Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Decoupling economic growth from emissions: the case of policies promoting resource substitution

  • Published:
Environment, Development and Sustainability Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The relationship between the economy and the environment is not straightforward and is influenced by a multitude of factors. Ideally, economic growth would not damage environmental quality and environmental protection would not hinder economic growth. Achieving this decoupling often requires environmental policy, but the analysis of specific policy instruments and their necessary levels to achieve it is rare. In this paper, we use a stylized equilibrium model to explore distinct policy instruments under which relative decoupling and absolute decoupling between economic growth and emissions occur. In our model, final-goods production uses polluting (non-renewable) and non-polluting (renewable) resources. The government taxes emissions and subsidizes renewables production. In the empirical application, we focus on the case of electricity generation. Results show that, with a growing subsidy, relative decoupling exists. Achieving absolute decoupling is harder, but it occurs for a certain interval of the subsidy growth rate. For that purpose, the choice of the tax and subsidy growth rates is more important than the choice of the initial levels for these instruments. The choice of the subsidy growth rate indicates the prioritization between the economy and the environment. A lower subsidy growth rate favors the environment, while a higher one favors the economy. The tax growth rate dictates the distance between the output growth rate and the emissions growth rate. The higher the tax growth rate, the higher the difference between them. In sum, the government can decide between attaining higher output growth rates, higher emissions decreasing rates, or an intermediate situation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In the context of an endogenous growth model where the steady state is emphasized—that is, the long run is analyzed—this assumption is required.

  2. We abstract from aspects such as population growth and the inclusion of other production factors in order to isolate the effects of natural resources on economic growth and the environment.

  3. We also considered the possibility of monopoly power for resources firms, both in the renewables and non-renewables sector, but qualitatively results remained unchanged, while calculations became more complicated. Hence, for simplification, we maintained perfect competition as the benchmark.

  4. Where \(g_{x}\) is the growth rate of the variable \(x\).

  5. The most recent corresponding report from NEA, IEA, and OECD, which is from 2015, indicates that coal remains cheaper than wind power in terms of levelized costs (with a cost of $0.02893/kWh as opposed to $0.04894/kWh). Hence, the cost gap decreased but still exists. Qualitatively, our results remain unchanged.

References

  • Almeida, T., Cruz, L., Barata, E., & García-Sánchez, I. (2017). Economic growth and environmental impacts: An analysis based on a composite index of environmental damage. Ecological Indicators, 76, 119–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ang, B. (2004). Decomposing analysis for policy making in energy: Which is the preferred method? Energy Policy, 32, 1131–1139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azar, C., Holmberg, J., & Karlsson, S. (2002). Decoupling—past trends and prospects for the future. Stockholm: Environmental Advisory Council.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bovenberg, A. L., & Smulders, S. (1995). Environmental quality and pollution-augmenting technological change in a two-sector endogenous growth model. Journal of Public Economics, 57, 369–391.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chakravorty, U., Roumasset, J., & Tse, K. (1997). Endogenous substitution among energy resources and global warming. The Journal of Political Economy, 105(6), 1201–1234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cleveland, C., & Ruth, M. (1998). Indicators of dematerialization and the materials intensity of use. Journal of Industrial Ecology, 2(3), 15–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole, M. (1999). Limits to growth, sustainable development and environmental Kuznets curves: As examination of the environmental impacts of economic development. Sustainable Development, 7, 87–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conrad, E., & Cassar, L. (2014). Decoupling economic growth and environmental degradation: Reviewing progress to date in the small island state of Malta. Sustainability, 6, 6729–6750.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Vita, G. (2006). Natural resources dynamics: Exhaustible and renewable resources, and the rate of technical substitution. Resources Policy, 31, 172–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Everett, T., Ishwaran, M., Ansaloni, G., & Rubin, A. (2010). Economic growth and the environment. Defra Evidence and Analysis Series Paper 2.

  • Freitas, L., & Kaneko, S. (2011). Decomposing the decoupling CO2 emissions and economic growth in Brazil. Ecological Economics, 70, 1459–1469.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galeotti, M. (2003). Environment and Economic Growth: Is Technical Change the Key to Decoupling? FEEM Working Paper No. 90.2003.

  • Galinato, G., & Yoder, J. (2010). An integrated tax-subsidy policy for carbon emission reductions. Resource and Energy Economics, 32, 310–326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giljum, S., Hak, T., Hinterberg, F., & Kovanda, J. (2005). Environmental governance in the European Union: Strategies and instruments for absolute decoupling. International Journal of Sustainable Development, 8(1/2), 31–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grimaud, A. (1999). Pollution permits and sustainable growth in a Schumpeterian model. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 38, 249–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grimaud, A. A. (2007). Why can an environmental policy tax promote growth through the channel of education? Ecological Economics, 62, 27–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grimaud, A., Lafforgue, G., & Magné, B. (2011). Climate change mitigation options and directed technical change: A decentralized equilibrium analysis. Resources and Energy Economics, 33, 938–962.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gupta, S. (2015). Decoupling: A step toward sustainable development with reference to OECD countries. International Journal of Sustainable Development and World Ecology. https://doi.org/10.1080/13504509.2015.1088485.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart, R. (2004). Growth, environment and innovation: A model with production vintages and environmentally oriented research. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 48(3), 1078–1098.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalkuhl, M., Edenhofer, O., & Lessmann, K. (2013). Renewable energy subsidies: Second-best policy or fatal aberration for mitigation? Resource and Energy Economics, 35, 217–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurosawa, A. (2004). Carbon concentration target and technological choice. Energy Economics, 26, 675–684.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ligthart, J. (1994). Sustainable growth and renewable resources in the global economy. In C. Carraro (Ed.), Trade, Innovation, Environment. Netherlands: Kluwer Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lin, C., & Zhang, W. (2011). Market power and shadow prices for nonrenewable resources: An empirical dynamic model. Annual Meeting, July 2426. Pittsburg, Pennsylvania.

  • Loo, B., & Banister, D. (2016). Decoupling transport from economic growth: Extending the debate to include environmental and social externalities. Journal of Transport Geography, 57, 134–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mauerhofer, V. (2013). Lose less instead of win more: The failure of decoupling and perspectives for competition in a degrowth economy. Environmental Values, 22, 43–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Næss, P., & Høyer, K. (2009). The emperor’s green clothes: Growth, decoupling, and capitalism. Capitalism Nature Socialism, 20(3), 74–95. https://doi.org/10.1080/10455750903215753.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • NEA, IEA, & OECD. (2010). Projected Costs of Generating Electricity 2010 Edition. Paris: Nuclear Energy Agency, International Energy Agency, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.

  • Ockwell, D. (2008). Energy and economic growth: Grounding and understanding in physical reality. Energy Policy, 36(4600), 4604.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2002). Indicators to measure decoupling of environmental pressure from economic growth. SG/SD(2002)1/FINAL. Retrieved from http://www.oecd.org/officialdocuments/publicdisplaydocumentpdf/?cote=sg/sd(2002)1/final&doclanguage=en.

  • Porter, M., & van der Linde, C. (1995). Toward a new conception of the environment competitiveness relationship. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9, 97–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ru, X., Chen, S., & Dong, H. (2012). Na empirical study on relationship between economic growth and carbon emissions based on decoupling theory. Journal of Sustainable Development, 5(8), 43–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schou, P. (2000). Polluting non-renewable resources and growth. Environmental & Resource Economics, 16, 211–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schou, P. (2002). When environmental policy is superfluous: Growth and polluting resources. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 104(4), 605–620.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silva, S., Soares, I., & Afonso, O. (2013). Economic and environmental effects under resource scarcity and substitution between renewable and non-renewable resources. Energy Policy, 54(C), 113–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silva, S., Soares, I., & Pinho, C. (2018). Renewable energy subsidies versus carbon capture and sequestration support. Environment, Development and Sustainability, 20(3), 1213–1227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steinberger, J., Krausmann, F., Getzner, M., Schandl, H., & West, J. (2013). Development and dematerialization: An international study. PLoS ONE, 8(10), e70385.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Tahvonen, O. (1997). Fossil fuels, stock externalities, and backstop technology. The Canadian Journal of Economics, 30(4a), 855–874.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tukker, A. (2005) The Relevance of Sustainable Consumption Policies for Realising Decoupling. In Paper for 10th European Roundtable of Sustainable Consumption and Production (ERSCP 2005), 5–7 October, Antwerp, Belgium. Retrieved from 01 December 2006 http://www.vito.be/erscp2005/documents/papers/PAPER076.P.

  • UNEP (2011) Decoupling natural resource use and environmental impacts from economic growth. Retrieved from http://www.unep.org/resourcepanel/decoupling/files/pdf/decoupling_report_english.pdf.

  • U.S. Energy Information Administration. (2013). Annual Energy Review 2012. Retrieved from http://www.eia.gov/aer.

  • van der Voet, E., van Oers, L., Moll, S., et al. (2005). Policy review on decoupling: development of indicators to assess decoupling of economic development and environmental pressure in the EU-25 and AC-3 countries. Centre of Environmental Sciences (CML), Leiden.

  • Wang, W., Liu, R., Zhang, M., & Li, H. (2013). Decomposing decoupling of energy-related CO2 emissions and economic growth in Jiangsu Province. Energy for Sustainable Development, 17, 62–71.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Ward, J., Sutton, P., Werner, A., Costanza, R., Mohr, S., & Simmons, C. (2016). Is decoupling GDP growth from environmental impact possible? PLoS ONE, 11(10), e0164733.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xepapadeas, A. (2005). Economic growth and the environment. In K. Maler & J. Vincent (Eds.), Handbook of environmental economics (Vol. 3, pp. 1220–1266). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yu, Y., Chen, D., Zhu, B., & Hu, S. (2013). Eco-efficiency trends in China, 1978–2010: Decoupling environmental pressure from economic growth. Ecological Indicators, 24, 177–184.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, Z. (2000). Decoupling China’s carbon emissions increase from economic growth: An economic analysis and policy implications. World Development, 28(4), 739–752.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Susana Silva gratefully acknowledges the financial support of “Fundação para a Ciência e Tecnologia” (FCT—Portugal), through the Grant SFRH/BPD/86707/2012.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Susana Silva.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Derivation of the output and emissions growth rates

Replacing (6) on (11), we obtain:

$$g_{Y} = \frac{{\dot{\lambda }}}{\lambda } - \rho.$$
(18)

From (10), we have:

$$\dot{\lambda } = \alpha \left( {c_{F} + \lambda + \psi \tau } \right)\left( {g_{R} - g_{F} } \right) - \dot{\tau }.$$
(19)

Replacing (19) into (18):

$$g_{Y} = \frac{{\alpha \left( {c_{F} + \lambda + \psi \tau } \right)\left( {g_{R} - g_{F} } \right) - \dot{\tau }}}{\lambda } - \rho.$$
(20)

From (9), we know that:

$$g_{R} - g_{F} = \left( {\frac{1}{1 - \alpha }} \right)\left( {\frac{{\dot{\sigma }}}{{c_{R} - \sigma }}} \right).$$
(21)

Replacing (21) into (20), we obtain the economic growth rate:

$$g_{Y} = \frac{{\alpha \left( {c_{F} + \lambda + \psi \tau } \right)\left( {\frac{1}{1 - \alpha }} \right)\left( {\frac{{\dot{\sigma }}}{{c_{R} - \sigma }}} \right) - \dot{\tau } - \lambda \rho }}{\lambda }.$$
(22)

From (12), we know that \(g_{F} = \frac{{g_{Y} - \alpha g_{R} }}{1 - \alpha }.\). Replacing (22) into this expression, we have:

$$g_{F} = \frac{{\alpha \left( {c_{F} + \lambda + \psi \tau } \right)\left( {\frac{1}{1 - \alpha }} \right)\left( {\frac{{\dot{\sigma }}}{{c_{R} - \sigma }}} \right) - \dot{\tau } - \lambda \rho }}{{\lambda \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)}} - \frac{\alpha }{1 - \alpha }g_{R}.$$
(23)

Using (10) for the expression of \(g_{R}\) and replacing it into (23), after some algebra, we obtain the expression of the growth of fossil fuels use, which is equal to the growth rate of emissions:

$$g_{F} = \frac{{\alpha \left( {c_{F} + \lambda + \psi \tau } \right)\left( {\frac{1}{1 - \alpha }} \right)\left( {\frac{{\dot{\sigma }}}{{c_{R} - \sigma }}} \right) - \dot{\tau } - \lambda \rho }}{\lambda } - \left( {\frac{{\dot{\lambda } + \dot{\tau }}}{{c_{F} + \lambda + \psi \tau }}} \right).$$
(24)

Finally, replacing the expression of \(\dot{\lambda }\), we obtain:

$$g_{F} = \frac{{\alpha \left( {c_{F} + \lambda + \psi \tau } \right)\left( {\frac{1}{1 - \alpha }} \right)\left( {\frac{{\dot{\sigma }}}{{c_{R} - \sigma }}} \right) - \dot{\tau } - \lambda \rho }}{\lambda } - \left( {\frac{\alpha }{1 - \alpha }} \right)\left( {\frac{{\dot{\sigma }}}{{c_{R} - \sigma }}} \right).$$
(25)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Silva, S., Soares, I. & Afonso, O. Decoupling economic growth from emissions: the case of policies promoting resource substitution. Environ Dev Sustain 23, 8331–8347 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10668-020-00967-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10668-020-00967-9

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation