Skip to main content
Log in

Preference Theory and Low Fertility: A Comparative Perspective

  • Published:
European Journal of Population / Revue européenne de Démographie Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The discussion on the causes of the most recent fertility decline in Europe, and in particular on the emergence of lowest-low fertility, emphasizes the relevance of cultural factors in addition to economic ones. As part of such a cultural framework, the heterogeneity of preferences concerning the “career vs. family” dichotomy has been systematized in the “Preference Theory” approach developed by Catherine Hakim. This heterogeneity in preferences, however, has so far been underinvestigated in a comparative framework. This paper makes use of comparative data from the 2004/2005 Round of the European Social Survey to test the links between individual-level preferences and both fertility outcomes and fertility intentions, in a variety of societal settings. Results confirm an association between work–family lifestyle preferences and realized fertility in a variety of European countries, while they do not show a relationship between lifestyle preferences and fertility intentions. Results further support the existence of heterogeneous patterns of association between lifestyle preferences and fertility choices among welfare regimes.

Résumé

Le débat portant sur les causes de la baisse la plus récente de la fécondité en Europe, et en particulier sur l’émergence des fécondités les plus basses met l’accent sur le rôle des facteurs culturels, par-delà les facteurs économiques. Dans le cadre de ces facteurs culturels, l’hétérogénéité des préférences en matière de dilemme «carrière ou famille» a été formalisé par Catherine Hakim sous la forme de la «théorie des préférences». Cette hétérogénéité des préférences a toutefois été peu explorée dans une perspective comparative. Cet article exploite les données comparatives de la vague 2004/2005 de l’Enquête Sociale Européenne pour tester les liens entre les préférences individuelles, d’une part, et la fécondité réelle et souhaitée, d’autre part, dans des contextes sociaux très divers. Les résultats confirment une association entre les préférences en matière de mode de vie par rapport au travail et à la famille et la fécondité réelle dans toute une série de pays européens, mais ne mettent pas en évidence de lien entre les préférences en matière de mode de vie et la fécondité souhaitée. De plus, les résultats confirment l’existence de schémas hétérogènes d’association entre les préférences en matière de modes de vie et les choix de fécondité dans les différents régimes d’Etat-providence.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. “The US, Britain and probably the Netherlands currently provide the prime examples of societies that have achieved the new scenario for women. […] Most European countries still have little or nothing to actively enforce equal opportunities legislation. […] For example, in Greece, Italy and Spain, there is evidence of informal barriers to women’s access to the labour market: female unemployment rates are more than double those of males […]. Within the European Union, only Britain, Ireland, and the Netherlands have a public body responsible for enforcing equal pay and equal opportunities laws” (Hakim 2003b, p. 360).

  2. The expression “female returners” refers to “women who seek to re-enter the work-force after a few years of unpaid care-taking responsibilities” (Doorewaard et al. 2004, p. 8).

  3. Edition 2.0, with data released on 8 March 2006. The original dataset includes all countries for which data have been deposited before 1 June 2005: Austria, Belgium, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, Germany, Greece, Luxembourg, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom, France, Hungary, Iceland, Ireland, Netherlands, Slovakia, Ukraine.

  4. The survey question used is the following: “People talk about the changing roles of husband and wife in the family. Here are three kinds of family. Which of them corresponds best with your ideas about the family?

    • A family where the two partners each have an equally demanding job and where housework and the care of the children are shared equally between them.

    • A family where the wife has a less demanding job than her husband and where she does the larger share of housework and caring for the children.

    • A family where only the husband has a job and the wife runs the home.

    • None of these three cases.”

  5. The survey question used is the following: “If without having to work you had what you would regard as a reasonable living income, would you still prefer to have a paid job, or wouldn’t you bother?”

  6. The survey question used is the following: “Who is the main income-earner in your household? Is it yourself? Your partner/spouse? Both of you jointly? Or someone else?”

  7. Forty respondents were classified both as family-oriented and as career-oriented. Actually, the questions used for classifying women are not mutually exclusive. Moreover, all the three questions used are opinion questions, so the answers could be driven by social norms rather than by the respondents' subjective ideals. For instance, while men usually define themselves as primary earners even when they are actually not, women sometimes answer in the opposite direction––cf. Hakim (2003b, p. 363) for a similar argument. For the remainder of this analysis, these cases will be excluded.

  8. Unfortunately, we could not consider Italy in this study, since Italian data were not comparable with other ESS-2 data.

  9. The question on fertility intentions is asked only to women aged 45 years or less. We also exclude from our analyses observations for which the relationship of the respondent with other household members is missing, when the respondent is not the only person in the household.

  10. A closer correspondence between fertility intentions and behaviours may be achieved when intentions refer to an explicit time interval (Miller and Pasta 1995).

  11. We found that the parallel regression assumption is not violated if the ordered logit models are run on the sub-sample of women with at least one child, thus suggesting that passing from parity zero to parity one is very different from experiencing other transitions, as shown in other studies (Testa and Grilli 2006). However, this solution implies a considerable reduction of the sample size and excludes from the analysis a significant proportion of work-oriented women who, according to Preference Theory, are frequently childless. We therefore decided to estimate generalized ordered models, which do not impose the constraints of parallel regression.

  12. This negative effect of being career oriented on fertility intentions in Britain becomes even higher if we run the same set of models only on the sub-sample of women living in a union, who—according to Hakim—should also have more clear life preferences. In other words, among married or cohabiting women, the consistency of the Preference Theory increases in the case of Britain, while the effect is lost in the case of Denmark. Results for these models are not shown because of the considerable reduction of the sample size they involve.

References

  • Aassve, A., Billari, F. C., & Piccarreta, R. (2007). Strings of adulthood: A sequence analysis of young British women’s work–family trajectories. European Journal of Population, 23, 369–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adsera, A. (2005). Where are the babies? Labour market conditions and fertility in Europe. IZA Discussion Paper 1576.

  • Ahn, N., & Mira, P. (2002). A note on the changing relationship between fertility and female employment rates in developed countries. Journal of Population Economics, 15, 667–682.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beets, G., Liefbroer, A. C., & de Gierveld, G. Jong. (1999). Changes in fertility values and behaviour: A life course perspective. In R. Leete (Ed.), Dynamics of values in fertility change (pp. 100–120). Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Butz, W. P., & Ward, M. P. (1979). The emergence of countercyclical U.S. fertility. American Economic Review, 69, 318–328.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caldwell, J. C., & Schindlmayr, T. (2003). Explanations of the fertility crisis in modern societies: A search for commonalities. Population Studies, 57(3), 77–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castles, F. G. (2003). The world turned upside down: Below replacement fertility, changing preferences and family–friendly public policy in 21 OECD countries. Journal of European Social Policy, 13(3), 209–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Commission of the European Communities. (2005). Green Paper “Confronting demographic change: A new solidarity between the generations”. Brussels: Commission of the European Communities.

  • Crompton, R., & Harris, F. (1998). Explaining women’s employment patterns: ‘Orientations to work’ revisited. British Journal of Sociology, 49(1), 118–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demeny, P. (2003). Population policy dilemmas in Europe at the dawn of the twenty-first century. Population and Development Review, 29(1), 1–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doorewaard, H., Hendrickx, J., & Verschuren, P. (2004). Work orientations of female returners. Work, Employment and Society, 18(1), 7–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esping-Andersen, G. (1990). The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Cambridge: Polity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Esping-Andersen, G., Gallie, D., Hemerijk, A., & Myles, J. (2002). Why we need a new welfare state. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Fagan, C. (2001). Time money and gender order: Work orientations and working-time preferences in Britain. Gender, Work and Organization, 8(3), 239–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferrera, M. (1998). Le Trappole del welfare. Bologna: Il Mulino.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferrera, M., Hemerijk, A. & Rhodes M. (2000). The future of the European welfare state: Managing diversity for a prosperous and cohesive Europe. Report for the Portuguese Presidency of the European Union, Conference on Europe, Globalization and the Future of Social Policy.

  • Gauthier, A. H. (2002). Family policies in industrialized countries: Is there convergence. Population, 57(3), 447–474.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hakim, C. (2000). Work-lifestyle choices in the 21st century: Preference theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hakim, C. (2002). Lifestyle preferences as determinants of women’s differentiated labour market careers. Work and Occupations, 29(4), 428–459.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hakim, C. (2003a). Models of the family in modern societies: Ideals and realities. Aldershot: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hakim, C. (2003b). A new approach to explaining fertility patterns: Preference theory. Population and Development Review, 29(3), 349–374.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hakim, C. (2003c). Public morality versus personal choice: The failure of social attitude surveys. British Journal of Sociology, 54(3), 339–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hakim, C. (2008). Diversity in tastes, values, and preferences: Comment on Jonung and Ståhlberg. Econ Journal Watch, 5(2), 204–218.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kohler, H. P., Billari, F. C., & Ortega, J. A. (2002). The emergence of lowest-low fertility in europe during the 1990s. Population and Development Review, 28(4), 641–681.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lesthaeghe, R. (1983). A century of demographic and cultural change in Western Europe: An exploration of underlying dimensions. Population and Development Review, 9(3), 411–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lesthaeghe, R., & Surkyn, J. (1988). Cultural and economic theories of fertility change. Population and Development Review, 13(1), 1–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McDonald, P. (2002). Sustaining fertility through public policy: The range of options. Population, 57(3), 417–446.

    Google Scholar 

  • McRae, S. (2003a). Constraints and choices in mothers’ employment careers: A consideration of Hakim’s Preference Theory. British Journal of Sociology, 54(3), 317–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McRae, S. (2003b). Choices and constraints in mothers’ employment careers: McRae replies to Hakim. British Journal of Sociology, 54(4), 585–592.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, W. B., & Pasta, D. J. (1995). Behavioural intentions: Which ones predict fertility behaviour in married couples? Journal of Applied Social Psychology, 25, 530–555.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Procter, I., & Padfield, M. (1999). Work orientations and women’s work: A critique of Hakim’s theory of the heterogeneity of women. Gender, Work and Organization, 6(3), 152–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rabušic, L. C. & Manea, B. E. (2006). Preference Theory—The case of the Czech Republic. Paper for the European Population Conference in Liverpool, UK, 21–24 June 2006.

  • Reher, D. S. (1998). Family ties in Western Europe: Persistent contrasts. Population and Development Review, 24(2), 203–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose, M. (2001). Closing down a work career. Housework, employment plans, and womens work attitudes. ESRC Working Paper 1. Transitions and Careers, University of Bath.

  • Stark, L., & Kohler, H. P. (2002). The debate over low fertility in the popular press: A cross-national comparison, 1998–1999. Population and Policy Review, 21(6), 535–574.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Surkyn, J. & Lesthaeghe, R. (2004). Value orientations and the second demographic transition (SDT) in Northern, Western and Southern Europe: An update. Demographic Research. Special Collection 3, Article 3. Online available at: http://www.demographic-research.org/.

  • Testa, M. R., & Grilli, L. (2006). The influence of childbearing regional contexts on ideal family size in Europe. Population, 61(1–2), 109–138.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tomlinson, J. (2006). Women’s work-life balance trajectories in the UK: reformulating choice and constraint in transitions through part-time work across the life-course. British Journal of Guidance and Counselling, 34(3), 365–382.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van de Kaa, D. J. (1987). Europe’s second demographic transition. Population Bulletin, 42(1), 1–57.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This research has been funded by the European Commission (DG Employment, Social Affairs and Equal Opportunities) under the Project “Fertility intentions and outcomes: The role of policies to close the gap” (VS/2006/0685). The main parts of the paper were written while the first author visited the Vienna Institute of Demography. We are grateful to Laurent Toulemon for comments and suggestions, as well to the participants of the 2007 Annual Conference of the Population Association of America (New York) and to the “Demosoc” seminar at the Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona for useful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Agnese Vitali.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Vitali, A., Billari, F.C., Prskawetz, A. et al. Preference Theory and Low Fertility: A Comparative Perspective. Eur J Population 25, 413–438 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10680-009-9178-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10680-009-9178-x

Keywords

Mots-clés

Navigation