Skip to main content
Log in

The strategy of raising counterfeiters’ costs in luxury markets

  • Published:
European Journal of Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A luxury monopolist can prefer increasing its net profits by raising the costs of a competitive fringe of counterfeiters compared to a situation where it can completely drive them out of the market. The mechanism underpinning this outcome results from the fact that counterfeiters can generate net revenues for the luxury monopolist because (1) sanctions imposed to counterfeiters are shaped and pocketed by the luxury monopolist under cover of deterrence (2) costs and profit loss due to counterfeiters and incurred by the luxury monopolist can be less than what is usually assumed. Moreover, the presence of counterfeits can be considered as promotional devices that signal the true luxury cachet, increases the snob value of the counterfeited brand and rewards high-end designers in a non-monetary way. In short, counterfeiting is like the light of the sun: it can burn the genuine firm but living without can be more harmful for the genuine firm.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Digital goods include goods for which the marginal cost of duplication is close to zero with copied products having a similar quality to original ones.

  2. Veblen effects refer to anomalies in the general theory of demand where the individual’s preference for buying a good increases with its price. Veblen effect are related to conspicuous consumption where individuals flaunt their acquisition of a good in anticipation of social status it will generate.

  3. Although the ‘endogeneity issue’ is beyond the scope of this contribution, it would be very interesting to investigate whether successful luxury brands are more counterfeited or whether more counterfeits of a given brand (up to a threshold) contribute to its luxury cachet.

  4. In law and economics, the ‘fines’ are public sanctions imposed by a court or other public authority with a view on deterrence and exceeding the amount of the damages suffered in order to outweigh a low probability of detection while ‘compensations’ are imposed to compensate damage done as a result of perfectly detected counterfeiting. In traditional deterrence model, what matters is not how the sanction is labelled and who is the recipient of the payment made by offenders (e.g., fines, compensations), but the insight that increasing the cost of an activity will necessarily decrease the rate at which it occurs. This hypothesis has been recently challenged by empirical evidence showing (1) that an increase in sanction can lead to an increase in the undesirable activity (Gneezy and Rustichini 2000) and (2) how the sanction is framed (and not only its amount) and the identity of recipients matter (Feldman and Teichman 2008). In our contribution, given the role played by the sanctions, they do not fit well the conventional meaning of terms used in law and economics literature. Indeed, we deal with all payments imposed on perpetrators of undesirable activities, regardless of their ‘labels’ which are strategically used under cover of deterrence or tort damages to maximize revenue of genuine firms. Consequently, we use the terms ‘sanctions’ and ‘fines’ interchangeably, but not in their conventional meanings.

  5. The positive sign of the first term of expression 17, will be verified in Sect. 3.4.

  6. Note that the demand addressed to counterfeiters decreases as the fine level increases: \( {\frac{{\partial D_{c} *}}{\partial f}} = {\frac{ - [2(1 - \alpha ) + \alpha \phi ]\phi }{2\alpha (1 - \alpha )(1 - \phi )}} < 0 \)

  7. We do not address in our contribution the problem resulting from insolvency of counterfeiters if the optimal fine is higher than the counterfeiter's wealth, which can require as pointed by Shavell (1985) costly non-monetary sanctions.

  8. The curve is convex because \( {\frac{{\partial^{2} \pi_{g} *}}{{\partial f^{2} }}} = {\frac{{[\alpha (2 - \phi )^{2} - 4(1 - \phi )]\phi^{2} }}{{2\alpha (1 - \alpha )(1 - \phi )^{2} }}} \)> 0.

  9. We consider that only genuine producers can make pressure on government whereas counterfeiters, as illegitimate producers cannot behave similarly. A natural extension is to analyse the case where both genuine producers and counterfeiters lobby, which is consistent with the situation in several developing countries where there is a huge informal sector exclusively dedicated to counterfeited items.

  10. We verify that \( f* \) is positive and that the second order condition are verified.

References

  • Teen Vogue. (2009). Marc Jacobs’ coveted clothes, cutting-edge ads, and celeb-packed front rows ensure this style pioneer’s hold on the throne. http://www.teenvogue.com/industry/2009/10/teen-vogue-handbook-marc-jacobs.

  • Allérès, D. (1998). La propriété intellectuelle dans l’univers du luxe. Réseaux, 16(88–89), 139–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anonymous. (2004). Psst. Wanna Real Rolex? The Economist, 24, 55–56.

  • Arrow, K. J. (1962). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In R. Nelson (Ed.), The rate and direction of inventive activity (pp. 609–625). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barnett, J. M. (2005). Shopping for Gucci on Canal Street: Reflections on status consumption intellectual property and the incentive thesis. Virginia Law Review, 91(6), 1381–1423.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barnett, J., El Harbi, S., & Grolleau, G. (forthcoming). The fashion lottery: Cooperative innovation in stochastic markets. Journal of Legal Studies.

  • Becker, G. S. (1968). Crime and punishment: An economic approach. Journal of Political Economy, 76(2), 169–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calixte, L. (2007). Nokia pare vertu de toutes les qualités. Challenges. March 22, http://www.challenges.fr/magazine/strategie/0072.7966/, Accessed on Jan 28, 2009.

  • Centre d’études internationales de la propriété industrielle (CEIPI). (2004). Impacts de la contrefaçon et de la piraterie en Europe, Rapport final à la Direction générale Justice et Affaires intérieures de la Commission européenne, Strasbourg.

  • Chaves, B., & Deroian, F. (2004). A note on strategic piracy in the economics of software: An explanation by learning costs. University of Paris X, FORUM, Mimeo. http://www.brousseau.info/semnum/pdf/2004-01-26_BC-FD.pdf.

  • Conner, K. R., & Rumelt, R. P. (1991). Software piracy: An analysis of protection strategies. Management Science, 37(2), 125–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corneo, G., & Jeanne, O. (1997). Conspicuous consumption, snobbism and conformism. Journal of Public Economics, 66, 55–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crumley, B. (2008). France fines eBay over Fake Vuitton. Time. Jun 30, http://www.time.com/time/business/article/0,8599,1819097,00.html.

  • De Castro, J. O., Balkin, D. B., & Shepherd, D. A. (2008). Can entrepreneurial firms benefit from product piracy? Journal of Business Venturing, 23, 75–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldman, Y., & Teichman, D. (2008). Are all legal dollars created equal? Northwestern University Law Review, 102(1), 223–262.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gneezy, U., & Rustichini, A. (2000). A fine is a price. Journal of Legal Studies, 29(1), 1–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grall, J. C., & Laur-Pouédras, E. (2008). Lutte contre la contrefaçon: Un arsenal juridique renforcée. Revue des Marques, 62, 82–84.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grolleau, G., & El Harbi, S. (2008). Profiting from being pirated by ‘pirating’ the pirates. Kyklos, 61, 385–390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Shapiro, C. (1988). Foreign counterfeiting of status goods. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103(1), 79–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins, H. (2004). When piracy becomes promotion. Technology Review, Aug 10, http://www.technologyreview.com/Biotech/13722/?a=f.

  • Kaplow, L. (1992). The optimal probability and magnitude of fines for acts that definitely are undesirable. International Review of Law and Economics, 12(1), 3–11.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laurenson. (2005). France awash with fashion fakes. BBC News, Paris. March 24, http://www.news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/europe/4378537.stm, Accessed on Jan 14, 2010.

  • Lee, S. H., & Yoo, B. (2005). Do counterfeits promote genuine products?, Zarb School of Business, Hofstra University, Hempstead, NY, working paper #7.

  • Levine, M. (2002). The $19,450 phone. The New York Times. http://www.nytimes.com/2002/12/01/magazine/the-19450-phone.html?pagewanted=1, Accessed on Jan 14, 2010.

  • Liebowitz, S. (2005). Economists’ Topsy-turvy view of piracy. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 2(1), 5–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poddar, S. (2005). Why software piracy rates differ, a theoretical analysis. National University of Singapore, working paper # 0515, http://www.fas.nus.edu.sg/ecs/pub/wp/wp0515.pdf.

  • Polinsky, A. M., & Shavell, S. (1979). The optimal tradeoff between the probability and magnitude of fines. American Economic Review, 69, 880–891.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raustiala, K., & Sprigman, C. (2006). The piracy paradox: Innovation and intellectual property in fashion design. Virginia Law Review, 92(8), 1687–1777.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ritson, M. (2007). Fakes can genuinely aid luxury brands. Marketing. July 25, http://www.marketingmagazine.co.uk/news/673098/Fakes-genuinely-aid-luxury-brands/, Accessed on Feb 22, 2010.

  • Salop, S. C., & Scheffman, D. T. (1983). Raising rivals’ costs. American Economic Review, 73, 267–271.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shavell, S. (1985). Criminal law and the optimal use of nonmonetary sanctions as a deterrent. Columbia Law Review, 85, 1232–1262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slive, J., & Bernhardt, D. (1998). Pirated for profit. Canadian Journal of Economics, 31(4), 886–899.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Takeyama, L. (1997). The intertemporal consequences of unauthorized reproduction of intellectual property. Journal of Law and Economics, 40, 511–522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, T. (1899). The theory of the leisure class: An economic study of institutions. London: Unwin Books. (1994).

    Google Scholar 

  • Verma, S. (1996). TRIPs—Development and transfer of technology. International Review of Industrial Property and Copyright Law, 27(3), 331–364.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whitwell, S. (2006). Brand piracy: Faking it can be good. Brand Strategy, http://www.intangiblebusiness.com/Brand-Services/Marketing-Services/News/Brand-piracy-faking-it-can-be-good~290.html, Accessed on Nov 5, 2007.

  • Yao, J. T. (2005). How a luxury monopolist might benefit from a stringent counterfeit monitoring regime. International Journal of Business and Economics, 4(3), 177–192.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are very grateful to Jen-Te Yao, Lucie Bottega and the anonymous referees for detailed comments and suggestions, which have substantially improved this manuscript.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gilles Grolleau.

Appendix

Appendix

The sign of \( {\frac{{\partial \hat{f}}}{\partial \alpha }} = {\frac{{(1 - \phi )[(2 - \phi )\alpha^{2} - 4\alpha + 2]}}{{\phi [2(1 - \alpha ) + \alpha \phi ]^{2} }}} \) is the same then the sign of polynomial \( P(\alpha ) = (2 - \phi )\alpha^{2} - 4\alpha + 2 \). as \( \Updelta^{\prime } = 2\phi \) then \( \mathop \alpha \nolimits_{1} = {\frac{{2 - \sqrt {2\phi } }}{2 - \phi }} \) and \( \mathop \alpha \nolimits_{2} = {\frac{{2 + \sqrt {2\phi } }}{2 - \phi }} \) as \( 0 < \phi < 1 \), then \( 0 < \alpha_{1} < 1 \) and \( \alpha_{2} > 1 \).

 

α

0

α1

1

Sign of P(α)

+

0

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Bekir, I., El Harbi, S. & Grolleau, G. The strategy of raising counterfeiters’ costs in luxury markets. Eur J Law Econ 33, 645–661 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-010-9142-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-010-9142-6

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation