Skip to main content
Log in

The impact of management systems on technical change: the adoption of pollution prevention techniques

  • Published:
Economic Change and Restructuring Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A firm’s capability to innovate is influenced by its organizational structure. We examine the effect of Total Quality Environmental Management (TQEM) on the adoption of innovative pollution prevention activities over the period 1992–1996, and show that the rate of innovation increases following the adoption of TQEM. However, the effect of TQEM on pollution prevention innovation “wears out” over time. Our analysis indicates that this is likely because pollution prevention undertaken in one year continues to be effective in future years. This, in turn, reduces the incentives for further innovation due to declining marginal returns, rather than because the institutional effectiveness of TQEM weakens. We provide corroborative evidence based on the time profile of pollution prevention of firms that adopted TQEM prior to the start of our sample, and also develop a stylized model with (partial) obsolescence of pollution prevention innovations that matches the empirical regularities we obtain. Our findings shed light on the importance of organizational structure on the pace of technical change.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In related research, we have investigated the importance of TQEM, relative to regulatory (and other) factors in the adoption of pollution prevention practices (Khanna et al. 2009), and how TQEM has affected the nature of pollution prevention activities (Deltas et al. 2014).

  2. The role of organizational structure on innovation has been examined outside of the environmental arena as well by Teece (1996), among others. More recently, Battisti and Stoneman (2010) established complementarities between organizational innovations and technological innovations among UK firms.

  3. In theory, the relationship between voluntary programs and innovation could go either way due to the nature of such programs which may enhance or limit incentives for innovation. Voluntary programs may provide firms the flexibility to set their own environmental goals (Sunnevåg 2000), allow for information exchanges that promote collaborative learning and reduce shared uncertainties (Aggeri 1999; Ashford 1999; de Vries et al. 2012; Skjærseth 2005). However, voluntary programs’ lack of stringency, a key factor in many environmental innovation studies (Brunnermeier and Cohen 2003; Jaffe and Palmer 1997; Lanjouw and Mody 1996), may curtail the incentive to undertake costly innovations that have uncertain outcomes (Cunningham and Clinch 2005).

  4. In this work, P2 is scalar-valued, and not distinguished by type. We recognize that there may indeed be synergies between P2s such that promoting one type using TQEM can enhance the adoption of others as well. Measuring such synergistic effects may require analysis akin to Battisti and Stoneman (2010). However, we cannot identify synergies separately from the returns to P2 with the data used in this study. The only way to identify synergies would be to distinguish P2 by type. If adding P2 of the same type does not involve any synergies (by assumption), then synergies can be distinguished by returns. Doing this disaggregated analysis is far beyond the scope of this work. It is also unclear how it would help us pin down the obsolescence parameter, which is the central question here.

  5. The myopic firm assumption also allows us to sidestep the issue of whether the adoption of TQEM is anticipated or un-anticipated. Consider a forward-looking manager who values both current and future profits, and anticipates adoption of TQEM in period t. Such a manager would reduce P2 innovation in period t-1, and would rationally allocate resources to pollution prevention research to the following year when the ability of identifying viable solutions would be enhanced due to the adoption of TQEM in that year.

  6. With a time-varying \({V}_{j,t}\), the steady state would be a distribution, not a point, and convergence would not deterministic. Both of these effects would lead to unnecessary complications to the exposition and analysis.

  7. The \({\epsilon }_{j,t}\) component of \({V}_{j,t}\), which represents random non-persistent variation, is unlikely to cause endogeneity issues, because the adoption of TQEM is a long-run decision and probably taken with some lag. Endogeneity would be a problem if \({V}_{j,t}\) exhibits systematic time variation across firms over time, i.e., its relative value across firms changes over time in a systematic way. This, however, is unlikely to be an issue in our panel, since it not a long one.

  8. The first year for which these data are reported is 1991. Pollution prevention activities for chemicals which have been added or deleted over the period 1991–1996 were dropped due to changes in the reporting requirements by the USEPA. This ensures that the change in pollution prevention activities in our sample over time is not due to differences in the chemicals that were required to be reported.

  9. The firm-reported TQEM data from IRRC are self-reported, i.e., they are not verified or certified by an external party. Non-survey response leads to some missing values of the TQEM variable, and results in an unbalanced panel. Since the decision to adopt TQEM is not likely to be made year to year and since even if a firm were to de-adopt TQEM, the culture and organizational practices are likely to persist, we assume that there is no de-adoption of TQEM during our sample period. This allows us to “fill-in” missing values for TQEM for 15% of the sample and affects an additional 4% of the observations for which transient “de-adoption” of TQEM was reported. Nonetheless, TQEM remains missing for 227 firm/year combinations.

  10. Synthetic control, a more recently developed method that generalizes our implicit “difference-in-difference” research design, cannot be credibly applied to our data given the very short duration of the panel.

  11. In a robustness check, we estimate separate trends for the firms that have adopted TQEM prior to the start of our sample, the firms that have adopted TQEM during our sample, and the firms that have never adopted TQEM.

  12. In robustness checks, not reported here for brevity, we have also dropped these observations from the linear model to ensure than any of the differences between the two models is not driven by the difference in observations. In these regressions, the TQEM treatment effect is slightly higher and the R-squared slightly lower.

  13. Alternatively, it could be that some firms are practicing the essence of TQEM as part of their standard way of doing business; thus, they may not find it necessarily to “officially” launch such a program.

  14. Observe that if all firms that adopted TQEM during our sample did it at the same year, the third subsample would not have been sufficient to identify the treatment effect. Moreover, if in addition no firms adopted TQEM prior to the start of our sample period, then the second subsample would not have been sufficient to identify the TQEM effect either.

  15. The results using yearly dummies in the other two samples are also similar and are omitted for brevity.

  16. In one specification, there is a tiny increase from year 3 to year 4, but it is also associated with an increase in the standard error of the year 4 effect. In fact, the year 4 effect is no longer as strongly statistically significant as the slightly smaller year 3 effect.

  17. Difference-in-difference estimates cannot be obtained in a model that estimates the time profile of TQEM effects using year dummies when limiting ourselves only to the firms that adopted TQEM during our sample period. This is because in such a sample no firms are treated in the first year, four distinct treatment effects need to be estimated (each requiring one year of data), and all firms are treated by the fifth year.

  18. Note that the first deviation is zero since it is used to pin down the value of \(\Delta \alpha\).

  19. These percentages are obtained by exponentiating the parameter estimates in Table 3, column 3, if these correspond to a Poisson and not a linear regression model.

References

  • Aggeri F (1999) Environmental policies and innovation: a knowledge-based perspective on cooperative approaches. Res Policy 28:699–717

    Google Scholar 

  • Anton WRQ, Deltas G, Khanna M (2004) Incentives for environmental self-regulation and implications for environmental performance. J Environ Econ Manag 48(1):632–654

    Google Scholar 

  • Arimura TH, Hibiki A, Katayama H (2008) Is a voluntary approach an effective environmental policy instrument?: a case for environmental management systems. J Environ Econ Manag 55(3):281–295

    Google Scholar 

  • Arimura TH, Darnall N, Katayama H (2011) Is ISO 14001 a gateway to more advanced voluntary action? The case of green supply chain management. J Environ Econ Manag 61(2):170–182

    Google Scholar 

  • Ashford N (1999) The influence of information-based initiatives and negotiated environmental agreements on technological change. In: Carraro L (ed) Voluntary approaches in environmental policy. Kluwer, Great Britain

    Google Scholar 

  • Battisti G, Stoneman P (2010) How innovative are UK Firms? Evidence from the fourth UK community innovation survey on synergies between technological and organizational innovations. Br J Manag 21:187–206

    Google Scholar 

  • Bennear LS (2007) Are management-based regulations effective? Evidence from state pollution prevention programs. J Policy Anal Manag 26(2):327–348

    Google Scholar 

  • Boldrin M, Levine DK (2008) Against intellectual monopoly. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Griffith R, Van Reenen J (1995) Dynamic count data models of technological innovation. Econ J 105:333–344

    Google Scholar 

  • Brouhle K, Graham B, Harrington DR (2013) Innovation under the Climate Wise Program. Resource and Energy Economics 35:91–112

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunnermeier SB, Cohen MA (2003) Determinants of environmental innovation in US manufacturing industries. J Environ Econ Manag 45:278–293

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen WM, Klepper S (1996) A reprise of size and R&D. Economic Journal 106:925–951

    Google Scholar 

  • Cunningham J, Clinch JP (2005) Innovation and environmental voluntary approaches. J Environ Plann Manag 48(3):373–392

    Google Scholar 

  • Deltas G, Harrington DR, Khanna M (2014) Green management and the nature of pollution prevention innovation. Appl Econ 46:465–482

    Google Scholar 

  • de Vries F, Nentjes A, Odam N (2012) Voluntary environmental agreements: lessons on effectiveness, efficiency and spill over potential. Int Rev Environ Resour Econ 6:119–152

    Google Scholar 

  • Genskow KD, Wood DM (2011) Improving voluntary environmental management programs: facilitating learning and adaptation. Environ Manag 47:907–916

    Google Scholar 

  • Hannan TH, McDowell J (1984) The determinants of technology adoption: the case of the banking firm. RAND J Econ 15(3):328–335

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrington DR, Deltas G, Khanna M (2014) Does pollution prevention reduce toxic releases? A dynamic panel data model. Land Econ 90(2):199–221

    Google Scholar 

  • Inoue E, Arimura TH, Nakano M (2013) A new insight into environmental innovation: Does the maturity of environmental management systems matter? Ecol Econ 94:156–163

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe A (1986) Technological opportunity and spillovers of R&D: evidence from firms’ patents, profits and market value. Am Econ Rev 76(5):984–1001

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe A, Palmer K (1997) Environmental regulation and innovation: a panel data study. Rev Econ Stat 79(4):610–619

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnstone N, Hascic I, Popp D (2010) Renewable energy policies and technological innovation: evidence from patent counts. Environ Resour Econ 45:133–155

    Google Scholar 

  • Karlson SH (1986) Adoption of competing inventions by United States steel producers. Rev Econ Stat 68(3):415–422

    Google Scholar 

  • Khanna M, Deltas G, Harrington DR (2009) Adoption of pollution prevention techniques: the role of management systems and regulatory pressures. Environ Resour Econ 44:85–106

    Google Scholar 

  • Klassen RD, McLaughlin CP (1993) TQEM and environmental excellence in manufacturing. Ind Manag Data Syst 93(6):14–23

    Google Scholar 

  • Lanjouw JO, Mody A (1996) Innovation and the international diffusion of environmentally responsive technology. Res Policy 25:549–571

    Google Scholar 

  • Lyon TP, Maxwell JW (2007) Environmental public voluntary programs reconsidered. Policy Stud J 35:723–750

    Google Scholar 

  • Ozusaglam S, Kesidou E, Wong CY (2018) Performance effects of complementarity between environmental management systems and environmental technologies. Int J Prod Econ 197:112–122

    Google Scholar 

  • Paton B (2000) Voluntary environmental initiatives and sustainable industry. Bus Strategy Environ 9:328–338

    Google Scholar 

  • Potoski M, Prakash A (2005) Covenants with Weak Swords: ISO 14001 and facilities' environmental performance. J Policy Anal Manag 24(4):745–769

    Google Scholar 

  • Potoski M, Prakash A (2013) Do voluntary programs reduce pollution? Examining ISO 14001's effectiveness across countries. Policy Stud J 41(2):273–294

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramirez Harrington D (2013) Effectiveness of state pollution prevention programs and policies. Contemp Econ Policy 31(2):255–278

    Google Scholar 

  • Ranson M, Cox B, Keenan C, Teitelbaum D (2015) The impact of pollution prevention on toxic environmental releases from U.S. manufacturing facilities. Environ Sci Technol 49(21):12951–12957

    Google Scholar 

  • Rennings K, Ziegler A, Ankele K, Hoffmann E (2006) The influence of different characteristics of the EU environmental management and auditing scheme on technical environmental innovations and economic performance. Ecol Econ 57(1):45–59

    Google Scholar 

  • Sam A, Khanna M, Innes R (2009) How do voluntary pollution reduction programs (VPRs) work? An empirical study of links between VPRs, environmental management and environmental performance. Land Econ 4(85):692–711

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1942) Capitalism, socialism and democracy. Harper Brothers, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Skjærseth JB (2005) Governing technological change by voluntary agreements: climate policy and Dutch petroleum production. Climate Policy 5:419–432

    Google Scholar 

  • Stoneman P, Kwon M-J (1994) The diffusion of multiple process technologies. Econ J 104:420–431

    Google Scholar 

  • Sunnevåg K (2000) Voluntary agreements and the incentives for innovation. Environment and Planning C. Gov Policy 18:555–573

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece DJ (1996) Firm organization, industrial structure, and technological innovation. J Econ Behav Organ 31(2):193–224

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner M (2007) On the relationship between environmental management, environmental innovation and patenting: evidence from German manufacturing firms. Res Policy 36(10):1587–1602

    Google Scholar 

  • Wruck KH, Jensen MC (1998) The two key principles behind effective TQEM programs. Eur Financ Manag 4(3):401–423

    Google Scholar 

  • Ziegler A, Nogareda JS (2009) Environmental management systems and technological environmental innovations: Exploring the causal relationship. Res Policy 38(5):885–893

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank two anonymous referees for comments that have improved the quality of the paper. Financial support from the EPA STAR program Grant No. R830870 is gratefully acknowledged. We alone bear responsibility for any errors.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to George Deltas.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Deltas, G., Harrington, D.R. & Khanna, M. The impact of management systems on technical change: the adoption of pollution prevention techniques. Econ Change Restruct 54, 171–198 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-020-09273-w

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-020-09273-w

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation