Skip to main content
Log in

Assessing the Sustainability of Optimal Pollution Paths in a World with Inertia

  • Published:
Environmental Modeling & Assessment Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Most formal optimal pollution control models in environmental economics assume a constant natural assimilative capacity, despite the biophysical evidence on feedback effects that can degrade this environmental function, as is the case with the reduction of ocean carbon sinks in the context of climate change. The few models that do consider this degradation establish a bijective relation between the pollution stock and the assimilative capacity, thus ignoring the inertia mechanism at stake. Indeed the level of assimilative capacity is not solely determined by the current pollution stock but also by the history of this stock and by the length of time the ecosystem remains above the degradation threshold. We propose an inertia assessment tool that tests the sustainability of any benchmark optimal pollution path when the inertia of the assimilative capacity degradation process is taken into account. Our simulations show a strong sensitivity to both the inertia degradation speed and the discount rate, thus stressing the need for increased monitoring of natural assimilative capacity in environmental policies.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The assimilative function A(Z) is a bijective function of the pollution stock Z.

  2. The implication that environmental damages may be compensated, totally or up to a point, by higher consumption can raise both social and environmental concerns with respect to the resulting policy. Although this compensation can make sense from a social planner’s perspective, it may hide inequalities if the agents actually suffering from the environmental damage are not the same as those who enjoy the economic benefits of pollution. In addition, it can be argued that when environmental damage causes irreversible degradation in natural capital (major biodiversity loss for instance), no compensation should be allowed to take place.

  3. An economic intuition often claimed to explain this relation is that the assimilative capacity level can be interpreted as a component of the discount rate, hence the higher α0 the higher Zss.

  4. It must be noted that irreversibility is present once the pollution stock reaches Zc since it is then impossible to reduce the pollution stock with a zero assimilative capacity and no external restoration.

  5. Our model displays similarities with [22] as we share the same inspirations in the literature. However, we do not abide by their strong assumptions on assimilative capacity restoration that make their model less relevant in tackling the crucial case of GHG.

  6. It must be noted that we have modified the notations of the authors to make them fit the ones we used so far and that here the inverted U-shape function refers to the total absolute assimilative capacity α(t) ∗ Z(t), not to the image function α(Z(t)).

  7. Variables with no superscript refer to the variables in the system with inertia while variables with a superscript refer to the variables obtained in the benchmark model without assimilative capacity degradation.

References

  1. Keeler, E., Spence, M., Zeckhauser, R. (1972). The optimal control of pollution. Journal of Economic Theory, 4, 19–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Plourde, C.G. (1972). A model of waste accumulation and disposal. The Canadian Journal of Economics, 5 (1), 119–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Schuster, U., & Watson, A. (2007). A variable and decreasing sink for atmospheric CO2 in the North Atlantic. Journal of Geophysical Research, C11006, 112.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Le Quéré, C., Radenbeck, C., Buitenhuis, E.T., Conway, T.J., Langenfelds, R., Gomez, A., Labuschagne, C., Ramonet, M., Nakazawa, T., Metzl, N., Gillett, N., Heimann, M. (2007). Saturation of the Southern Ocean CO2 sink due to recent climate change. Science, 316(5832), 1735–1738.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  5. International Climate Change Taskforce. (2005). Meeting the climate challenge : recommandations of the International Climate Change Taskforce.

  6. Plattner, G.-K., Joos, F., Stocker, T., Marchal, O. (2007). Feedback mechanisms and sensitivities of ocean carbon uptake under global warming. Tellus, 53B, 564–592.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Heinze, C., Meyer, S., Goris, N., Anderson, L., Steinfeldt, R., Chang, N., Le Quéré, C., Bakker, D.C.E. (2015). The ocean carbon sink - impacts, vulnerabilities and challenges. Earth System Dynamics, 6, 327–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Watson, A.J., Schuster, U., Bakker, D.C.E., Bates, N.R., Corbière, A., González-Dávila, M., Friedrich, T., Hauck, J., Heinze, C., Johannessen, T., Körtzinger, A., Metzl, N., Olafsson, J., Olsen, A., Oschlies, A., Padin, X.A., Pfeil, B., Santana-Casiano, J.M., Steinhoff, T., Telszewski, M., Rios, A.F., Wallace, D.W.R., Wanninkhof, R. (2009). Tracking the variable North Atlantic sink for atmospheric CO2. Science, 326, 1391–1393.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  9. Schuster, U., Watson, A.J., Bates, N.R., Corbière, A., Gonzalez-Davila, M., Metzl, N., Pierrot, D., Santana-Casiano, M. (2009). Trends in North Atlantic sea-surface CO2 from 1990 to 2006. Deep-Sea Res. Pt. II, 56, 620–629.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  10. Forster, B. (1975). Optimal pollution control with a nonconstant exponential rate of decay. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 2, 1–6.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Tahvonen, O., & Salo, S. (1996). Nonconvexities in optimal pollution accumulation. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 31, 160–177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Toman, M.A., & Withagen, C. (2000). Accumulative pollution, clean technology and policy design. Resource and Energy Economics, 22, 367–384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Tahvonen, O., & Withagen, C. (1996). Optimality of irreversible pollution accumulation. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 20, 1775–1795.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Hediger, W. (2009). Sustainable development with stock pollution. Environment and Development Economics, 14(6), 759–780.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Krawczyk, J.B., & Serea, O.-S. (2013). When can it be not optimal to adopt a new technology? A viability theory solution to a two-stage optimal control problem of new technology adoption. Optimal Control Applications and Methods, 34(2), 127–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Perman, R., Ma, Y., McGilvray, J. (1996). Natural resource and environmental economics. London: Longman.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Forster, B. (1973). Optimal consumption planning in a polluted environment. Economic Record, 49(4), 534–545.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Holling, C. (1973). Resilience and stability of ecological systems. Annual Review of Ecology and Systematics, 4, 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Hanson, G.C., Groffman, P.M., Gold, A.J. (1994). Symptoms of nitrogen saturation in a riparian wetland. Ecological Applications, 4, 750–756.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Prieur, F. (2009). The environmental Kuznets curve in a world of irreversibility. Economic Theory, 40(1), 57–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Leandri, M. (2009). The shadow price of assimilative capacity in optimal flow pollution control. Ecological Economics, 68(4), 1020–1031.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. El Ouardighi, F., Benchekroun, H., Grass, D. (2014). Controlling pollution and environmental absorption capacity. Annals of Operations Research, 220(1), 111–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Pearce, D.W. (1976). The limits of cost-benefit analysis as a guide to environmental policy. Kyklos, 29(1), 97–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Pezzey, J.C.V. (1996). An analysis of scientific and economic studies of pollution assimilation. Working Paper 1996/7, Center for Resource and Environmental Studies, the Australian National University.

  25. Godard, O. (2006). La pensée économique face à l’environnement. In Leroux, A. (Ed.) leçons de Philosophie Economique - Volume 2 : Economie normative et philosophie morale, Paris, Economica (pp. 241–277).

  26. Cesar, H., & de Zeeuw, A. (1994). Sustainability and the greenhouse effect: robustness analysis of the assimilation function. In Carraro, C., & Filar, J. (Eds.) Control and game theoretical models of the environment (pp. 25–45). Birkhäuser: Boston.

  27. Martinet, V., & Doyen, L. (2007). Sustainability of an economy with an exhaustible resource: a viable control approach. Resource and Energy Economics, 29(1), 17–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Schubert, K. (2008). La valeur du carbone : niveau initial et profil temporel optimaux. In Quinet, A. (Ed.) La valeur tutélaire du carbone. Centre d’Analyse Stratégique, 2 (pp. 195–210).

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful to the FAERE Working Papers anonymous referee for stimulating comments. We also thank the participants of the 2016 EAERE and 2016 FAERE conference for their feedback. All remaining errors are ours. Marc Leandri is thankful to INRA-LAMETA for the research fellowship that permitted him to initiate this research. The authors are grateful to the anonymous referees and to the editor and advisory editor for their stimulating and helpful comments.

Funding

This work was supported by the ANR GREEN-Econ research project (ANR-16-CE03-0005) and the ANR-10-LabX-11-01.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marc Leandri.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A.1 The Benchmark Model

Let us solve the benchmark optimal pollution control problem with constant assimilative capacity:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} && \max_{y(t)}{{\int}_{0}^{\infty}\left[ f(y(t))-D(Z(t))\right] e^{-\rho t}dt}, \\ && \:\:\text{s.t.} \\ && \:\:\dot{Z}(t)=y(t)-\alpha_{0} Z(t), \quad Z(0)=Z_{0}>0,\\ \end{array} $$

with the standard properties: f, the concave benefit function from pollution; D, the environmental damage function (increasing and convex); ρ, the discount rate; Z0, the initial pollution stock; and α0 the constant assimilative capacity (0 < α0)

We thus get the following Hamiltonian with λ the co-state variable associated to Z

$$ \mathcal{H}_{c}(t)=f(y(t))-D(Z(t))+\lambda (t)(y(t)-\alpha_{0} Z(t)), $$
(14)

which yields the standard first-order conditions

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} && f^{\prime }(y(t))=-\lambda (t), \end{array} $$
(15)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} && \dot{\lambda}(t)=(\rho +\alpha_{0})\lambda (t)+D^{\prime }(Z(t)). \end{array} $$
(16)

1.1.1 A.1.1 Benchmark Steady State

Given the dynamics of Z and λ and the properties of f and D, a unique Zss exists such that

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} && f^{\prime}(\alpha_{0} Z_{ss}) >0, \\ && f^{\prime}(\alpha_{0} Z_{ss})(\rho+\alpha_{0})- D^{\prime}(Z_{ss})= 0. \end{array} $$
(17)

Let us introduce the standard functional forms commonly found in the literature that we will use for further calculations and that respect the basic properties required:

$$f(y){}={}cy-\frac{b}{2}y^{2}, \:\: with\;c,b{}>{}0,\:\: \quad D{}(Z){}={}\frac{d}{2}Z^{2}{}, \:\: with\;d{}>{}0. $$

With these functional forms, Eq. 17 is tantamount to

$$ Z_{ss}=\frac{(\rho+\alpha_{0})c}{(\rho+\alpha_{0})b\alpha_{0}+d}. $$
(18)

1.1.2 A.1.2 Characterization of the Optimal Path

We can determine analytically the expression of Z(t), λ(t) and y(t) along the optimal pollution path by solving the first-order conditions (15), (16) for the quadratic linear functional forms.

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&Z^{*}(t) = e^{- \bar{\rho} t} (Z(0) - Z_{ss}) + Z_{ss}, \end{array} $$
(19)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&y^{*}(t)=\frac{c+\lambda}{b}, \end{array} $$
(20)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&\lambda^{*}(t) = b (- \rho + \alpha_{0}) e^{- \bar{\rho} t} (Z(0) \,-\, Z_{ss}) \,-\, \frac{d}{\rho + \alpha_{0}} Z_{ss}, \end{array} $$
(21)

where \( \bar {\rho } = \sqrt {(\rho /2 + \alpha _{0})^{2} + d/b} - \rho /2 >0\). \( \bar {\rho } \) is the speed of convergence of the dynamic.

Equations 19 and 20 will enable us to analyze the comparative statics we are interested in but they will also be used in Section 4 to simulate numerically benchmark optimal pollution paths and to test their behavior in the presence of inertia.

1.1.3 A.1.3 Proof of Proposition 1

Proof The proof is straightforward. According to Eq. 1 we have

$$\frac{\partial Z_{ss}}{\partial{\alpha_{0}}} = \left( c \frac{d - b (\alpha_{0} + \rho)^{2}}{(d + \rho \alpha_{0} b + {\alpha_{0}^{2}} b)^{2}}\right). $$

Hence, defining \(\bar {\alpha }= \sqrt {d/b} - \rho \)

$$\frac{\partial Z_{ss}}{\partial{\alpha_{0}}} \gtreqqless 0 \iff \alpha_{0} \lesseqqgtr \bar{\alpha}. $$
  • if \(\rho > \sqrt {d/b}\), \(\bar {\alpha }<0\) and thus ∀α0 > 0 we have \(\alpha _{0} >\bar {\alpha }\) and \(\frac {\partial Z_{ss}}{\partial {\alpha }} < 0\).

  • if \(\rho < \sqrt {d/b}\) then \(\frac {\partial Z_{ss}}{\partial {\alpha _{0}}} > 0\) for \(0 < \alpha _{0} < \bar {\alpha }\) and \(\frac {\partial Z_{ss}}{\partial {\alpha _{0}}} < 0\) for \(\bar {\alpha } < \alpha _{0}\).

1.1.4 A.1.4 Assimilative Capacity and Social Welfare at the Steady State

We check that the intuitive positive effect of α on the social welfare at the steady state is actually true. The social welfare can be written as:

$$W(\alpha)=f(\alpha Z_{ss}(\alpha)) - D(Z_{ss}(\alpha)). $$

Hence, taking into account (17)

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \frac{\partial{W}}{\partial{\alpha}}&=&\left( \alpha \frac{\partial{Z_{ss}}}{\partial{\alpha}} + Z_{ss}(\alpha) \right) f^{\prime}(\alpha Z_{ss}(\alpha))\\ &&-\frac{\partial{Z_{ss}}}{\partial{\alpha}}D^{\prime}(Z_{ss}(\alpha))\\ &=& \left( - \rho \frac{\partial{Z_{ss}}}{\partial{\alpha}}+ Z_{ss}(\alpha) \right) f^{\prime}(\alpha Z_{ss}(\alpha)). \end{array} $$

As by first-order condition f(αZss(α)) > 0, when \(\frac {\partial {Z_{ss}}}{\partial {\alpha }} <0\) we have \(\frac {\partial {W}}{\partial {\alpha }} >0\). Nevertheless, with our specific forms we can prove that it is always positive, in fact:

$$W(\alpha) = \frac{1}{2}\frac{ c^{2} (\alpha + \rho) (d \alpha + \rho \alpha^{2} b + b \alpha^{3} - d \rho)}{(d + \rho \alpha b + b \alpha^{2})^{2}}, $$

and thus

$$\frac{d W(\alpha)}{d \alpha} = \frac{c^{2} d (b (\rho+ \alpha)^{3} + d\alpha)}{(d + \rho \alpha b + b \alpha^{2})^{3}} > 0. $$

1.2 A.2 Injection of a Benchmark Optimal Path

1.2.1 A.2.1 Proof of Proposition 2

Proof

  1. 1.

    is straightforward.

  2. 2.

    if a steady state with α > 0 exists, we have

    $$\alpha_{ss} Z_{ss} =\lim\limits_{t\to \infty} y^{*}(t). $$

    Hence, according to Eq. 8:

    $$Z_{ss} =\frac{\alpha_{0}}{ \alpha_{ss}} Z_{ss}^{*}. $$

    A steady state exists if Eq. 10 is verified, given that α > 0, i.e. if

    $$ Z_{ss} \leq\bar{Z} \quad \iff \frac{\alpha_{0}}{ \alpha_{ss}} Z_{ss}^{*}\leq\bar{Z} \quad \iff Z_{ss}^{*}\leq \frac{\alpha_{ss}}{\alpha_{0}} \bar{Z}. $$
    (22)

1.2.2 A.2.2 Proof of Condition (12)

Let us state the following corollary to Proposition 2:

Corollary 3

If \(Z^{*}_{ss}>\bar {Z}\) , the BP is not sustainable.

Proof

  • If αss = 0, then according to Proposition 2 no sustainable steady state can be reached.

  • If αss > 0, since by definition αssα0, then \(Z^{*}_{ss}>\bar {Z} \Rightarrow \frac {Z_{ss}^{*}}{ \alpha _{ss}}>\frac {\bar {Z}}{\alpha _{0}}\)

    Condition (22) is not verified and no sustainable steady state can be reached.

Corollary 3 can be translated with our functional forms into the following condition. Let us define ρu such that

$$\rho_{u}=\frac{d\bar{Z}-\alpha_{0}c+b{\alpha_{0}^{2}}\bar{Z}}{c-b\alpha_{0}\bar{Z}}. $$

We have

$$ \rho> \rho_{u} \Rightarrow Z_{ss}^{*} >\bar{Z}. $$
(23)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Leandri, M., Tidball, M. Assessing the Sustainability of Optimal Pollution Paths in a World with Inertia. Environ Model Assess 24, 249–263 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-018-9612-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-018-9612-8

Keywords

Navigation