Skip to main content
Log in

Global financial crisis as a phenomenon of stock market overshooting

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Empirica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Inspired by Dornbusch’s model of exchange rate overshooting we develop a theory of stock market behaviour and its impact on the real economy. The idea is that stock market prices overshoot and undershoot their long-run equilibrium values which are determined by the development in the real economy. The overshooting is triggered primarily by a loose monetary policy. With our model we explain the genesis of the global financial crisis (GFC) 2008/2009 primarily as the result of a loose monetary policy in the USA. Following the overshooting and crash in the stock market the real economy dropped into a recession. After modelling the interaction of three markets with different speed of adjustment—money, stocks and goods—for a closed economy we expand it to an open economy and lastly study the spillovers of a financial market crisis between countries (from a large to a small country) by introducing the transmission channels of external trade or cross-border financial transactions. A long-lasting monetary easing as exhibiting by the Fed and the ECB since 2007 and 2008, respectively could—according to our model—generate another boom-bust cycle.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This term was coined by Krugman (2009) to differentiate the economic situation in 2009 from that of the “Great Depression” in 1929–1933. The “Great Depression” received its name from Lionel Robbins (1934).

  2. Some (see Cassidy 2008) have dubbed this constellation a “Minsky moment” (Minsky 1986).

  3. Some of this literature comprises: Krugman (2008), Akerlof and Shiller (2009), Larosière Report (2009), European Commission (2009b), Stiglitz (2010), Lewis (2010), Roubini and Mihm (2010), Tichy (2010). A comprehensive investigation into common traits and differences between past financial market and economic crises is offered by Reinhart and Rogoff (2009). Comparisons of the development of the main macroeconomic and foreign trade variables during the Great Depression 1929 with that during the Great Recession 2009 can be found in Eichengreen and O’Rourke (2009) and in Aiginger (2009). DG ECFIN jointly with Université Libre de Bruxelles (ULB) and University of British Columbia (UBC) organized a conference on “Advances in international macroeconomics—Lessons from the crisis”, in Brussels on 23–24 July 2010 (see DG ECFIN 2010).

  4. Only to mention a few of such platforms of discussion, e.g. see the “Global Crisis Debate” on VoxEU: http://www.voxeu.org/ or the newly created Institute for New Economic Thinking (INET): http://intereconomics.org/ or Ökonomenstimme: http://www.oekonomenstimme.org/.

  5. Jan In’t Veld et al. (2010) use an estimated open economy DSGE model with financial frictions for the US and the ROW, to evaluate various competing explanations about the recent boom bust cycle (innovation in US mortgage market (securitisation/expansion of sub prime lending); savings glut/flight to safety hypothesis; monetary policy; TFP growth; stock market and housing bubble). Accordingly, the loose monetary policy and more so bubbles in the stock and housing market played an essential role in the US crisis.

  6. This financial supervision framework will consist of a new European Systemic Risk Board (ESRB) and three new European Supervisory Authorities (ESAs) for the financial services sector: A European Banking Authority (EBA) based in London, a European Insurance and Occupational Pensions Authority (EIOPA) in Frankfurt and a European Securities and Markets Authority (ESMA) in Paris. The new authorities will be made up of the 27 national supervisors. This framework is to give Europe the control tower and the radar screens it needs to detect the risks which can accumulate across the financial system as we witnessed in the run up to and at the height of the financial crisis (see European Commission 2010 and for more information on the EU Financial Supervision System, see: http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/finances/committees/index_en.htm).

  7. The empirical "three-market barometer" (i.e., indicators for the stock market, the goods market and the money market) of the Austrian Institute for Business Cycle Research (today WIFO), introduced by its founder, F.A. von Hayek in Austria along the lines of the Harvard Barometer, predicted relatively well the crisis of the 1930s (Tichy 1973, pp. 61–62).

  8. Other approaches to deal with the "irrational exuberance" of stock market behaviour are those of the catastrophe theory, developed by René Thom (1927). Zeeman (1974) tried to analyse theoretically the behaviour of stock market crashes. Aschinger (1987, 2001) applied this methodology to the 1987 US stock market crash. The catastrophe theory approach, however, has not very much economic “flesh” in it. Hayek (1929) introduced the notion of overheating in its business cycle theory.

  9. The extremely loose monetary policy of the Fed during the period 2002–2005 apparently has caused such a special precondition. The relationship of monetary policy and stock market behaviour in our model (Eqs. 1 and 2) may apply only to such a special case of risk-neutrality. Normally, bonds and shares are far from being perfect substitutes.

  10. The long-run rate (i*) can be thought as to be determined by a Taylor rule or to be in line with the long-run real interest rate according to the Fisher equation (Fisher 1930).

  11. Equation 3 is obtained by taking the logarithm of the money market equilibrium condition \( M/P = Y^{\phi } \exp ( - \lambda i) \).

  12. Stock market prices can be identified with indices like the Dow Jones Industrial (DJI) or the DAX or the ATX etc.

  13. The rate of convergence to equilibrium is a function of the adjustment coefficient in the error correction mechanism θ in (2). In case of perfect foresight, in order to correctly predict the actual path of stock market prices it must be true that \( \theta = \nu \). The consistent adjustment coefficient, \( \tilde{\theta } \), obtained as the solution to Eq. (2) if \( \theta = \nu \), is a function of the structural parameters of the economy (see Dornbusch 1976, p. 1167): \( \tilde{\theta }(\lambda ,\delta ,\sigma ,\pi ) = \pi (\sigma /\lambda + \delta )/2 + \left[ {\pi^{2} (\sigma /\lambda + \delta )^{2} /4 + \pi \delta /\lambda } \right]^{1/2} \).

  14. For solving differential equations, see Chiang (1984), chapter 14.

  15. The IS curve represents the combination of goods prices relative to stock market prices at constant prices. Therefore it would be more appropriate to call this curve the \( \dot{p} = 0 \) curve.

  16. In case of rational expectations concerning the adjustment path of stock market prices—in analogy to the solution for rational expectations concerning the development of exchange rate changes in Dornbusch (1976, p. 1170)—one can obtain the following equation of the overshooting phenomenon (by substituting the expression of footnote 9): \( dp^{sm} /dm^{d} = 1 + 1/\lambda \tilde{\theta } = 1 + 1//(\pi (\sigma /\lambda + \delta )/2 + [ {\pi^{2} (\sigma /\lambda + \delta )^{2} /4 + \pi \delta /\lambda }]^{1/2} ) \).

  17. The complete relative price argument in this equation is (\( e + p^{*} - p \)) where \( p^{*} \) is the logarithm of the foreign price level. Setting the foreign price level equal to unity implies that \( p^{*} = 0 \).

  18. With this usual model specification we consider also the transmission of world raw material prices from one country to the other. According to Schulmeister (2009) the huge boom in world raw material and oil prices up to the middle of 2008 was the forerunner of the present global economic crisis.

  19. For the explanations of boom-bust cycles, see also Tornell and Westermann (2002).

  20. Brunnermaier and Sannikov (2009) try to save the reputation of DSGE models (attacked heavily by Buiter 2009) by constructing a macroeconomic model with a detailed financial sector in order to capture the interbank trade which collapsed after the Lehman Brothers failure and was one of the reasons to cause the “Great Recession”. A New Keynesian (NK) model with durable goods and collateral constraints (credit squeeze) by Monacelli (2009) tries to capture features of the GFC. Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) demonstrated earlier in their model of credit cycles that the dynamic interaction between credit limits and asset prices turns out to be a powerful transmission mechanism by which the effects of shocks persist, amplify, and spill over to other sectors.

References

  • Aiginger K (2009) The current economic crisis: causes, cures and consequences, WIFO working papers, no. 241, Aug 2009

  • Akerlof G, Shiller R (2009) Animal spirits, frankfurt am main. Campus, Frankfurt

    Google Scholar 

  • Altunbas Y, Gambocorta L, Marqués-Ibánez D (2010) Does monetary policy affect bank risk-taking?, ECB working paper, no. 1166, March 2010

  • Aschinger G (1987) Eine Katastrophentheoretische Erklärung des Börsenkrachs 1987. https://www.unifr.ch/spc/UF/94avril/aschinger.html

  • Aschinger G (2001) Währungs- und Finanzkrisen: Entstehung, Analyse und Beurteilung aktueller Krisen. Verlag Vahlen, München

    Google Scholar 

  • Borio C, Zhu H (2008) Capital regulation, risk-taking and monetary policy: missing link in the transmission mechanism?, BIS working papers, no. 268, Dec 2008

  • Breuss F (2006) Monetäre Außenwirtschaft und Europäische Integration. Peter Lang—Europäischer Verlag der Wissenschaften, Frankfurt am Main

    Google Scholar 

  • Breuss F, Kaniovski S, Schratzenstaller M (2009) Macro-economic effects of the fiscal stimulus measures in Austria, Austrian economic quarterly, 4/2009, pp 205–216

  • Brunnermeier MK, Sannikov Y (2009) A macroeconomic model with a financial sector, Princeton University, unpublished paper, Nov 2009

  • Buiter W (2009) The unfortunate uselessness of most ‘state of the art’ academic monetary economics, The economist (online), 6 March 2009

  • Cassidy J (2008) The minsky moment, comment, The New Yorker, 4 Feb 2008. http://www.newyorker.com/talk/comment/2008/02/04/080204taco_talk_cassidy

  • Chiang AC (1984) Fundamental methods of mathematical economics, 3rd edn. McGraw-Hill, Singapore

    Google Scholar 

  • De Grauwe P (2009) “Top-down versus bottom-up macroeconomics”, VoxEU, 19 Nov 2009. http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/4231, Lecture given at the OeNB conference on European economic integration 2009: “The Euro’s contribution to economic stability in CESE”, Vienna, 15 to 16 Nov 2009

  • De Nicolò G, Dell’Ariccia G, Laeven L, Valencia F (2010) Monetary policy and bank risk taking, IMF staff position note, SPN/10/09, 27 July 2010

  • DG ECFIN (2010) “Advances in international macroeconomics—Lessons from the crisis”, conference of DG ECFIN jointly organized with Université Libre de Bruxelles (ULB) and University of British Columbia (UBC) in Brussels on 23–24 July 2010. http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2010/20100723_advances_in_international_macroeconomics/index_en.htm

  • Dornbusch R (1976) Expectations and exchange rate dynamics. J Polit Econ 84(6):1161–1176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen B, O’Rourke KH (2009) A tale of two depressions, VoxEU, 4 June 2009. http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/3421

  • European Central Bank (2010) Monetary policy transmission in the Euro area, a decade after the introduction of the Euro. ECB Monthly Bulletin, UK, pp 85–98

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2009a) The financial and economic crisis—facts and policies, DG economic and financial affairs (ECFIN), homepage: http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/focuson/crisis/index_en.htm; legislative proposals by the commission concerning financial supervision within the context of the single market program, see: http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/finances/committees/index_en.htm

  • European Commission (2009b) Economic crisis in Europe: causes, consequences and response, European economy, 7/2009

  • European Commission (2009c) European economic forecast: autumn 2009, European economy 7/2009

  • European Commission (2010) Financial supervision package—frequently asked questions, MEMO/10/434, Brussels, 22 Sept 2010

  • Fisher I (1930) The theory of interest. The Macmillan Co., New York

    Google Scholar 

  • G20 (2010) The G20 Toronto summit declaration, 26–27 June 2010. http://www.g20.org/Documents/g20_declaration_en.pdf

  • G20 Group of Twenty (2009) Results of summits (Washington, London, Pittsburgh; see: https://www.pittsburghg20.org/index.aspx)

  • Gambocorta L (2009) Monetary policy and the risk-taking channel, BIS quarterly review, pp 45–53

  • Gärtner M, Lutz M (2004) Makroökonomik flexibler und fester Wechselkurse, 3. Springer, Auflage

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon RJ (1986) The American business cycle, bureau of economic analysis, studies in business cycles, 1986, p 25

  • Hayek FA (1929) Geldtheorie und Konjunkturtheorie, Österreichisches Institut für Konjunkturforschung, Beiträge zur Konjunkturforschung, no. 1, Vienna, 1929

  • Hayek FA (1945) The use of knowledge in society. Am Econ Rev 35(4):519–530

    Google Scholar 

  • In’t Veld J, Roeger W, Raciborski R, Ratto M (2010) The recent boom bust cycle: the relative contribution of capital flows, credit supply and asset bubbles, paper presented at the DG ECFIN conference (DG ECFIN, 2010), Brussels, 23–24 July 2010

  • Kiyotaki N, Moore J (1997) Credit cycles. J Polit Econ 105(2):211–248

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman PR (2008) The return of depression economics and the crisis of 2008. Norton & Co, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman PR (2009) The great recession versus the great depression, The New York Times, Wednesday, 22 July 2009. Online: http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2009/03/20/the-greatrecession-versus-the-great-depression/

  • Larosière Report (2009) The high-level group of financial supervision in the EU, chaired by Jacques de Larosière, Brussels, 25 Feb 2009. http://ec.europa.eu/internal_market/finances/docs/de_larosiere_report_en.pdf

  • Lewis M (2010) The big short. Inside the doomsday machine. Allen Lane at the Penguin Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Maurer A, Degain Ch (2010) Globalization and trade flows: what you see is not what you get!, WTO staff working paper ERSD-2010–2012, June 2010

  • Minegishi M, Cournède B (2010) Monetary policy responses to the crisis and exit strategies, OECD economics department working papers, OECD, Paris, no. 753, 18 Feb 2010

  • Minsky PH (1986) Stabilizing an unstable economy. McGraw-Hill, New York (new edition 2008)

    Google Scholar 

  • Monacelli T (2009) New Keynesian models, durable goods, and collateral constraints. J Monet Econ 56(2):242–254

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mooslechner P (2010) Reform der Finanzmärkte, FIW policy brief, no. 7, Sept 2010. http://www.fiw.ac.at/

  • Obstfeld M, Rogoff K (1996) Foundations of international macroeconomics. The MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 558–566

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2009) Economic outlook, volume 2009/1, no. 85, OECD, Paris, June 2009

  • OECD (2010) Economic outlook, volume 2010/1, no. 87, OECD, Paris, May 2010

  • OECD, WTO, UNCTAD (2010) Report on G20: trade and investment measures (November 2009 to Mid-may 2010), 14 June 2010

  • Reinhart CM, Rogoff KS (2009) This time is different: eight centuries of financial folly. Princeton and Oxford, Princeton University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Robbins L (1934) The great depression. London, Macmillan

    Google Scholar 

  • Roubini N, Mihm ST (2010) Crisis economics. A crash course in the future of finance. The Penguin Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Schulmeister S (2009) Trading practices and price dynamics in commodity markets and the stabilising effects of a transaction tax. Wifo Study, Vienna

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz JE (2010) Free fall. America, free markets, and the sinking of the world economy. W.W. Norton & Company, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor JB (2009) The financial crisis and the policy responses: an empirical analysis of what went wrong, NBER, working paper, no. 14631, Jan 2009

  • Thom R (1972) Stabilité structurelle et morphogénèse. Benjamin, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Tichy G (1973) Konjunkturforschung in Österreich. In: Seidel H, Kramer H (Hrsg.) Wirtschaftsforschung in Österreich: Eine Standortbestimmung, WIFO, Wien, 1973, pp 55–83

  • Tichy G (2010) Why did policy ignore the harbingers of the crisis? (published in this issue of Empirica 1/2011)

  • Tornell A, Westermann F (2002) Boom-bust cycles: facts and explanations, international monetary fund staff papers, 49, 2002, pp 111–155

  • WTO (2010) Report to the TPRB from the director-general on trade-related developments, WTO, trade policy review body, WT/TPR/OV/W/3, 14 June 2010. http://www.wto.org/english/news_e/archive_e/trdev_arc_e.htm

  • Zeeman EC (1974) On the unstable behaviour of stock exchanges. J Math Econ 1(1):39–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Fritz Breuss.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Breuss, F. Global financial crisis as a phenomenon of stock market overshooting. Empirica 38, 131–152 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10663-010-9140-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10663-010-9140-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation