S., Moir, R., & Muller, R. A. (1999). Heterogeneity and the voluntary provision of public goods. Experimental Economics, 2, 5–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Charness, G., & Grosskopf, B. (2001). Relative payoffs and happiness: An experimental study. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 45, 301–328.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clotfelter, C. T. (1985). Federal tax policy and charitable giving. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clotfelter, C. T. (1990). The impact of tax reform on charitable giving: A 1989 perspective. In J. Slemrod (Ed.), Do taxes matter (pp. 203–235). Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, D. D., & Millner, E. L. (2005). Rebates and matches and consumer behavior. Southern Economic Journal, 72, 410–421.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, D. D., Millner, E. L., & Reilly, R. J. (2005). Subsidy schemes and charitable contributions: A closer look. Experimental Economics, 8, 85–106.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duquette, N. (2016). Do tax incentives affect charitable contributions? Evidence from public charities’ reported revenues. Journal of Public Economics, 137, 51–69.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duquette, N., & Hargaden, E. (2019). Inequality and giving. Working Paper.

  • Eckel, C. C., & Grossman, P. J. (2003). Rebate versus matching: Does how we subsidize charitable contributions matter? Journal of Public Economics, 87, 681–701.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eckel, C. C., & Grossman, P. J. (2006a). Do donors care about subsidy type? An experimental study. In D. Davis & M. Isaac (Eds.), Research in experimental economics (pp. 163–182). New York: JAI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eckel, C. C., & Grossman, P. J. (2006b). Subsidizing charitable giving with rebates or matching: Further laboratory evidence. Southern Economic Journal, 72, 794–807.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eckel, C. C., & Grossman, P. J. (2008). Subsidizing charitable contributions: A natural field experiment comparing matching and rebate subsidies. Experimental Economics, 11, 234–252.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eckel, C. C., Grossman, P. J., & Johnston, R. (2005). An experimental test of the crowding out hypothesis. Journal of Public Economics, 89, 1543–1560.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eckel, C. C., Grossman, P. J., & Milano, A. (2007). Is more information always better? An experimental study of charitable giving and hurricane Katrina. Southern Economic Journal, 74, 388–411.

    Google Scholar 

  • Erkal, N., Gangadharan, L., & Nikiforakis, N. (2011). Relative earnings and giving in a real-effort experiment. American Economic Review, 101, 3330–3348.

    Google Scholar 

  • Filiz-Ozbay, E., & Uler, N. (2019). Demand for giving to multiple charities: An experimental analysis. Journal of European Economic Association, 17, 725–753.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171–178.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greiner, B. (2015). Subject pool recruitment procedures: Organizing experiments with ORSEE. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1, 114–125.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huck, S., & Rasul, I. (2011). Matched fundraising: Evidence from a natural field experiment. Journal of Public Economics, 95, 351–362.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hungerman, D. (2014). Public goods, hidden income, and tax evasion: Some nonstandard results from the warm-glow model. Journal of Development Economics, 109, 188–202.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hungerman, D., & Ottoni-Wilhelm, M. (2018). Impure Impact giving: Theory and evidence. Working Paper.

  • Karlan, D., & List, J. A. (2007). Does price matter in charitable giving? Evidence from a large-scale natural field experiment. American Economic Review, 97, 1774–1793.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krasteva, S., & Yildirim, H. (2016). Information, competition and the quality of charities. Journal of Public Economics, 144, 64–77.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levitt, S. D., & List, J. A. (2007). What do laboratory experiments measuring social preferences reveal about the real world? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21, 153–174.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, S. X., Eckel, C. C., Grossman, P. J., & Brown, T. L. (2011). Giving to government: Voluntary taxation in the lab. Journal of Public Economics, 95, 1190–1201.

    Google Scholar 

  • List, J. (2011). The market for charitable giving. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25, 157–180.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maurice, J., Rouaix, A., & Willinger, M. (2013). Income redistribution and public good provision: An experiment. International Economic Review, 54, 957–975.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mirrlees, J. A. (1971). An exploration in the theory of optimal income taxation. Review of Economic Studies, 38, 175–208.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peloza, J., & Steel, P. (2005). The price elasticities of charitable contributions: A meta-analysis. Journal of Public Policy & Marketing, 24(2), 260–272.

    Google Scholar 

  • Randolph, W. (1995). Dynamic income, progressive taxes, and the timing of charitable contributions. Journal of Political Economy, 103, 709–738.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rey-Biel, P., Sheremeta, R. M., & Uler, N. (2018). When income depends on performance and luck: The effects of culture and information on giving. In A. Gunnthorsdottir, D. Norton, & D. V. Caprar (Eds.), Experimental economics and culture (pp. 167–203). Bingley: Emerald Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saez, E., Slemrod, J., & Giertz, S. H. (2012). The elasticity of taxable income with respect to marginal tax rates: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, 50, 3–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selten, R., & Ockenfels, A. (1998). An experimental solidarity game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 34, 517–539.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seltzer, N. (2009). 1,014 GRE practice questions. Princeton Review.

  • Silverman, D., Slemrod, J., & Uler, N. (2014). Distinguishing the role of authority “In” and authority “To”. Journal of Public Economics, 113, 32–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Uler, N. (2009). Public goods provision and redistributive taxation. Journal of Public Economics, 93, 440–453.

    Google Scholar 

  • Uler, N. (2011). Charitable giving, inequality, and taxes. Experimental Economics, 14, 287–306.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vesterlund, L. (2016). Voluntary giving to public goods: moving beyond the linear voluntary contribution mechanism. In John Kagel & Alvin Roth (Eds.), Handbook of experimental economics (Vol. 2). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Warr, P. G. (1983). The private provision of a public good is independent of the distribution of income. Economics Letters, 13, 207–211.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank two anonymous referees and the Editor of this journal for their valuable suggestions. We thank James Alm, Yan Chen, Rachel Croson, Emel Filiz-Ozbay, Enda Hargaden, Charles Holt, Rowell Huesmann, Daniel Hungerman, Steve Leider, John List, Charles Longfield, Yusufcan Masatlioglu, Yesim Orhun, Laura Razzolini, Anya Samek, Joel Slemrod, Nat Wilcox, seminar participants at the University of Chicago, the University of Michigan, the 2015 Economic Science Association Conference, and the 2015 Science of Philanthropy Initiative Annual Conference. We thank the John Templeton Foundation, the Science of Philanthropy Initiative, and the University of Maryland for financial support. Andrew Card, Yulia Chhabra, Juyeon Ha, Zedekiah Higgs, and Ethan McCall provided excellent research assistance. We also thank John Jensenius and Pak Ho Shen for their help with programming the experiment.

Funding

Funding was provided by Science of Philanthropy Initiative.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Neslihan Uler.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (PDF 420 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Sheremeta, R.M., Uler, N. The impact of taxes and wasteful government spending on giving. Exp Econ 24, 355–386 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-020-09673-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-020-09673-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation