Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Outsourcing sustainability: a game-theoretic modeling approach

  • Published:
Environment Systems and Decisions Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

As a response to stakeholders’ interest in sustainable products and services, an organization may change its approach to sustainability issues, from isolated social and environmental projects to corporate sustainability strategies and practices that are part of their core business. However, many of the efforts associated with these sustainability strategies cannot be directly exerted by focal organizations. We consider the situation in which a focal organization (sustainability buyer) outsources sustainability efforts to another organization (sustainability seller). While buyers cannot directly exert sustainability efforts, they can provide economic or technical support to their sellers in order to incentivize these efforts. We investigate how the effort and support decisions change according to characteristics of stakeholders, buyers, and sellers. Additionally, the presence of sustainability-minded stakeholders may lead to buyers’ competition on the sustainability effort exerted by their sellers. Therefore, we extend our analysis of sustainability efforts and incentives to the case of two competing buyers, and we determine conditions under which sharing a seller is preferred by the buyers to having a separate seller for each buyer.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. http://www.nytimes.com/2012/01/26/business/ieconomy-apples-ipad-and-the-human-costs-for-workers-in-china.html (accessed April 5, 2012).

  2. http://money.cnn.com/2012/02/09/technology/apple_foxconn_petition/ (accessed April 5, 2012).

  3. http://www.cleanenergydurham.org/ (accessed November 20, 2012).

  4. Source: www.globalreporting.org (press release of March 8, 2012). GRI is a non-net benefit organization that provides companies and organizations with a comprehensive sustainability reporting framework that is widely used around the world.

  5. http://www.apple.com/supplierresponsibility/ (accessed March 27, 2012).

  6. In Cournot competition, two firms simultaneously decide how much to produce. These quantity choices have an impact on the market price. See Mas-Colell et al. (1995) for a detailed description.

References

  • Bair J (2009) Global commodity chains: genealogy and review. In: Bair J (ed) Frontiers of commodity chains research. Stanford University Press, Stanford, pp 1–34

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernstein F, Kök AG (2009) Dynamic cost reduction through process improvement in assembly networks. Manag Sci 55(4):552–567

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brun LC, Gereffi G (2011) The multiple pathways to industrial energy efficiency: a systems and value chain approach. Report prepared for the Environmental Defense Fund (EDF)

  • Clift R (2003) Metrics for supply chain sustainability. Clean Technol Environ Policy 5:240–247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delmas M, Montiel I (2009) Greening the supply chain: when is customer pressure effective? J Econ Manag Strateg 18(1):171–201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Enkvist PA, Nauclér T, Rosander J (2007, February) A cost curve for greenhouse gas reduction. McKinsey Quarterly 35–45

  • Fair Labor Association (2012) Independent Investigation of Apple Seller, Foxconn: Report Highlights. Retrieved from http://www.fairlabor.org/sites/default/files/documents/reports/foxconn_investigation_report.pdf

  • Foran B, Lenzen M, Deyb C, Bilek M (2005) Integrating sustainable chain management with triple bottom line accounting. Ecol Econ 52(2):143–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gereffi G, Humphrey J, Sturgeon TJ (2005) The governance of global value chains. Rev Int Polit Econ 12(1):78–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gupta S, Loulou R (1998) Process innovation, product differentiation, and channel structure: strategic incentives in a duopoly. Mark Sci 17(4):301–316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haanaes K, Reeves M, Balagopal B, Arthur D, Hopkins MS, Kruschwitz N (2011) First look: the second annual sustainability & innovation survey. MIT Sloan Manag Rev 52(2):77–83

    Google Scholar 

  • Harhoff D (1996) Strategic spillovers and incentives for research and development. Manag Sci 42(6):907–925

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jira C, Toffel MW (2012) Engaging supply chains in climate change. Working paper 12-026, Harvard Business School

  • Kim S-H, Netessine S (2012) Collaborative cost reduction and component procurement under information asymmetry. Working paper No. 2012/33/TOM, INSEAD

  • Kleindorfer PR, Singhal K, Van Wassenhove LN (2005) Sustainable operations management. Prod Oper Manag 14(4):482–492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee S (2008) Drivers for the participation of small and medium-sized sellers in green supply chain initiatives. Supply Chain Manag Int J 13(3):185–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Locke RM, Qin F, Brause A (2007) Does monitoring improve labor standards? Lessons from Nike. Ind Labor Relat Rev 61(1):3–31

    Google Scholar 

  • Locke R, Amengual M, Mangla A (2009) Virtue out of necessity? Compliance, commitment and the improvement of labor conditions in global supply chains. Polit Soc 37(3):319–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mas-Colell A, Whinston MD, Green JR (1995) Microeconomic theory. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Noci G (1997) Designing ‘green’ vendor rating systems for the assessment of a seller’s environmental performance. Eur J Purch Supply Manag 3(2):103–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plambeck EL, Lee HL, Yatsko P (2012) Improving environmental performance in your Chinese supply chain. MIT Sloan Manag Rev 53(2):42–51

    Google Scholar 

  • Sarkis J (2003) A strategic decision framework for green supply chain management. J Clean Prod 11(4):397–409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seuring S, Müller M (2008) From a literature review to a conceptual framework for sustainable supply chain management. J Clean Prod 16(15):1699–1710

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Talluri K, van Ryzin G (2004) The theory and practice of revenue management. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Norwell

    Google Scholar 

  • WBCSD (2008) Sustainable consumption facts and trends: from a business perspective

  • Zhu K, Zhang RQ, Tsung F (2007) Pushing quality improvement along supply chains. Manag Sci 53(3):421–436

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alvaro J. Mendoza.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1

Anticipating the seller’s response function given by (2), the buyer chooses the support level u ≥ 0 that maximizes her benefit function

$$ \pi^{B} \left( u \right) = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {A^{0} \left( {a - bA^{0} } \right) + \left( {a - 2bA^{0} - c^{b} /\gamma } \right)\gamma u - b\gamma^{2} u^{2} } \hfill & { {\text{if}}\,u \ge - A^{0} /\gamma } \hfill \\ { - c^{b} u} \hfill & {{\text{if}}\,u < - A^{0} /\gamma } \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. $$

If \( A^{0} > 0 \), any positive u will increase seller’s effort from A 0 to \( A^{0} + \gamma u \). Therefore, the buyer maximizes \( A^{0} \left( {a - bA^{0} } \right) + \left( {a - 2bA^{0} - c^{b} /\gamma } \right)\gamma u - b\gamma^{2} u^{2} \) subject to u ≥ 0. The KKT conditions are given by

$$ \begin{array}{ll}\gamma \left( {a - 2bA^{0} - c^{b} /\gamma } \right) - 2b\gamma^{2}u \le 0 \hfill \\ \left[ {\gamma \left( {a - 2bA^{0} - c^{b} /\gamma} \right) - 2b\gamma^{2} u} \right]u = 0\hfill \\\end{array} $$

The second-order condition is \( - 2b\gamma^{2} < 0 \). Solving for u and replacing in the seller’s best response function, we obtain the optimal solution

$$ u^{*} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\frac{{a - c^{b} /\gamma - 2bA^{0} }}{2b\gamma }} \hfill & {{\text{if}}\,a - c^{b} /\gamma > 2bA^{0} } \hfill \\ 0 \hfill & { {\text{if}}\,a - c^{b} /\gamma \le 2bA^{0} } \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. $$
$$ x^{*} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\frac{{a - c^{b} /\gamma }}{2b}} \hfill & { {\text{if}}\,a - c^{b} /\gamma > 2bA^{0} } \hfill \\ {A^{0} } \hfill & {{\text{if}}\,a - c^{b} /\gamma \le 2bA^{0} } \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. $$

If \( A^{0} \le 0 \), the seller will exert a positive effort only if \( u \ge - A^{0} /\gamma \). Thus, the buyer finds \( u \) that maximizes the net benefit \( A^{0} \left( {a - bA^{0} } \right) + \left( {a - 2bA^{0} - c^{b} /\gamma } \right)\gamma u - b\gamma^{2} u^{2} \) subject to \( u \ge - A^{0} /\gamma \). Additionally, this net benefit must be positive. Otherwise, the buyer will provide no support. The KKT conditions are given by

$$ \gamma \left( {a - 2bA^{0} - c^{b} /\gamma } \right) - 2b\gamma^{2} u + \lambda = 0 $$
$$ u + A^{0} /\gamma \ge 0 $$
$$ \left( {u + A^{0} /\gamma } \right)\lambda = 0 $$
$$ \lambda \ge 0 $$

On the one hand, if \( u = - A^{0} /\gamma \), then \( \lambda = - \gamma a + c^{b} \). This is feasible if \( a \le c^{b} /\gamma \). However, \( \pi^{B} \left( { - A^{0} /\gamma } \right) = A^{0} a < 0 \), so the buyer will prefer to provide no support. On the other hand if \( \lambda = 0 \), then \( u = \left( {a - c^{b} /\gamma - 2bA^{0} } \right)/2b\gamma \), which is feasible if \( a > c^{b} /\gamma \). However, \( \pi^{B} \left( {\left( {a - c^{b} /\gamma - 2bA^{0} } \right)/2b\gamma } \right) \ge 0 \) only if \( a - c^{b} /\gamma > \left( { - 4bc^{b} A^{0} /\gamma } \right)^{1/2} \). Thus,

$$ u^{*} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\frac{{a - c^{b} /\gamma - 2bA^{0} }}{2b\gamma }} \hfill & { {\text{if}}\,a - c^{b} /\gamma > \left( { - 4bc^{b} A^{0} /\gamma } \right)^{1/2} } \hfill \\ 0 \hfill & { {\text{if}}\,a - c^{b} /\gamma \le \left( { - 4bc^{b} A^{0} /\gamma } \right)^{1/2} } \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. $$
$$ x^{*} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\frac{{a - c^{b} /\gamma }}{2b}} \hfill & {{\text{if}}\,a - c^{b} /\gamma > \left( { - 4bc^{b} A^{0} /\gamma } \right)^{1/2} } \hfill \\ 0 \hfill & {{\text{if}}\,a - c^{b} /\gamma \le \left( { - 4bc^{b} A^{0} /\gamma } \right)^{1/2} } \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. $$

The optimal benefits are obtained by replacing the optimal effort and support in the net benefit functions (1) and (3).

Proof of Proposition 2

The symmetric equilibrium is given by \( u_{1} = u_{2} = K/2 \). We can obtain \( u_{1}^{*} \) and \( u_{2}^{*} \) using the expression for K obtained in Eq. (10). Thus, we obtain \( x^{*} \) by substituting \( u_{1}^{*} \) and \( u_{2}^{*} \) in Eq. (8). The optimal net benefits can be obtained by substituting \( x^{*} \), \( u_{1}^{*} \) and \( u_{2}^{*} \) in Eqs. (7) and (9).

Proof of Proposition 3

From (17), we have a system of two equations. Solving for u 1 and u 2, we obtain \( u_{1}^{*} \) and \( u_{2}^{*} \). Then, we substitute these in Eq. (15) to obtain \( x_{1}^{*} \) and \( x_{2}^{*} \). Finally, we substitute the optimal efforts and supports in Eqs. (13) and (16) to obtain the respective optimal net benefits for sellers and buyers.

Proof of Proposition 4

  1. 1)

    By directly comparing \( x^{*} \) from Eq. (11) with \( x_{1}^{*} + x_{2}^{*} \) from Eq. (18), we can determine that the effort in the shared-seller network is greater than the total effort in the separate-sellers network if \( a \le - 2c^{b} /\gamma \). However, this is not possible given our assumption that \( \tilde{K} > 0 \).

  2. 2)

    From Eqs. (11) and (18), we can determine that the effort in the shared-seller network is greater than the effort of each seller in the separate-sellers network if \( a \ge \frac{{4c^{b} }}{\gamma } \). Additionally, the seller’s net benefit function in both networks can be written as \( \tilde{r}\left[ {1 - \left( {1 + \alpha x} \right)e^{ - \alpha x} } \right] \) (because \( \delta = 0 \) and \( \hat{r} = \tilde{r} \)). Because this function is increasing in the effort x, the seller’s net benefit is greater in the shared-seller network relative to the separate-sellers network if \( a \ge \frac{{4c^{b} }}{\gamma } \).

  3. 3)

    By direct comparison of the optimal buyer’s net benefit from Eqs. (12) and (19), we can determine that this net benefit is higher in the shared-seller network if \( a \ge \frac{{4c^{b} }}{\gamma } + 36b{ \ln }\left( {\frac{{\alpha \tilde{r} }}{{c^{0} }}} \right) \).

1.1 One buyer–one seller with alternative price function

In Sect. 4, we found that the seller’s best response function is given by the following:

$$ x\left( u \right) = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {A^{0} + \gamma u, } \hfill & {{\text{if}}\,u > - \frac{{A^{0} }}{\gamma },} \hfill \\ {0,} \hfill & {{\text{otherwise}}.} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. $$

Assume that instead of a linear price function, the price that stakeholders are willing to pay for sustainability efforts is given by \( p\left( x \right) = {a \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {a {(1 + bx)}}} \right. \kern-0pt} {(1 + bx)}} \). Thus, anticipating the seller’s response function, the buyer chooses the support level u ≥ 0 that maximizes her benefit function

$$ \pi^{B} \left( u \right) = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\frac{{a(A^{0} + \gamma u)}}{{1 + b(A^{0} + \gamma u)}} - c^{b} u} \hfill & {{\text{if}}\,u \ge - A^{0} /\gamma } \hfill \\ { - c^{b} u} \hfill & {{\text{if}}\,u < - A^{0} /\gamma } \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. $$

If A 0 > 0, any positive u will increase seller’s effort from A 0 to \( A^{0} + \gamma u \). Therefore, the buyer maximizes \( \frac{{a(A^{0} + \gamma u)}}{{1 + b(A^{0} + \gamma u)}} - c^{b} u \) subject to u ≥ 0. It can be checked that the second-order condition is negative. Solving for u and replacing in the seller’s best response function, we obtain the optimal solution

$$ u^{*} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\frac{{\left( {\frac{a\gamma }{{c^{b} }}} \right)^{1/2} - bA^{0} - 1}}{b\gamma }} \hfill & {{\text{if}}\,\left( {\frac{a\gamma }{{c^{b} }}} \right)^{1/2} > bA^{0} + 1} \hfill \\ 0 \hfill & {{\text{if}}\,\left( {\frac{a\gamma }{{c^{b} }}} \right)^{1/2} \le bA^{0} + 1} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. $$
$$ x^{*} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\frac{{\left( {\frac{{a\gamma }}{{c^{b} }}} \right)^{{1/2}} - 1}}{b}} \hfill & {{\text{if}}\left( {\frac{{a\gamma }}{{c^{b} }}} \right)^{{1/2}} > bA^{0} + 1} \hfill \\ {A^{0} } \hfill & {{\text{if}}\left( {\frac{{a\gamma }}{{c^{b} }}} \right)^{{1/2}} \le bA^{0} + 1} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. $$

If \( A^{0} \le 0 \), the seller will exert a positive effort only if \( u \ge - A^{0} /\gamma \). Thus, the buyer finds u that maximizes the net benefit \( \frac{{a(A^{0} + \gamma u)}}{{1 + b(A^{0} + \gamma u)}} - c^{b} u \) subject to \( u \ge - A^{0} /\gamma \). Additionally, this net benefit must be positive. Finding the KKT conditions and solving for u, we obtain

$$ u^{*} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\frac{{\left( {\frac{a\gamma }{{c^{b} }}} \right)^{1/2} - bA^{0} - 1}}{b\gamma }} \hfill & {{\text{if}}\, \left( {\frac{a\gamma }{{c^{b} }}} \right)^{1/2} > \left( { - bA^{0} } \right)^{1/2} + 1} \hfill \\ 0 \hfill & {{\text{if}}\, \left( {\frac{a\gamma }{{c^{b} }}} \right)^{1/2} \le \left( { - bA^{0} } \right)^{1/2} + 1} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. $$
$$ x^{*} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\frac{{\left( {\frac{a\gamma }{{c^{b} }}} \right)^{1/2} - 1}}{b}} \hfill & {{\text{if}}\, \left( {\frac{a\gamma }{{c^{b} }}} \right)^{1/2} > \left( { - bA^{0} } \right)^{1/2} + 1} \hfill \\ {A^{0} } \hfill & {{\text{if}}\, \left( {\frac{a\gamma }{{c^{b} }}} \right)^{1/2} \le \left( { - bA^{0} } \right)^{1/2} + 1} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. $$

We can see that the optimal effort and support decisions, \( x^{*} \) and \( u^{*} \), vary for four different regions characterized by \( A^{0} \), a, c b, and \( \gamma \):

$$ \Upomega_{1} = \left\{ {\left( {A^{0} , a, c^{b} , \gamma } \right):A^{0} > 0, \, \left( {\frac{a\gamma }{{c^{b} }}} \right)^{1/2} > bA^{0} + 1} \right\} $$
$$ \Upomega_{2} = \left\{ {\left( {A^{0} , a, c^{b} , \gamma } \right):A^{0} \le 0, \, \left( {\frac{a\gamma }{{c^{b} }}} \right)^{1/2} > \left( { - bA^{0} } \right)^{1/2} + 1} \right\} $$
$$ \Upomega_{3} = \left\{ {\left( {A^{0} , a, c^{b} , \gamma } \right):A^{0} > 0, \, \left( {\frac{a\gamma }{{c^{b} }}} \right)^{1/2} \le bA^{0} + 1} \right\} $$
$$ \Upomega_{4} = \left\{ {\left( {A^{0} , a, c^{b} , \gamma } \right):A^{0} \le 0, \, \left( {\frac{a\gamma }{{c^{b} }}} \right)^{1/2} \le \left( { - bA^{0} } \right)^{1/2} + 1} \right\} $$

In regions \( {{\Upomega}}_{1} \) and \( {{\Upomega}}_{2} \), both the support and the effort are positive. In region \( {{\Upomega}}_{3} \), the effort is positive but the support is zero. Finally, in region \( {{\Upomega}}_{4} \), both the effort and the support are equal to zero. These results have a similar structure to those presented in Proposition 1, for the linear price case.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Mendoza, A.J., Clemen, R.T. Outsourcing sustainability: a game-theoretic modeling approach. Environ Syst Decis 33, 224–236 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10669-013-9443-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10669-013-9443-8

Keywords

Navigation