Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

A Two-Sector Model of Economic Growth with Endogenous Technical Change and Pollution Abatement

  • Published:
Environmental Modeling & Assessment Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We provide insights into the relationships between technological development, economic growth, and pollution accumulation using a two-sector model of economic growth with endogenous technical change. In the model, output is produced using a polluting resource. Production can be used for either consumption or abatement of pollution. Scientists can be allocated between two research activities: resource-saving and abatement-augmenting technologies. Our results indicate conditional path dependency. Specifically, when the innovative capacity in the resource-saving research sector is sufficiently high, scientists are allocated to improve only the resource-saving technology, independently of the state of the technologies and environment. Consequently, the allocation of researchers is path-independent. When the innovative capacity in the abatement-augmenting research sector is sufficiently high, the optimal allocation of researchers depends on the initial level of the pollution stock or technologies but eventually will be directed to improve the abatement technology. We further characterize the optimal steady-state and off-steady-state dynamics and show that green growth is always socially optimal. By using a two-sector model, we address a lack of attention to multi-sector growth models in neoclassical growth theory and show that distinct results and transitional dynamics can emerge.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Green growth has become a central objective of international organizations such as the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, the World Bank, and the United Nations.

  2. Resource-saving technical change implies that the same level of output can be produced with less resource usage. On the other hand, abatement-augmenting technical change implies that the same level of abatement can be achieved with fewer use abatement inputs.

  3. Dirty technical change implies that the same level of production can be done with less use of the inputs, while still causing the same level of pollution. On the other hand, as clean production is pollution-free, clean technical change implies the same level of clean production with less of the inputs.

  4. For the economic literature on endogenous technical change and environmental pollution (in particular, global warming and climate change), we refer the reader to Bovenberg and Smulders [20, 21], Goulder and Mathai [32], Popp [57, 58], Grimaud et al. [34], and Acemoglu et al. [4, 6]. For the empirical literature on environment and endogenous technical change, the reader is referred to Newell et al. [52], Popp [57], Acemoglu et al. [6], and Aghion et al. [10]. For a conceptual review of economic growth and the environment, see Smulders et al. [66].

  5. Nordhaus [53] introduced the concept of backstop technology and analyzed the timing of the substitution of such technologies for fossil fuel resources.

  6. The phenomenon, which describes diminishing pollution and constant economic growth through technological progress, is also known as the Porter Hypothesis [60].

  7. The empirical literature on EKC starts with Grossman and Krueger [36, 37].

  8. In the rest of the paper, we use the terms macro good, output, production, income, and GDP interchangeably.

  9. In the context of energy production, improvements in fuel efficiency are an example of factor-augmenting technical change. One other example is material efficiency, a metric to express the degree of the use of a particular material required to produce particular a product [26]. Material efficiency can be improved by reducing the amount of the material that enters the production process and ends up in the waste stream without damaging the desired quality of the output [26, 42].

  10. The aggregate innovation production function, that is, Eq. (2.5), has constant returns to accumulated knowledge in the model. This is because if the returns to the accumulated knowledge are slightly higher, the model generates explosive growth. On the other hand, if there are decreasing returns to the accumulated knowledge, productivity growth gradually ceases.

  11. For specifications of two-sector growth models with knowledge spillovers, we refer the reader to [51].

  12. This assumption also allows us to avoid any scale effect on output growth [38, 43]. For example, if the number of researchers was subject to exponential growth, the growth rate of the output in our model would itself grow exponentially.

  13. Quite a few other studies have followed this mainstream approach, where damage adversely affects the social welfare (e.g., [18, 41, 50, 56, 72]). Alternatively, Chakravorty et al. [24, 25], Amigues and Moreaux [11], Amigues et al. [12], Gerlagh et al. [30], and Kollenbach [45] set a ceiling on the accumulated pollution stock. The incentive behind choosing a ceiling is that “it represents a threshold beyond which a catastrophe takes place” [50].

  14. Notice that under a resource-saving research regime, all scientists are allocated to the resource-saving research sector. Therefore, B(t) = B0.

  15. Analogous to Corollary 2, all researchers are allocated to improve the clean (intermediate) technology for a sufficiently high level of pollution stock or a sufficiently advanced clean technology.

  16. Moreaux and Withagen [50] also highlight the aftermath of resource scarcity, which is the main contribution of the paper.

  17. To name a few, these distortions are (i) the intertemporal spillover effects (i.e., inventors do consider the fact that the ideas they produce can be used to generate new innovations), (ii) the appropriability effects (i.e., inventors can only partially appropriate the social value they create), and (iii) the creative destruction effect [34].

References

  1. Acemoglu, D. (2002). Directed technical change. The Review of Economic Studies, 69(4), 781–809.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Acemoglu, D. (2003). Labor- and capital-augmenting technical change. Journal of the European Economic Association, 1(1), 1–37.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Acemoglu, D. (2009). Introduction to modern economic growth. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Acemoglu, D, Aghion, P, Bursztyn, L, Hémous, D. (2012). The environment and directed technical change. American Economic Review, 102(1), 131–166.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Acemoglu, D, Aghion, P, Hémous, D. (2014). The environment and directed technical change in a north–south model. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 30(3), 513–530.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Acemoglu, D, Akcigit, U, Hanley, D, Kerr, W. (2016). Transition to clean technology. Journal of Political Economy, 124(1), 52–104.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Aghion, P, & Howitt, P. (1992). A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica, 60(2), 323–351.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Aghion, P, & Howitt, P. (2009). The economics of growth. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Aghion, P, & Akcigit, U. (2014). What do we learn from Schumpeterian growth theory?. In Handbook of economic growth (Vol. 2, pp. 515–563). Elsevier.

  10. Aghion, P, Dechezleprêtre, A, Hémous, D, Martin, R, Van Reenen, J. (2016). Carbon taxes, path dependency and directed technical change: evidence from the auto industry. Journal of Political Economy, 124(1), 1–51.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Amigues, JP, & Moreaux, M. (2013). The atmospheric carbon resilience problem: a theoretical analysis. Resource and Energy Economics, 35(4), 618–636.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Amigues, JP, Lafforgue, G, Moreaux, M. (2014). Optimal timing of ccs policies with heterogeneous energy consumption sectors. Environmental and Resource Economics, 57(3), 345–366.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Andreoni, J, & Levinson, A. (2001). The simple analytics of the environmental Kuznets curve. Journal of Public Economics, 80(2), 269–286.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Attanasio, O. (1996). Relative wage movements and the distribution of consumption. Journal of Political Economy, 104(6), 1227–1262.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Attanasio, OP, & Weber, G. (1993). Consumption growth, the interest rate and aggregation. The Review of Economic Studies, 60(3), 631–649.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Attanasio, O, & Weber, G. (1995). Is consumption growth consistent with intertemporal optimization? Evidence from the consumer expenditure survey. Journal of Political Economy, 103(6), 1121–1157.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Attanasio, OP, Banks, J, Meghir, C, Weber, G. (1999). Humps and bumps in lifetime consumption. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 17(1), 22–35.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Ayong Le Kama, A, Fodha, M, Lafforgue, G. (2013). Optimal carbon capture and storage policies. Environmental Modeling & Assessment, 18(4), 417–426.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Blundell, R, Browning, M, Meghir, C. (1994). Consumer demand and the life-cycle allocation of household expenditures. The Review of Economic Studies, 61(1), 57–80.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Bovenberg, AL, & Smulders, S. (1995). Environmental quality and pollution-augmenting technological change in a two-sector endogenous growth model. Journal of Public Economics, 57(3), 369–391.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Bovenberg, AL, & Smulders, S. (1996). Transitional impacts of environmental policy in an endogenous growth model. International Economic Review, 37(4), 861–893.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Bowen, A, & Hepburn, C. (2014). Green growth: an assessment. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 30(3), 407–422.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Brock, WA, & Taylor, MS. (2010). The green Solow model. Journal of Economic Growth, 15(2), 127–153.

    Google Scholar 

  24. Chakravorty, U, Magné, B, Moreaux, M. (2006). A Hotelling model with a ceiling on the stock of pollution. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 30(12), 2875–2904.

    Google Scholar 

  25. Chakravorty, U, Moreaux, M, Tidball, M. (2008). Ordering the extraction of polluting nonrenewable resources. American Economic Review, 98(3), 1128–1144.

    Google Scholar 

  26. DESA. (2007). Industrial development for the 21st century: sustainable development perspectives. New York: United Nations.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Dinda, S. (2005). A theoretical basis for the environmental Kuznets curve. Ecological Economics, 53(3), 403–413.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Engelhardt, GV, & Kumar, A. (2009). The elasticity of intertemporal substitution: new evidence from 401(k) participation. Economics Letters, 103(1), 15–17.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Fried, S. (2018). Climate policy and innovation: a quantitative macroeconomic analysis. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 10(1), 90–118.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Gerlagh, R, Kverndokk, S, Rosendahl, KE. (2014). The optimal time path of clean energy R&D policy when patents have finite lifetime. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 67(1), 2–19.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Golosov, M, Hassler, J, Krusell, P, Tsyvinski, A. (2014). Optimal taxes on fossil fuel in general equilibrium. Econometrica, 82(1), 41–88.

    Google Scholar 

  32. Goulder, LH, & Mathai, K. (2000). Optimal CO2 abatement in the presence of induced technological change. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 39, 1–38.

    Google Scholar 

  33. Greaker, M, Heggedal, TR, Rosendahl, KE. (2018). Environmental policy and the direction of technical change. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 120(4), 1100–1138.

    Google Scholar 

  34. Grimaud, A, Lafforgue, G, Magne, B. (2011). Climate change mitigation options and directed technical change: a decentralized equilibrium analysis. Resource and Energy Economics, 33(4), 938–962.

    Google Scholar 

  35. Grossman, GM, & Helpman, E. (1993). Innovation and growth in the global economy. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  36. Grossman, GM, & Krueger, AB. (1991). Environmental impacts of a North American free trade agreement. NBER Working Paper Series Working Paper.

  37. Grossman, GM, & Krueger, AB. (1995). Economic growth and the environment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(2), 353–377.

    Google Scholar 

  38. Groth, C. (2007). A new-growth perspective on non-renewable resources. In Bretschger, L, & Smulders, S (Eds.) Sustainable resource use and economic dynamics (Chap. 7, pp. 127–163). Springer.

  39. Hassler, J, Krusell, P, Olovsson, C. (2012). Energy-saving technical change. Tech. rep., National Bureau of Economic Research.

  40. Heutel, G, & Fischer, C. (2013). Environmental macroeconomics: Environmental policy, business cycles, and directed technical change. NBER Working Paper Series Working Paper.

  41. Hoel, M, & Kverndokk, S. (1996). Depletion of fossil fuels and the impacts of global warming. Resource and Energy Economics, 18(2), 115–136.

    Google Scholar 

  42. IEA. (2015). World Energy Outlook 2015. Tech. rep., International Energy Agency.

  43. Jones, CI. (1999). Growth: with or without scale effects? American Economic Review, 89(2), 139–144.

    Google Scholar 

  44. Jones, CI. (2016). The facts of economic growth. In Handbook of macroeconomics (Vol. 2, pp. 3–69). Elsevier.

  45. Kollenbach, G. (2015). Abatement, R&D and growth with a pollution ceiling. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 54, 1–16.

    Google Scholar 

  46. Krautkraemer, JA. (2005). Economics of natural resource scarcity: the state of the debate. In RD Simpson, MA Toman, RU Ayres (Eds.) , Scarcity and growth revisited: natural resources and the environment in the new millennium, resources for the future.

  47. Lennox, JA, & Witajewski-Baltvilks, J. (2017). Directed technical change with capital-embodied technologies: implications for climate policy. Energy Economics, 67, 400–409.

    Google Scholar 

  48. Lieb, CM. (2004). The environmental Kuznets curve and flow versus stock pollution: the neglect of future damages. Environmental and Resource Economics, 29(4), 483– 506.

    Google Scholar 

  49. Mattauch, L, Creutzig, F, Edenhofer, O. (2015). Avoiding carbon lock-in: policy options for advancing structural change. Economic Modelling, 50, 49–63.

    Google Scholar 

  50. Moreaux, M, & Withagen, C. (2015). Optimal abatement of carbon emission flows. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 74, 55–70.

    Google Scholar 

  51. Naito, T, & Ohdoi, R. (2008). Dynamics of a two-sector endogenous growth model with intersectoral knowledge spillovers. Economic Theory, 35(3), 599–605.

    Google Scholar 

  52. Newell, R, Jaffe, AB, Stavins, RN. (1999). The induced innovation hypothesis and energy-saving technological change. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 941–975.

    Google Scholar 

  53. Nordhaus, WD. (1973). The allocation of energy resources. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 4(3), 529–576.

    Google Scholar 

  54. Nordhaus, WD. (2002). Modeling induced innovation in climate-change policy. Technological Change and the Environment, 9, 259–290.

    Google Scholar 

  55. OECD. (2012). OECD Environmental Outlook to 2050. OECD Publishing.

  56. Van der Ploeg, F, & Withagen, C. (2012). Is there really a Green Paradox? Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 64(3), 342–363.

    Google Scholar 

  57. Popp, D. (2002). Induced innovation and energy prices. American Economic Review, 92, 160–180.

    Google Scholar 

  58. Popp, D. (2004). Entice: Endogenous technological change in the dice model of global warming. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 48(1), 742–768.

    Google Scholar 

  59. Popp, D. (2006). Entice-br: the effects of backstop technology R&D on climate policy models. Energy Economics, 28(2), 188– 222.

    Google Scholar 

  60. Porter, ME, & Van der Linde, C. (1995). Toward a new conception of the environment-competitiveness relationship. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(4), 97–118.

    Google Scholar 

  61. Romer, PM. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5, Part 2), S71—S102.

    Google Scholar 

  62. Rouge, L. (2019). Environmental policy instruments and the long-run management of a growing stock of pollutant. Environmental Modeling & Assessment, 24(1), 61–73.

    Google Scholar 

  63. Scholz, JK, Seshadri, A, Khitatrakun, S. (2006). Are Americans saving optimally for retirement? Journal of Political Economy, 114(4), 607–643.

    Google Scholar 

  64. Smulders, S, & De Nooij, M. (2003). The impact of energy conservation on technology and economic growth. Resource and Energy Economics, 25(1), 59–79.

    Google Scholar 

  65. Smulders, S, Bretschger, L, Egli, H. (2011). Economic growth and the diffusion of clean technologies: explaining environmental Kuznets curves. Environmental and Resource Economics, 49(1), 79–99.

    Google Scholar 

  66. Smulders, S, Toman, M, Withagen, C. (2014). Growth theory and green growth. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 30(3), 423–446.

    Google Scholar 

  67. Solow, RM. (2005). Reflections on growth theory. Handbook of Economic Growth, 1, 3–10.

    Google Scholar 

  68. Stern, N. (2008). The economics of climate change. American Economic Review, 98(2), 1–37.

    Google Scholar 

  69. Stokey, NL. (1998). Are there limits to growth? International Economic Review, 39(1), 1–31.

    Google Scholar 

  70. Tahvonen, O. (1997). Fossil fuels, stock externalities, and backstop technology. Canadian Journal of Economics, 30(4a), 855–874.

    Google Scholar 

  71. Tsur, Y, & Zemel, A. (2011). On the dynamics of competing energy sources. Automatica, 47(7), 1357–1365.

    Google Scholar 

  72. Van Der Ploeg, F, & Withagen, C. (1991). Pollution control and the Ramsey problem. Environmental and Resource Economics, 1(2), 215–236.

    Google Scholar 

  73. World Bank Group. (2010). World development indicators 2014. Washington, DC: World Bank Publications.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Burak Ünveren, Cees Withagen, Fred Schroyen, Gunnar Eskeland, Linda Nøstbakken, Snorre Kverndok, Tetsu Haruyama, Eric Bond, Prudence Dato, Tuna Dinç, Can Askan Mavi, and two anonymous referees for many useful and constructive discussions on this topic, and Rögnvaldur Hannesson, Leif Sandal, and Sophie Lian Zhou for their detailed comments. We have also benefited from the comments and suggestions of the participants at the EAERE 22nd Annual Conference, Rokko Forum, the Bergen Economics of Energy and Environment Research Conference, and the Joint UiB-NHH PhD Workshop.

Funding

This work received financial support from the Center for Sustainable Energy Studies (CenSES).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tunç Durmaz.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A: Proof of Theorem 1

Proof

The transversality condition (TC) states that \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }e^{-\rho t}\lambda \left (t\right ) Z\left (t\right ) = 0 \) which is equivalent to − ρ + 𝜃λ + 𝜃Z < 0 being evaluated at the limit \(t\rightarrow \infty \).

From Eq. 3.21, the TC can be restated as

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \frac{n}{Z}-\frac{Z^{\nu }}{\lambda }<0\text{.} \end{array} $$

However, the solution to \(\dot {Z}=n-\delta Z\) is given by

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} Z=\frac{\int e^{\delta t}ndt+Z_{0}}{e^{\delta t}}. \end{array} $$

This implies

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \frac{n}{Z}=\frac{e^{\delta t}n}{\int e^{\delta t}ndt+Z_{0}}. \end{array} $$

Deduce that n/Z is the growth rate of

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \int e^{\delta t}ndt+Z_{0}, \end{array} $$

which is bounded from below by δ if n does not converge to zero.

Likewise, the solution to \(\dot {\lambda }=\left (\rho +\delta \right ) \lambda -Z^{\nu }\) is

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \lambda =\frac{-\int e^{-\left( \rho +\delta \right) t}Z^{\nu }dt+\lambda_{0}}{e^{-\left( \rho +\delta \right) t}} \end{array} $$

implying

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \frac{Z^{\nu }}{\lambda }=\frac{e^{-\left( \rho +\delta \right) t}Z^{\nu }}{ \lambda_{0}-\int e^{-\left( \rho +\delta \right) t}Z^{\nu }dt}. \end{array} $$

It follows that − Zν/λ is the growth rate of

$$ \lambda_{0}-\int e^{-\left( \rho +\delta \right) t}Z^{\nu }\text{.} $$

Nevertheless, λ ≥ 0 implies

$$ \lambda_{0}\geq \int e^{-\left( \rho +\delta \right) t}Z^{\nu }\text{.} $$
(A.1)

Note that \(e^{-\left (\rho +\delta \right ) t}Z^{\nu }\) is zero or negative in the limit. Otherwise, \(\int e^{-\left (\rho +\delta \right ) t}Z^{\nu }\) would diverge to infinity violating Eq. (A.1). Thus, Zν/λ converges to zero, which implies that

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \frac{n}{Z}-\frac{Z^{\nu }}{\lambda } \end{array} $$
(A.2)

converges to δ, thus contradicting the TC. Then, \(n\rightarrow 0\).

Recall that \(\sigma \equiv \frac {x}{y}=\alpha \beta \frac {q}{z}\). As nzq = z(1 − q/z), if \(n\rightarrow 0 \), then \(q/z\rightarrow 1\) as z > 0 for all t. On the basis of this result, we conclude that \(\sigma \rightarrow \alpha \beta \). □

Appendix B: Proof of Proposition 1

Proof

The optimal research policy at time t depends on the marginal social value of doing research in the two R&D sectors. Multiplying both sides of Eqs. 3.10 and 3.11 by eρtA and eρtB, respectively, and rearranging yields

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \dot{(e^{-\rho t} \lambda_{A} A)}&=&-e^{-\rho t}p A z^{\alpha} \ \text{ and}\\ \dot{(e^{-\rho t} \lambda_{B} B)}&=&-e^{-\rho t}{\mu} B x^{\beta}. \end{array} $$

Time integrating these two equations and taking into account the transversality conditions for the technology indexes A and B given by Eq. 3.12 allows us to write the sectoral (social) wages as

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \omega_{A}(t) \equiv a\lambda_{A}(t) A(t) &=& {\int}^{\infty}_{t} e^{-\rho(\tau- t)}a p(\tau)y(\tau)d\tau, \end{array} $$
(B.1)
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \omega_{B}(t) \equiv b\lambda_{B}(t) B(t) &=& {\int}^{\infty}_{t} e^{-\rho(\tau- t)}b {\mu}(\tau)q(\tau)d\tau, \end{array} $$
(B.2)

where ωA(t) and ωB(t) are the social wages in the resource-saving and abatement-augmenting research sectors, respectively. If ωA(t) > ωB(t), all resources for research will be allocated to improve the resource-saving technology at time t. To determine this, we write ωA(t) − ωB(t) using Eq. 3.5 as

$$ \omega_{A}(t)-\omega_{B}(t) =\!{\int}^{\infty}_{t} e^{-\rho(\tau- t)}\frac{\beta{\mu}(\tau)q(\tau)}{\sigma(\tau)} \left( \! a - \frac{b \sigma(\tau)}{\beta}\!\right) d\tau. $$
(B.3)

Because the FA constraint necessitates that σαβ, if a > αb, then ωA(t) − ωB(t) > 0 for all t. □

Appendix C: Proof of Proposition 2

Proof

As, by hypothesis, there is FA over \([\bar {t},\infty )\), the pollution stock will shrink at the constant rate of δ; that is, 𝜃Z = −δ. Integrating the equation of motion for the social cost of pollution (i.e., Eq. 3.9) over \([\bar {t},\infty )\) yields

$$ {\lambda}(t) = e^{(\rho+\delta)(t-\bar{t})}\left[\lambda(\bar{t})-Z(\bar{t})^{\nu} \frac{1-e^{-(\rho+(1+\nu)\delta)(t-\bar{t})}}{\rho+\delta(1+\nu)}\right]~\hspace{2.2mm} $$
(C.1)

When FA is practiced from \(\bar {t}\) onwards, Eq. C.1 yields the time path for the cost of pollution. Taking into account the transversality condition \(\underset {{\small {t \rightarrow \infty }}}{\lim } e^{-\rho t}{\lambda }(t)Z(t)= 0\), the social cost of pollution over \([\bar {t},\infty )\) simplifies to

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} {\lambda}(t)=\frac{Z(\bar{t})^{\nu} e^{-\nu \delta(t-\bar{t})}}{\rho+\delta(1+\nu)}, \end{array} $$
(C.2)

whose growth rate is 𝜃λ = −νδ.

As for \(\theta _{\bar {\mu }}\), note that

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} M(A(t),B_{0})& =& {\alpha}{}({\alpha\beta}{})^{-\frac{1-\alpha+\alpha\epsilon}{1-\alpha\beta}} \\ &&\left( A(t)^{1-\beta-\epsilon}B_{0}^{-(1-\alpha+\alpha\epsilon)}\right)^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha\beta}}, \end{array} $$

whose growth rate is

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} a{(1-\beta -\epsilon)}/{(1-\alpha\beta)}. \end{array} $$

By definition, \(\bar {\mu }(t) \equiv M(A(t),B_{0})\ \bar {\varphi }_{\lambda }\). Thus, the growth rate of \(\bar {\mu }\) is equal to that of M(A(t),B0). This completes the proof. □

Appendix D: Proof of Proposition 3

Proof

If \(\bar {\mu }(0)> {\lambda }(0)\), then n(0) > 0, that is, PA is optimal at time t = 0. However, − δν > a(1 − β𝜖)/(1 − αβ) implies \(\theta _{\bar {\mu }} < \theta _{\bar {\lambda }}\), where \(\bar {\lambda }\) denotes the social cost of pollution when the pollution flow is fully abated. Accordingly, the growth rate of \(\bar {\lambda }\) remains higher than that of \(\bar {\mu }\) at all times. Thus, after a certain point in time, that is, when \(t=\bar {t}>0\), \(\bar {\mu }(\bar {t}) = {\lambda }(\bar {t})\). Consequently, n(t) = 0 for \(t\geq \bar {t}\). □

Appendix E: Proof of Corollary 1

By hypothesis, αb > a and 𝜖 > 1. These two inequalities imply that \( {\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{A}>\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{B}}\), where \(\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{B} \equiv -b(1-\alpha + \alpha \epsilon )/(1-\alpha \beta )\). During FA, the net opportunity cost of pollution shrinks at the rate of \(\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{A}s_{A}+\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{B} s_{B}\). Since \(\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{A} >\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{B}\), any convex combination of \(\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{A}\) and \(\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{B}\) is smaller than \(\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{A}\). Hence, when \(\bar {\mu }(\bar {t})\leq \lambda (\bar {t})\) and considering that research can take place in both sectors, \(\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{A}s_{A}+\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{B} s_{B}(\leq \bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{A})\), the net opportunity cost of pollution always stays lower than the social cost of pollution if \(-\delta \nu >\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{A}\). Consequently, \(-\delta \nu >\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{A}\) provides a sufficient condition for FA to be pursued permanently from \(\bar {t}\) onward.

Appendix F: Proof of Corollary 2

Proof

Given that \(-\delta \nu > \bar {\theta }^{A}_{\lambda } > \bar {\theta }^{B}_{\lambda }\) and, therefore, \( \theta _{\bar {\mu }} < \theta _{{\bar {\lambda }}}\), the marginal cost of fully abating the pollution will always be lower than its social cost from time \(\bar {t}\) onward; that is, \( \bar {\mu }(t)\leq {\lambda }(t)\) and, in turn, σ(t) = αβ for \(t\geq \bar {t}\). The difference between the social wages in the two research sectors during the FA regime can be written as

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \omega_{B}(\bar{t}) -\omega_{A}(\bar{t}) ={\int}^{\infty}_{\bar{t}} e^{-\rho(\tau- \bar{t})}\frac{\beta{\mu}(\tau)q(\tau)}{\alpha \beta} \left( {\alpha b }- a\right) d \tau, \end{array} $$

where we substitute αβ for σ in Eq. B.3. Since αb > a, the social wage in the abatement-augmenting research sector is higher for \(t\in [\bar {t},\infty )\).

Recall that \(\bar {\mu }(t)\equiv M\left (A(t),B(t)\right )\bar {\varphi }_{\lambda }\) and \({\lambda }({t})= {Z(t)^{\nu } e^{-\nu \delta (t-\bar {t})}}/{\left (\rho +\delta (1+\nu )\right )}\). If \(M\left (A(0),B(0)\right )\bar {\varphi }_{\lambda } \leq {Z(0)^{\nu }}/{\left (\rho +\delta (1+\nu )\right )}\) and \(-\delta \nu >\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{A}\), the pollution flow is fully abated, and all scientists are directed at the B sector from t = 0 onward. □

Appendix G: Proof of Corollary 3

Proof

When the net opportunity cost of pollution is bigger than the social cost of pollution, that is, \(\bar {\mu }(0)> {\lambda }(0)\), then PA is optimal at time t = 0. Thus, n(0) > 0. However, \(-\delta \nu >\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{A} \geq \bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{A}s_{A}+\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{B} s_{B}\) (see Appendix E for details) implies \(\theta _{\bar {\mu }} < \theta _{\bar {\lambda }}\). Accordingly, the growth rate of \(\bar {\lambda }\) remains higher than that of \(\bar {\mu }\) at all times. Thus, after a certain point in time, that is, when \(t=\bar {t}>0\), the net opportunity cost of pollution gets equal to the social cost of pollution \(\bar {\mu }(\bar {t}) = {\lambda }(\bar {t})\). Consequently, FA is pursued permanently for \(t \geq \bar {t}\). □

Appendix H: Proof of Proposition 4

Proof

From Eq. 3.30, 𝜃σ > 0 until FA is attained. Since 𝜃σ > 0, it is optimal to allocate all resources to the abatement-augmenting research for \(t>\tilde {t}\), where \(\sigma (\tilde {t})=a \beta /b\). Thus, ωA(t) − ωB(t) for \(t>\tilde {t}\), where \(\omega _{A}(t) - \omega _{B}(t)\vert _{t>\tilde {t}}\) equals the finite sum

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&{\int}^{\bar{t}}_{\tilde{t}} e^{-\rho(\tau- t)}\frac{\beta{\mu}(\tau)q(\tau)}{\sigma(\tau)} \left( a-\frac{b \sigma(\tau)}{\beta}\right) d\tau \\ &&-\frac{(\alpha b - a)A(\bar{t})^{\frac{2-\beta - \epsilon}{\alpha\beta}}B(\bar{t})^{-\frac{\alpha(\epsilon-1)}{1-\alpha\beta}}}{\left( (\alpha\beta)^{\frac{\alpha\beta}{1-\alpha\beta}}(1 - \alpha\beta)\right)^{\epsilon-1}(\rho(1 - \alpha\beta)+\alpha b(\epsilon-1))}\!<\!0. \end{array} $$

Depending on the initial conditions (A(0),Z(0),B(0)) (see Appendix J), the intersection of d𝜃λ/d𝜃Z with the optimal trajectory defines the optimal \(\left (\theta _{\lambda }(0),\theta _{Z}(0)\right )\). Then, given the initial values for the state variables, λ(0) and σ(0) can be determined from \(\lambda (0) = Z(0)^{\nu }/\left (\rho + \delta - \theta _{\lambda }(0)\right )\) and

$$ \frac{\sigma(0)^{-{(1-\beta)\bar{\theta}_{\lambda}^{B}/b}}}{(1-\sigma(0))^{\epsilon}} = \frac{\lambda(0)}{M(A(0),B(0))}, $$

respectively.

Depending on the initial conditions, if σ(0) is sufficiently low such that abσ(0)/β > 0 and ωA(0) − ωB(0)|t> 0 > 0, then sA(0) = 1. Because \(\omega _{A}(t) - \omega _{B}(t)\vert _{t>\tilde {t}}<0\), an abatement-augmenting research regime has to begin before \(\hat {t}(<\tilde {t})\).

A mixed-research regime, in which resources are allocated to both research sectors, cannot be maintained because 𝜃σ > 0 (cf. Eq. 3.30) until the time when \(\sigma (\bar {t})=\alpha \beta \). The necessary condition for a mixed-research regime at time \(\hat {t}\) is \(\omega _{A}(t)-\omega _{B}(t)= 0\vert _{t=\hat {t}}\). Sustaining this regime necessitates

$$ \frac{d\left( \omega_{A}(t)-\omega_{B}(t)\right)}{d t}\vert_{t=\hat{t}} = 0, $$

and consequently, σ = aβ/b. Nevertheless, because 𝜃σ > 0, the economy switches from one research regime to the other one.

In Appendix L, we conduct further analysis and show that an interior solution for scientific activity that can permanently be sustained cannot be part of an optimal solution. □

Appendix I: Economic Dynamics During a PA Phase

Using Eqs. 3.273.28, and 3.30, the difference between the output growth rates in the two regimes can be calculated to yield

$$ {\theta^{A}_{y}} - {\theta^{B}_{y}} = \frac{a -\alpha b}{1-\alpha \beta }- \frac{\alpha (1-\beta)}{(1-\alpha \beta) K_{\lambda}(\sigma) }\left( \bar{\theta}_{\lambda}^{B} -\bar{\theta}_{\lambda}^{A} \right) $$

where \({\theta ^{i}_{j}}\) denotes the growth rate of variable j in research regime i ∈{A,B}. One can calculate that

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &{\theta^{A}_{y}} - {\theta^{B}_{y}} >0 ~&\text{ if } \hspace{3mm}\sigma< \frac{(1-\beta)a }{a(1-\beta)+ (\alpha b - a)}, \\ &{\theta^{A}_{y}} - {\theta^{B}_{y}} \leq 0 ~&\text{ otherwise}. \end{array} $$
(I.1)

When the switch to the abatement-augmenting research regime happens for a sufficiently small share of abatement expenditure, the economic growth during the transition to the FA regime would be smaller than the one under a resource-saving research regime.

Furthermore, the growth rate of the abatement expenditure is always higher in an abatement-augmenting research regime:

$$ {\theta^{A}_{x}} - {\theta^{B}_{x}} = \frac{a -\alpha b}{1-\alpha \beta } + \frac{1-\alpha}{(1-\alpha \beta) K_{\lambda}(\sigma) }\left( \bar{\theta}_{\lambda}^{B} -\bar{\theta}_{\lambda}^{A} \right)<0. $$
(I.2)

Accordingly, the growth rate of consumption is smaller:

$$ {\theta^{A}_{c}} - {\theta^{B}_{c}} = \frac{-(1-\alpha\beta)\left[(1-\beta)a +(1-\alpha) b \sigma\right]}{(1-\beta)\bar{\theta}_{\lambda}^{B}/b +(1-\alpha)\bar{\theta}_{\lambda}^{A}/a} . $$
(I.3)

Appendix J: Initial Conditions

First, the dynamical system given by Eq. 3.21 can equivalently be written as

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \rho+\delta - \theta_{\lambda}& =& \frac{Z^{\nu}}{{M(A,B_{0})\varphi_{\lambda}(\sigma)}}, \\ \theta_{Z} + \delta &=& \frac{N(A,B_{0})\varphi_{Z}(\sigma)}{Z}. \end{array} $$
(J.1)

Using Eqs. 3.163.17, and 3.21, the derivatives of 𝜃λ and 𝜃Z with respect to σ yield

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \frac{d\theta_{\lambda}}{d\sigma}&=& \frac{(\rho+\delta - \theta_{\lambda}) K_{\lambda}(\sigma)}{\sigma}, \\ \frac{d\theta_{Z}}{d\sigma}&=& -\frac{(\theta_{Z} + \delta) K_{Z}(\sigma)}{\sigma}. \end{array} $$

Eliminating σ, Eq. J.1 implicitly defines 𝜃λ(𝜃Z; A,B,Z) such that

$$ \frac{ d\theta_{\lambda}}{d\theta_{Z}} = -\frac{\rho+\delta - \theta_{\lambda}}{\theta_{Z} + \delta}\kappa(\sigma)<0. $$
(J.2)

For a given initial vector (A(0),Z(0),B0), the intersection of this curve with the optimal trajectory OP defines the optimal initial vector \(\left (\theta _{\lambda }(0),\theta _{Z}(0)\right )\). Given the initial pollution stock, Z(0), the initial social cost of pollution can be determined from \({\lambda (0) = Z(0)^{\nu }/\left (\rho + \delta - \theta _{\lambda }(0)\right )}\).

Appendix K: No Technical Progress

Suppose that a = b = 0. Thus, \(\dot {A}=\dot {B}= 0\), and A(t) = A0 and B(t) = B0 for all t. Owing to the monotonic relationship between σ and λ (see Eq. 3.20), σ can be deemed a function of λ. Substituting σ, in n(σ) enables us to defineη(λ) ≡ n(σ(λ)), which is a strictly decreasing function of λ. Because the support of λ is \((0,M \bar {\varphi }_{\lambda }]\), owing to the boundary values of σ which are 0 and αβ. η(λ) varies between \(+\infty \) and 0 as λ varies between 0 and \(M \bar {\varphi }_{\lambda }\).

When there is no technological change, the optimal paths of Z and λ are the solution of the following autonomous dynamic system described by Eqs. 2.3 and 3.9:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \dot{\lambda}&=&\left( \rho+\delta \right){\lambda}-Z^{\nu} \ \text{ and} \end{array} $$
(K.1)
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \dot{Z}&=&\eta({\lambda})-\delta Z. \end{array} $$
(K.2)

Figure 3 depicts the phase plane for (Z,λ) by plotting the isoclines \(\dot {\lambda }= 0\) and \(\dot {Z}= 0\). First, the isocline \(\dot {\lambda }= 0\) is defined by λ = Zν/(ρ + δ), which gives an increasing relation between Z and λ. Furthermore, \({\lambda }\leq M \bar {\varphi }_{\lambda }\) since the co-state variable is non-negative; that is, γ ≥ 0. Secondly, the isocline \(\dot {Z}= 0\) is defined by η(λ) = δZ, which gives a strictly decreasing relationship between the social cost of pollution, λ, and pollution stock, Z. Thus, λ varies between \(M \bar {\varphi }_{\lambda }\) and 0 when \(Z\rightarrow 0\) and \(Z\rightarrow \infty \), respectively

Appendix L: Mixed-Research Regime

From Eqs. 3.7 and 3.8, an interior solution for the scientific activity requires

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \omega_{A}\equiv a \lambda_{A} A = \omega_{B} \equiv b \lambda_{B} B=\omega, \end{array} $$

where ωA(t) and ωA(t) are the social wages in the resource-saving and abatement-augmenting research sectors, respectively. Multiplying both sides of Eqs. 3.10 and 3.11 by eρtA and eρtB, respectively, and rearranging yields

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \dot{(e^{-\rho t}a \lambda_{A} A)}&=&e^{-\rho t}a A p z^{\alpha} \ \text{ and } \\ \dot{(e^{-\rho t}b \lambda_{B} B)}&=&e^{-\rho t}b B {\mu} x^{\beta}. \end{array} $$

The equality of social wages allows the equalization of these two expressions and gives us apy = bμq. Using this relationship and Eq. 3.5 yields \(\sigma ^{M}=\beta \frac {a}{b},\) which is, indeed, a constant. Thus, when there is research in both sectors, and the two sectors are active over \([0,\infty )\), the share of the abatement expenditure in the GDP is fixed. The fact that abatement cannot exceed the pollution flow, that is, σαβ, leads to σMαβaαb. Therefore, to justify a mixed-research regime, the innovative capacity b has to be sufficiently higher than a. Further, as, by hypothesis, b > a/α, then, σM < αβ; that is, a permanent mixed-research regime in which the social sectoral wages are equal can only occur when the pollution is always partially abated.

As σ is parametrically determined, μ and n become functions of the technology indexes A and B only (see Eqs. 3.16 and 3.17). From Eqs. 3.16 and 3.17, we can calculate the growth rate for the social cost of pollution and the net level of pollution as \(\theta _{\lambda } = \frac {\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{A}}{a}\theta _{A}+\frac {\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{B}}{b}\theta _{B}\) (or, equivalently, \(\theta _{\lambda } = {\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{A}}s_{A}+{\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{B}}s_{B}<0\)) and \(\theta _{n}=\frac {\bar {\theta }^{A}_{Z}}{a}\theta _{A} + \frac {\bar {\theta }^{B}_{Z}}{b}\theta _{B}\) (or, \(\theta _{n} = {\bar {\theta }_{Z}^{A}}s_{A}+{\bar {\theta }_{Z}^{B}}s_{B}>0\)), respectively. Accordingly, time differentiating the dynamic system given by Eq. 3.21 yields

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \frac{\dot{\theta}_{\lambda}}{\rho+\delta - \theta_{\lambda}}&=&\frac{\bar{\theta}_{\lambda}^{A}}{a}\theta_{A}+\frac{\bar{\theta}_{\lambda}^{B}}{b}\theta_{B}-\nu \theta_{Z}, \end{array} $$
(L.1)
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \frac{\dot{\theta}_{Z}}{\theta_{Z}+\delta}&=&\frac{\bar{\theta}^{A}_{Z}}{a}\theta_{A} + \frac{\bar{\theta}^{B}_{Z}}{b}\theta_{B} -\theta_{Z}. \end{array} $$
(L.2)

Following this, the isoclines \(\dot {\theta }_{\lambda }= 0\) and \(\dot {\theta }_{Z}= 0\) are

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \theta_{\lambda} &=& \nu \theta_{Z} \ \text{ and} \end{array} $$
(L.3)
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \theta_{Z} &=& \frac{\bar{\theta}^{B}_{Z}-\bar{\theta}^{A}_{Z}}{\bar{\theta}_{\lambda}^{A}-\bar{\theta}_{\lambda}^{B}}\bar{\theta}_{\lambda}^{B} +\bar{\theta}^{B}_{Z}- \frac{\bar{\theta}^{B}_{Z}-\bar{\theta}^{A}_{Z}}{\bar{\theta}_{\lambda}^{A}-\bar{\theta}_{\lambda}^{B}}{\theta}_{\lambda}. \end{array} $$
(L.4)

The dynamics of 𝜃λ and 𝜃Z in a mixed-research regime are pictured in Fig. 4. It can be seen that the isocline \(\dot {\theta }_{Z}= 0\) is the segment joining the points \((\bar {\theta }^{A}_{Z},\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{A})\) and \((\bar {\theta }^{B}_{Z},\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{B})\). It is immediately verified that if b > a/α, \(\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{A}>\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{B}\). Furthermore, σM < 1 implies that βa < b. Thus, \(\bar {\theta }^{A}_{Z}<\bar {\theta }^{B}_{Z}\). As 𝜃A = asA and 𝜃B = bsB, \(\theta _{\lambda } = {\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{A}}s_{A}+{\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{B}}s_{B}\). Then, the positivity constraint sA ≥ 0 is equivalent to \(\theta _{\lambda }\geq \bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{B}\). Moreover, 1 ≥ sA implies \(\theta _{\lambda }\leq \bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{A}\). Therefore, in a mixed-research regime \(\theta _{\lambda }\in \left [\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{B},\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{A}\right ]\).

Fig. 4
figure 4

Mixed-research regime: phase diagram analysis

We see that all trajectories converge in finite time either toward the abatement efficiency, B, border (i.e., the horizontal line for \(\bar {\theta }^{B}_{\lambda }\)), or toward the production efficiency A border (i.e., the \(\bar {\theta }^{A}_{\lambda }\) horizontal). It is, therefore, impossible to permanently sustain a mixed-research regime. This is also justified by Theorem 1 stating that the share of the abatement expenditure will eventually converge to its upper bound αβ, thus, violating \(\sigma =\beta \frac {a}{b}\) in a mixed-research regime.

In a mixed regime, the dynamics of the resources allocated for research is determined by the following equation:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} s_{A} = \frac{\theta_{\lambda} - \bar{\theta}_{\lambda}^{B}}{\bar{\theta}_{\lambda}^{A} - \bar{\theta}_{\lambda}^{B}}. \end{array} $$
(L.5)

Because dsA/d𝜃λ > 0, the resources allocated for the resource-saving research increases when 𝜃λ approaches the \(\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{A}\). Conversely, the resources allocated for abatement-augmenting research increases when 𝜃λ approaches the \(\bar {\theta }_{\lambda }^{B}\).

Because \(-\delta \nu > \bar {\theta }^{B}_{\lambda }\), σ steadily grows until FA is attained (i.e., when σ(t) = 0). During the PA phase, a mixed-research regime which can be sustained cannot exist. During the FA phase, a mixed-research regime cannot exist because the social wage in the abatement-augmenting research sector would always be higher. Instead, it is only when the pollution stock, or low level of resource-saving or abatement-augmenting technologies, are sufficiently low that the social planner would find it optimal partially abate the pollution and start allocating resources to augment the resource-saving technology (cf. Eq. B.3). Nevertheless, because \(-\delta \nu > \bar {\theta }^{A}_{\lambda }\), the share of the expenditure in the economy that is spent on abatement increases in time. This can be observed from Eq. 3.23. When σ gets sufficiently high, and before abatement is fully abated, the resources for research are allocated to improve only the abatement-augmenting technologies. This phase starts right after the instant when ωA(t) = ωB(t).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Amigues, JP., Durmaz, T. A Two-Sector Model of Economic Growth with Endogenous Technical Change and Pollution Abatement. Environ Model Assess 24, 703–725 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-019-09660-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-019-09660-2

Keywords

Navigation