Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Estimating the Skill Bias in Agglomeration Externalities and Social Returns to Education: Evidence from Dutch Matched Worker-Firm Micro-Data

  • Published:
De Economist Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper employs a unique set of micro-data covering almost one-third of the Dutch labor force, to estimate the heterogeneity of agglomeration externalities across education levels. This paper shows that there is substantial heterogeneity in the relationship between agglomeration and productivity of workers (proxied by their hourly wage) with different educational background. Apart from estimating the impact of the aggregate density of regional labor markets, we also estimate whether the composition of the local labor market in terms of education is related to the productivity of different types of workers. Using the presence of universities as an instrument, we estimate the effect of the supply of university graduates on wages, i.e. the social return to education. We find that agglomeration externalities are substantially higher for high- and medium skilled than for low-skilled employees. We find no positive effects from the presence of high-skilled on the productivity of low-skilled.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Source: own calculations based on data from CBS Statline (http://statline.cbs.nl).

  2. We have excluded employees born in Turkey from the OECD group, and added them to the non-OECD group.

  3. CBS derives local employment by combining tax data (that give total employment per firm) with a survey where multi-establishment firms with 10 or more employees provide employment in each municipality. Employees of multi-establishments firms with less than 10 employees (with a relatively low share in employment), are allocated to the headquarter.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Angrist, J. (2000). How large are human-capital externalities? Evidence from compulsory schooling laws. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 15, 9–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beaudry, C., & Schiffauerova, A. (2009). Who’s right, Marshall or Jacobs? The localization versus urbanization debate. Research Policy,38, 318–337.

    Google Scholar 

  • Briant, A., Combes, P. P., & Lafourcade, M. (2010). Dots to boxes: Do the size and shape of spatial units jeopardize economic geography estimations? Journal of Urban Economics,67, 287–302.

    Google Scholar 

  • Canton, E. (2009). Human capital externalities and proximity: Evidence from repeated cross-sectional data. De Economist,157, 79–105.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ciccone, A. (2000). Agglomeration effects in Europe. European Economic Review,46, 213–227.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ciccone, A., & Hall, R. E. (1996). Productivity and the density of economic activity. American Economic Review,86, 54–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Combes, P. P., Duranton, G., & Gobillon, L. (2008). Spatial wage disparities: sorting matters. Journal of Urban Economics,63, 723–742.

    Google Scholar 

  • Combes, P. P., Duranton, G., Gobillon, L., Puga, D., & Roux, S. (2010). Estimating agglomeration effects with history, geology, and worker fixed-effects. In E. L. Glaeser (Ed.), Agglomeration economics (pp. 15–66). Chicago, IL: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Combes, P. P., & Gobillon, L. (2015). The empirics of agglomeration economies. Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics,5, 247–348.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Groot, H. L. F., Poot, J., & Smit, M. J. (2016). Which agglomeration externalities matter most and why? Journal of Economic Surveys,30, 756–782.

    Google Scholar 

  • De la Roca, J., & Puga, D. (2017). Learning by working in big cities. The Review of Economic Studies, 84, 106–142.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duranton, G. (2010). The economics of clusters: Lessons from the French experience. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duranton, G., & Puga, D. (2004). Micro-foundations of urban agglomeration economies. In V. Henderson & J. Thisse (Eds.), Handbook of regional and urban economics (pp. 2063–2117). Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fujita, M. M. (1989). Urban economic theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fujita, M. M., Krugman, P., & Venables, A. J. (1999). The spatial economy: Cities, regions, and international trade. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fujita, M. M., & Thisse, J. (2002). Economics of agglomeration-cities, industrial location and regional growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E. L., Kallal, H. D., Scheinkman, J. A., & Shleifer, A. (1992). Growth in cities. Journal of Political Economy,100, 1126–1152.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E. L., & Maré, D. C. (2001). Cities and skills. Journal of Labor Economics,19, 316–342.

    Google Scholar 

  • Graham, D. J., Melo, P. C., Jiwattanakulpaisarn, P., & Noland, R. B. (2010). Testing for bi-directional causality between productivity and agglomeration economies. Journal of Regional Science,50, 935–951.

    Google Scholar 

  • Groot, S. P. T. (2013). Agglomeration, globalization and regional labor markets: Micro-evidence for the Netherlands, Tinbergen Institute Research Series, 553. Amsterdam: Vrije Universiteit.

    Google Scholar 

  • Groot, S. P. T., de Groot, H. L. F., & Smit, M. J. (2014). Regional wage differences in the Netherlands: Evidence, trends and explanations. Journal of Regional Science,54, 503–523.

    Google Scholar 

  • Groot, S. P. T., & Weterings, A. (2013). Internationalisation and firm productivity: Firm and regional level effects. In CBS, internationalisation monitor 2013, The Hague.

  • Harvey, D. (1981). The urban process under capitalism: A framework for analysis. In M. J. Dear & A. J. Scott (Eds.), Urbanization and urban planning in capitalist society (pp. 91–122). London: Taylor and Francis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henderson, J. V. (1988). Urban development, theory, fact, and illusion. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henderson, J. V. (2003). Marshall’s scale economies. Journal of Urban Economics,53, 1–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Horan, P. M., & Tolbert, C. M. (1984). The organization of work in rural and urban labor markets. Boulder: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs, J. (1969). The economy of cities. New York: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe, A. B., Trajtenberg, M., & Henderson, R. (1993). Geographic localization of knowledge spillovers as evidenced by patent citations. Quarterly Journal of Economics,108, 577–598.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics,22, 3–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. (1890). Principles of economics. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Melo, P. C., Graham, D. J., & Noland, R. (2009). A meta-analysis of estimates of urban agglomeration economies. Regional Science and Urban Economics,39, 332–342.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mincer, J. (1974). Schooling, experience, and earnings. New York: NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moretti, E. (2004). Estimating the external return to education: Evidence from longitudinal and repeated cross-sectional data. Journal of Econometrics,121, 175–212.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moulton, B. R. (1990). An illustration of a pitfall in estimating the effects of aggregate variables on micro units. Review of Economics and Statistics,72, 334–338.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter, M. E. (1990). The competitive advantage of nations. Houndmills: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Puga, D. (2010). The magnitude and causes of agglomeration economies. Journal of Regional Science,50, 203–219.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rauch, J. E. (1993). Productivity gains from geographic concentration of human capital: Evidence from the cities. Journal of Urban Economics,34, 380–400.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenthal, S. S., & Strange, W. C. (2004). Evidence on the nature and sources of agglomeration economies. In J. V. Henderson & J. Thisse (Eds.), Handbook of urban and regional economics (pp. 2119–2171). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schulz, T. P. (1988). Education investment and returns. In H. Chenery & T. N. Srinivasan (Eds.), Handbook of development economics (pp. 543–630). Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1776). The wealth of nations. Lawrence: Digireads.com Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, W. R. (1965). A preface to urban economics. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Bergeijk, P. A. G., Fortanier, F., Garretsen, J. H., de Groot, H. L. F., & Moons, S. J. V. (2011). Productivity and internationalization: A micro-data approach. De Economist,159, 381–388.

    Google Scholar 

  • Verstraten, P., Verweij, G., & Zwaneveld, P. J. (2019). Complexities in the spatial scope of agglomeration externalities. Journal of Regional Science,59, 29–55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge, J. M. (2002). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Stefan P. T. Groot.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

During the first stage of working on this paper, Stefan Groot was working at the Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam. We are grateful to two anonymous reviewers of this journal for their constructive comments on an earlier version of this paper. We are also grateful to Coen Teulings and Wouter Vermeulen for many inspiring discussions on this and related papers. The usual disclaimer applies.

Appendix 1: Estimating Distance Decay Functions to Define Local Labor Markets

Appendix 1: Estimating Distance Decay Functions to Define Local Labor Markets

The size and shape of spatial units that is used to estimate regional patterns in economic outcomes matters a great deal for the research findings (Briant et al. 2010; Combes and Gobillon 2015). The work of Groot et al. (2014), who estimate agglomeration externalities on both the level of Dutch municipalities and on the level of NUTS-3 regions, provides a good illustration of this phenomenon. On the NUTS-3 level, they find that doubling the employment density is associated with 4.8% higher regional wages (controlling for worker heterogeneity), while applying the exact same methodology on the level of municipalities yields an estimated agglomeration elasticity of only 2.1%. Briant et al. (2010) find that the optimal choice for a regional classification depends on the spatial scope of the phenomenon under investigation, whereby the level of spatial disaggregation should match the level at which the forces under examination are expected to operate. In the case of agglomeration forces, this is the level of the local labor market.

A further problem is that data availability often limits the options that researchers have when choosing the appropriate regional classification. Even when the level of detail is sufficient, availabilities are often restricted to administrative units which may deviate substantially from what can be considered a regional labor market. Besides the fact that the average size of such administrative areas may not be appropriate, there is also a substantial heterogeneity in the (spatial) size of regional units, particularly on the level of municipalities. Another problem arises from taking a discrete approach to defining a regional classification: if two individuals are located just a few meters apart but on different sides of the regional border they are considered to be in different regions (or in our case local labor markets), while in reality there is no real difference in location.

In this paper, we have therefore chosen to consider the relevant local labor market for an economic actor at a certain location as a continuum. The farther away from the core of each individual actors local labor market, the less an area is considered to be part of the relevant local labor market. Following Thompson (1965) and Horan and Tolbert (1984), we conceptually define local labor markets as the area around an economic core where labor market transactions generally take place, which is bounded by the radius within which most of the commuting towards the core takes place. A straightforward operational definition that follows from this theoretical definition is to consider the extent to which an area at a given radius from a location where economic activities take place is part of the relevant local labor market (in other words, the spatial weight of the area at that radius) to be equal to the cumulative distribution function of the fraction of commutes that take place within that radius or further. Thus, as 100% (10%) of commutes takes place within a radius of 0 km (50 km) or more, we apply a spatial weight of ‘1’ (‘0.1’).

To formalize this relationship we have estimated a distance decay function. After experimenting with different functional specifications with up to three parameters, we found the following functional form to match the cumulative distribution function of observed commuting patterns almost exactly,

$$w(r) = \alpha + \beta \cdot \ln (r)\quad {\text{for}}\quad r > 0\quad \& \quad w > 0,\quad w(r) = 0\quad {\text{for}}\quad r = 0,\quad w(r) = 1\quad {\text{for}}\quad w > 1,$$
(3)

whereby w is the spatial weight of an area at a radius of distance r from the economic core. In the micro data that is available for this paper, we have both the residence and work municipality available for almost all Dutch employees (see Sect. 3 for a discussion of our data), as well as the x and y coordinates of the center of each municipality. Using OLS to estimate the above equation resulted in parameter estimates of α = 0.9385 and β = – 0.2219. The relationship between the spatial weight and distance to the core municipality of the average Dutch local labor market is presented in Fig. 4. Even though 50% commutes less than 7 km, around 10% of all commuters live more than 40 km from their jobs. At a distance of 68 km the estimated distance decay function crosses the horizontal axis. Even though there is a small percentage of commutes within our data that takes place at distances up to 200 km, the fact that these commutes account for less than 1% of total commutes supports the view that the estimated cutoff point is appropriate.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Estimated distance decay function

Even though we could theoretically use actual the cumulative distribution function for each individual municipality as distance decay function, such a measure would be highly endogenous given our purpose of estimating agglomeration externalities. More productive regions characterized by high wages attract commuters from a very wide area compared to less productive and rural areas. Not in the least because of the increased demand for infrastructure that follows from these large commuting flows, there is generally more infrastructure connecting the large economic centers which results in better accessibility, attracting even more commuters (for this reason, estimating distance decay functions based on commuting time rather than distance is also problematic). If the distance decay function would be based on actual commuting towards a given municipality, the size of the spatial units would affect the size of agglomeration externalities, which is—given the findings of Briant et al. (2010) very likely to result in biased estimates. Therefore, we use the same distance decay parameters for all regions in our sample.

Figure 5 shows spatial weights for the local labor markets around three—for the purpose of illustration arbitrary chosen—municipalities: Amsterdam, Groningen and Maastricht. The weights quickly decline to 30–40% and decline more gradually from there onwards.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Weights (in %) of municipalities around three local labor markets

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Groot, S.P.T., de Groot, H.L.F. Estimating the Skill Bias in Agglomeration Externalities and Social Returns to Education: Evidence from Dutch Matched Worker-Firm Micro-Data. De Economist 168, 53–78 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10645-019-09354-w

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10645-019-09354-w

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation