Skip to main content
Log in

Policy uncertainty, symbiosis, and the optimal fiscal and monetary conservativeness

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Empirica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper extends a well-known macroeconomic stabilization game between monetary and fiscal authorities developed by Dixit and Lambertini (American Economic Review 93: 1522–1542) to multiplicative (policy) uncertainty. We find that even if fiscal and monetary authorities share a common output and inflation target (i.e., the symbiosis assumption), the achievement of the common targets is no longer guaranteed; under multiplicative uncertainty, in fact, a time consistency problem arises unless policymakers’ output target is equal to the natural level.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Similar conclusions have been derived by Dornbusch et al. (1998); Mihov (2001) and ECB (2001) more specifically for monetary policy. They claim that the creation of European Monetary Union is likely to have strengthened the degree of uncertainty surrounding the transmission of monetary policy measures within the union.

  2. Indeed, multiplicative (or parameter) uncertainty was first introduced by Holt (1962), who showed that policy performance would deteriorate when model parameters are uncertain.

  3. Holly and Hughes Hallett (1989: 64–67) gives a comprehensive description of multiplicative uncertainty and compare it to additive uncertainty.

  4. See, e.g., Estrella and Mishkin (1999); Peersman and Smets (1999); Svensson (1999); Rudebusch (2001, 2002); Giannoni (2002); Lawler (2002); Schellekens (2002); Söderström (2002); Walsh (2003): Sect. 4).

  5. See Dupuis and Hostland (2001); Auerbach and Hassett (2002, 2007).

  6. See Dixit and Lambertini (2001, 2003a, b). See also Lambertini (2006).

  7. In their model policy-makers do not face uncertainty since they observe all the shocks in the Rogoff’s (1985) tradition.

  8. See Lambertini (2006) for a discussion.

  9. By assuming additive uncertainty, it is trivial to show that D&L’s results on fiscal-monetary interactions hold in expected terms, because of the certainty equivalence (D&L use quadratic games).

  10. Cf. Rogoff (1985) and Lambertini (2006).

  11. For the sake of brevity, we here consider only a multiplicative shock on fiscal policy effectiveness, but the robustness of our results with respect to different stochastic structures will be later discussed.

  12. See Dixit and Lambertini (2003a) for an extensive discussion about the model and of its micro-foundations. For technical details see Dixit and Lambertini (2003a: Appendix A), which is available at http://www.princeton.edu/~dixitak/home/appendix_aer.pdf. Regarding the robustness of our results to different policy transmission mechanisms, see Sect. 4.

  13. See Sect. 4 for a discussion on result robustness with respect to difference source of multiplicative uncertainty.

  14. Note that \( E(\mu ) = \bar{\mu } = 1 \) and \( \sigma_{\mu }^{2} = E\left[ {\mathop {\left( {\mu - E(\mu )} \right)}\nolimits^{2} } \right] \); thus the variance can be rewritten as \( \sigma_{\mu }^{2} = E\left[ {\mu^{2} + E(\mu )^{2} - 2\mu E(\mu )} \right] = E\left[ {\mu^{2} + \mathop {\bar{\mu }}\nolimits^{2} - 2\mu \bar{\mu }} \right] = E\left[ {\mu^{2} } \right] - \mathop {\bar{\mu }}\nolimits^{2} \).

  15. See the policy-makers’ reaction functions in the instrument space (Appendix A).

  16. Optimal policy implies equalization of marginal costs and benefits of an inflation increase. When expectations are high, the output is low. Thus the marginal gain of increasing inflation is also high because of policy-makers’ quadratic losses. Hence, higher expectations imply looser policies. See again the policy-makers’ reaction functions.

  17. Recall that, for x = x C and \( \pi_{0} = \pi_{0}^{C} \), y = y * and π = π *.

  18. In order to move from instruments to objectives, we need to draw Eq. (3) as the locus of inflation rates in the instrument space (dashed lines). This locus is represented by a set of parallel lines with a slope equal to −c and an intercept equal to the associated inflation. In Fig. 1, higher dashed lines are associated with higher expected inflation rates.

  19. For the sake of brevity, robustness is here only discussed in informal terms. Further results on other possible shock structure (including multiple correlated shocks) are available upon request from the authors.

  20. Indeed, in addition to the discretionary equilibrium, D&L distinguish between leadership and commitment as possible game solutions. We discuss the robustness of our results only in the case of the D&L’s (Stackelberg) leadership equilibria. Commitment cannot be considered, either as state-contingent-linear or as non-linear rule, since the multiplicative shock is not observable before setting the policy (being a shock on policy effects and not on the state of the economy).

  21. In other words, equilibria of policy games are often too much sensitive to modeling assumptions. See Kreps (1990) for a discussion on use and misuse of different equilibrium concepts and the effects of minor changes in analytical models and agents’ preferences.

  22. Thus it holds also under monetary policy uncertainty.

  23. In particular, different prescriptions arise from model uncertainty in monetary policy, which is studied in a companion paper (see Di Bartolomeo et al. 2007).

  24. See Appendix A.

  25. See Dixit and Lambertini (2003b).

  26. The cooperative solution is found by considering the joint minimization of a common loss function. However, in our context, the result can be directly verified from Eq. (7) and (8) by setting θ = θ Β = θ G . Ideal inflation and real output cannot be achieved for any possible value of θ.

  27. See e.g., Dixit and Lambertini (2003a); Benigno and Woodford (2005, 2006); Lambertini (2006) for a general discussion.

  28. Both social loss (13) and reduced form (2) and (3) coefficients depend on the economy deep parameters by the micro-foundation of the model; thus reduced form and social loss parameters are interrelated. Full details about this interaction are provided by appendices of Dixit and Lambertini (2003a) available at http://www.princeton.edu/~dixitak/home/appendix_aer.pdf.

  29. We disregard the possibly negative effects of the tax (linear) distortions on the micro-founded welfare loss. This does not affect our results (See Appendix B).

  30. Note that Eq. (13) is minimized by substituting Eq. (7) and (8) and not Eq. (8) and (10) into it, since E(π)2 and E(y)2 are different from E(π 2) and E(y 2).

  31. From the first order conditions, we obtain two pairs of roots, but only the solution immediately below (Eq. (15) and (16)) implies that the 2 by 2 Hessian matrix is positive-semi definite: both the determinant and the trace of the Hessian in (13) and (14) are positive. The determinant is instead negative and the trace remains positive (an indeterminate Hessian matrix and a saddle point) when considering the other solution. Moreover, solution (13) and (14) is a global minimum also if the constraints 0 < θ G  < + ∞ and 0 < θ B  < + ∞ are considered (no corner solutions). Computations are available upon request.

References

  • Auerbach AJ, Hassett KA (2002) Fiscal policy and uncertainty. Int Finance 5:229–249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auerbach AJ, Hassett KA (2007) Optimal long-run fiscal policy: constraints, preferences and the resolution of uncertainty. J Econ Dyn Control 31:1451–1472

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benigno P, Woodford M (2005) Inflation stabilization and welfare: the case of a distorted steady state. J Eur Econ Assoc 3:1185–1236

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benigno P, Woodford M (2006) Optimal taxation in an RBC model: a linear-quadratic approach. J Econ Dyn Control 30:1445–1489

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brainard W (1967) Uncertainty and the effectiveness of policy. Am Econ Rev 57:411–425

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Bartolomeo G, Manzo M, Giuli F (2007) Monetary policy uncertainty and money and fiscal interactions. Dissertation, University of Rome I

  • Dixit A, Lambertini L (2001) Monetary-fiscal policy interactions and commitment versus discretion in a monetary union. Eur Econ Rev 45:977–987

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A, Lambertini L (2003a) Interactions of commitment and discretion in monetary and fiscal policy. Am Econ Rev 93:1522–1542

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A, Lambertini L (2003b) Symbiosis of monetary and fiscal policies in a monetary union. J Int Econ 60:235–247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dornbusch R, Favero C, Giavazzi F (1998) Immediate challenges for the European central bank. Econ Policy 26:17–64

    Google Scholar 

  • Dupuis D, Hostland D (2001) The implications of parameter uncertainty for medium-term fiscal planning. Working Paper 21, Ministère des Finances, Canada

  • Estrella A, Mishkin FS (1999) Rethinking the role of NAIRU in monetary policy: implications of model formulation and uncertainty. In: Taylor JB (ed) Monetary policy rules. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 405–430

    Google Scholar 

  • European Central Bank (2001) Monetary policy-making under uncertainty. Monthly Bulletin January: 43–55

  • Giannoni MP (2002) Does model uncertainty justify caution? Robust optimal monetary policy in a forward-looking model. Macroecon Dyn 6:111–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holly S, Hughes Hallett A (1989) Optimal control, expectations and uncertainty. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Holt CC (1962) Linear decision rules for economic stabilisation and growth. Quart J Econ 76:20–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ironside B, Tetlow RJ (2007) Real-time model uncertainty in the United States: the fed from 1996–2003. J Money Credit Bank 39:1533–1561

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kreps D (1990) Game theory and economic modelling. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lambertini L (2006) Monetary-fiscal interactions with a conservative central bank. Scott J Polit Econ 53:90–128

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane PR (2004) Monetary-fiscal interactions in an uncertain world: lessons for european policymakers. Institute for international integration studies. Dissertation, Trinity College Dublin

  • Lawler P (2002) Monetary uncertainty, strategic wage setting and equilibrium employment. Econ Lett 77:35–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Letterie W (1997) Better monetary control may decrease the distortion of stabilization policy: a comment. Scand J Econ 99:463–470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mihov I (2001) One monetary policy in EMU: monetary policy implementation and transmission in the European monetary union. Econ Policy 33:371–406

    Google Scholar 

  • Pearce DK, Sobue M (1997) Uncertainty and the inflation bias of monetary policy. Econ Lett 57:203–207

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peersman G, Smets F (1999) The Taylor rule: a useful monetary policy benchmark for the Euro area? Int Finance 2:85–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff K (1985) The optimal degree of commitment to an intermediate monetary target. Quart J Econ 100:1169–1189

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rudebusch GD (2001) Is the fed too timid? monetary policy in an uncertain world. Rev Econ Stat 83:203–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rudebusch GD (2002) Assessing nominal income rules for monetary policy with model and data uncertainty. Econ J 112:402–432

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schellekens P (2002) Caution and conservatism in the making of monetary policy. J Money Credit Bank 34:160–177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Söderström U (2002) Monetary policy with uncertain parameters. Scand J Econ 104:125–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svensson LEO (1999) Inflation targeting: some extensions. Scand J Econ 101:337–361

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor JB (1998) Information technology and monetary policy, institute for monetary and economic studies. Bank Jpn Monet Econ Stud 16:19–28

    Google Scholar 

  • Walsh C (2003) Accountability, transparency, and inflation targeting. J Money Credit Bank 35:829–849

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors are grateful to an anonymous referee, N. Acocella, G. Ciccarone, V. Di Simone, F. Coricelli, M. Paffermayr, P. Tirelli and seminar participants at University of Rome La Sapienza for useful discussions and comments on earlier drafts. All errors are our own responsibility. This research project has been supported by MIUR (PRIN 2005) and a Marie Curie Transfer of Knowledge Fellowship of the European Community’s Sixth Framework Programme under contract number MTKD-CT-014288. Giovanni Di Bartolomeo also gratefully acknowledges the University of Crete for hospitality.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Giovanni Di Bartolomeo.

Appendices

Appendix A

This appendix contains some equations used in the discussion; all of them can be easily derived after tedious algebra.

By considering different orders of moves, the Stackelberg (fiscal leadership) solution is:

$$ E\left( y \right) = \frac{{B_{1} y^{ * } + \sigma_{\mu }^{2} B_{2} \bar{y}}}{{B_{1} + \sigma_{\mu }^{2} B_{2} }}\;{\text{and}}\;E\left( \pi \right) = \pi^{ * } + b\theta_{B} \left( {\frac{{\sigma_{\mu }^{2} B_{2} }}{{B_{1} + \sigma_{\mu }^{2} B_{2} }}} \right)\left( {y^{ * } - \bar{y}} \right) $$
(A.1)

where \( B_{1} = a^{2} (\theta_{G} + \theta_{B}^{2} b^{2} ) \) and \( B_{2} = A_{2} (1 + \theta_{B} b^{2} ) \).

The Stackelberg (central bank’s leadership) solution is:

$$ E\left( y \right) = \frac{{C_{1} y^{ * } + \sigma_{\mu }^{2} C_{2} \bar{y}}}{{C_{1} + \sigma_{\mu }^{2} C_{2} }}\;{\text{and}}\;E\left( \pi \right) = \pi^{ * } + b\theta_{B} \left( {\frac{{\sigma_{\mu }^{2} B_{2} }}{{C_{1} + \sigma_{\mu }^{2} C_{2} }}} \right)\left( {y^{ * } - \bar{y}} \right) $$
(A.2)

where: \( \begin{gathered} C_{1} = A_{1} A_{2} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} + a^{2} \left[ {\mathop {\left( {a + cb} \right)}\nolimits^{2} \theta_{G}^{2} + c^{2} \theta_{B} } \right]\rm {,} \hfill \\ C_{2} = A_{2}^{2} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} + c^{2} \mathop {\left( {ab\theta_{G}^{2} + c} \right)}\nolimits^{2} + c^{2} D\;{\text{and}}\;D = a\left( {a + b^{3} c\left( {\theta_{G} + \theta_{B} } \right)} \right)\theta_{G} + B_{2} - c^{2} > 0 \hfill \\ \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \).

In the Nash equilibrium described in the main text, the derivatives of the equilibrium outcomes are:

$$ \frac{\partial E\left( y \right)}{{\partial \theta_{G} }} = \frac{{ac^{2} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} (a + b^{3} c\theta_{B} + bc)\left( {y^{ * } - \bar{y}} \right)}}{{\mathop {\left( {\theta_{G} a^{2} + c^{2} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} + abc\theta_{G} + b^{2} c^{2} \theta_{G} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} - abc\theta_{B} } \right)}\nolimits^{2} }} $$
(A.3)
$$ \frac{\partial E\left( \pi \right)}{{\partial \theta_{G} }} = - \frac{{\theta_{B} bc^{2} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} (a + b^{3} c\theta_{B} + bc)\left( {y^{ * } - \bar{y}} \right)}}{{\mathop {\left( {\theta_{G} a^{2} + c^{2} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} + abc\theta_{G} + b^{2} c^{2} \theta_{G} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} - abc\theta_{B} } \right)}\nolimits^{2} }} $$
(A.4)
$$ \frac{\partial E\left( y \right)}{{\partial \theta_{B} }} = - \frac{{abc^{3} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} (1 + b^{2} \theta_{B} )\left( {y^{ * } - \bar{y}} \right)}}{{\mathop {\left( {\theta_{G} a^{2} + c^{2} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} + abc\theta_{G} + b^{2} c^{2} \theta_{G} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} - abc\theta_{B} } \right)}\nolimits^{2} }} $$
(A.5)
$$ \frac{\partial E\left( \pi \right)}{{\partial \theta_{B} }} = \frac{{bc^{2} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} (1 + b^{2} \theta_{B} )\left( {\theta_{G} a^{2} + abc\theta_{G} + c^{2} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} + \theta_{G} b^{2} c^{2} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} } \right)\left( {y^{ * } - \bar{y}} \right)}}{{\mathop {\left( {\theta_{G} a^{2} + c^{2} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} + abc\theta_{G} + b^{2} c^{2} \theta_{G} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} - abc\theta_{B} } \right)}\nolimits^{2} }} $$
(A.6)
$$ \frac{\partial E\left( y \right)}{{\partial \sigma_{\mu }^{2} }} = - \frac{{ac^{2} (1 + b^{2} \theta_{B} )A_{1} \left( {y^{ * } - \bar{y}} \right)}}{{\mathop {\left( {\theta_{G} a^{2} + c^{2} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} + abc\theta_{G} + b^{2} c^{2} \theta_{G} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} - abc\theta_{B} } \right)}\nolimits^{2} }} $$
(A.7)
$$ \frac{\partial E\left( \pi \right)}{{\partial \sigma_{\mu }^{2} }} = \frac{{abc^{2} \theta_{B} (1 + b^{2} \theta_{B} )A_{1} \left( {y^{ * } - \bar{y}} \right)}}{{\mathop {\left( {\theta_{G} a^{2} + c^{2} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} + abc\theta_{G} + b^{2} c^{2} \theta_{G} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} - abc\theta_{B} } \right)}\nolimits^{2} }} $$
(A.8)

Appendix B

Consider a general welfare function (see Dixit and Lambertini (2003a: Appendix A-B):

$$ L_{W} = E_{0} \left[ {\frac{1}{2}\mathop {\left( {\pi - \pi^{ * } } \right)}\nolimits^{2} + \frac{{\theta_{W} }}{2}\mathop {\left( {y - y^{ * } } \right)}\nolimits^{2} + \vartheta_{W} x} \right] $$
(B.1)

where π *, y *, θ W \( ,\;\vartheta_{W} \) are directly derived from the fundamentals of the economy.

The optimal degrees of conservativeness that can be derived after simple algebra are:

$$ \theta_{G}^{ * * } = \frac{{c^{2} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} \left[ {a\theta_{W} \left( {y^{ * } - \bar{y}} \right) - \vartheta_{W} } \right]}}{{c^{2} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} \left[ {a + bc\left( {1 + b^{2} \theta_{W} } \right)} \right]\left( {y^{ * } - \bar{y}} \right) + \left[ {a\left( {a + bc} \right) + b^{2} c^{2} \sigma_{\mu }^{2} } \right]\vartheta_{W} }} < \theta_{G}^{ * } $$
(B.2)
$$ \theta_{B}^{ * * } = 0 $$
(B.3)

The above result confirms the conclusion reached in the main text: the central bank should take account of inflation stabilization only, whereas the government should target both real output and inflation deviations and adopt a degree of conservativeness higher than the social one. By introducing a tax-distortion cost in the welfare function, the optimal degree of government’s conservativeness should be even higher. The economic intuition is trivial.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Di Bartolomeo, G., Giuli, F. & Manzo, M. Policy uncertainty, symbiosis, and the optimal fiscal and monetary conservativeness. Empirica 36, 461–474 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10663-009-9104-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10663-009-9104-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation