1 Introduction

A layman would have an eye-catching and appealing picture of natural resource abundance. But a closer and scientific investigation of the effects of natural resources on both the macro- and socio-economic variables would suggest otherwise. For instance, natural resource abundance has been found to fuel growth “exclusiveness”. The entire supply chain of natural resources from discovery to sales has features of growth elitism. As an illustration, governments or their appointees hold property rights to natural resource wealth, in which case, the immediate effect of the supply chain is self-enrichment of the property rights holders. Second, in a case where the private sector is allowed to be among the stakeholders, selfish interest of the government through excessive taxation might discourage investment required to discover natural resources in the first place. Another channel is if the political elite or other powerful groups were given preferential access to the resource wealth, they would use it for their own benefit without investing the generated wealth for overall growth (Warner 2012).

Also, the exact macroeconomic effect of natural resource abundance is difficult to unravel. In the short term, there is existence of volatility in the revenue accruable from the exploitation, exploration and sales of these resources. This makes it difficult to conduct macroeconomic stabilization policies. The long run challenge relates to the ample evidences that have shown that resource-endowed countries tend to have slower economic growth rate as compared with resource-scarce countries (Frankel 2012; Oyinlola et al. 2015; Arezki and Nabli 2012). This strand of the literature is referred to as “Resource Curse Hypothesis” (RCH), a coinage attributed to Sachs and Warner (1995). It should be noted that the RCH debate is inconclusive, as studies have argued and documented evidences on both sides of the argument (See Frankel 2012 for a survey).

The problem identified by the studies that have refuted RCH is due to the fact that they concentrate on aggregate growth. These studies have an implicit assumption that all the citizens enjoy the rents received from the sales/export of these resources, which is the hardly the case in reality. In the sub-Saharan African (SSA) case, there are ample evidences that have proved that a selected proportion of the population, mostly the political elite and urban dwellers, enjoy these proceeds. Also, a large chuck of this revenue is spent on recurrent and administrative expenditures, which is biased against the poor and unemployed. Thus, this being the case is an indication that these categories of citizenry (i.e. the poor and unemployed) are potentially being deprived from reaping the benefits of the endowment.Footnote 1 This among others might limit the ability of these sets of citizens to contribute their productivity quota to the national output. Hence, it could then be summarily stated that natural resource abundance would not lead to inclusive growth,Footnote 2 as this might be a plausible candidate in explaining the RCH. The existence of inclusive growth ensures that all the sections of the country are active in the growth process of the economy. To this end, there would be increase in the tax-based revenue of the government, through increase in job creation. Hence, government would have more funds to formulate and implement developmental policies.

The importance of inclusive growth has been demonstrated on a global, regional and national levels. A classical example is the tagging of the World Economic Forum that was held in Nigeria Forging Inclusive Growth, Creating Jobs; in February 2014, UK’s Department for International Development (DFID) highlighted inclusive growth as part of work plans and strategies. Also, in May 2014, European Commission emphasized the important role of the private sector led strategy in achieving inclusive growth. Nigeria’s 2013 Federal Government Budget was coined ‘Fiscal Consolidation with Inclusive Growth’; in November 2013, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) set inclusive growth as a pivotal part of their research agenda for 2014.Footnote 3 To further demonstrate the importance of inclusive growth, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) and United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) have actively been engaging in coming up with policy papers geared towards enhancing inclusive growth. Examples of such papers include OECD (2012) whose report identified three problems: poverty,Footnote 4 unemploymentFootnote 5 and inequality,Footnote 6 that growth from 1990s to date had failed to tackle. OECD (2013a, b, c) also emphasizes the importance of inclusive growth. Goal 8 of the proposed Open Working Group on Sustainable Development Goal is related to inclusive growth. G20 (2013) have confirmed the absence of inclusive growth in the region and further argued not only for a strong, sustainable and balanced growth but also for a more inclusive pattern of growth that will mobilize the talents of the citizenry. Also, Anand et al. (2013) argued that the Arab Spring, the growing divide between Main Street and Wall Street in advanced economies, and the “three speed” world economy have placed inclusive growth at the forefront of policy debates.

In this study, we make a case for Human Capital Development (HCD) as a likely and efficient candidate/mechanism to ensure and enhance inclusive growth. HCD is a broad concept and cannot be measured holistically. However, we postulate that education and health are key indicators of HCD. This claim has also been backed by the fact that they (education and health) have retained their prominence by being among the nine objectives of Millennium Development Goals (MDGs) and recently, Sustainable Development Goals (SDG). Also, agencies such as United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization (UNESCO), OECD, UNDP and World Health Organization (WHO) have advocated for the improvement in the quality of service delivery as well as increase in government expenditures on these sectors.

Based on the foregoing, this study seeks to achieve two broad objectives. Firstly, to empirically examine the possibility of achieving inclusive growth through increase in government expenditures on health and education. The second objective is to examine the potential benefit of investing the natural resources rent on HCD indicators. To this end, the study uses financing gap model and simulation methodology under certain assumptions to estimate the potential economic growth accruable by investing natural resource rent on human capital indicators.

The novelty this study brings forth is based on its objective. Most of the existing papers on inclusive growth are policy papers, which is less empirical, as it is not driven by econometric or other scientific approaches.Footnote 7 The scope of this study is limited to 18 SSA countries for the period 1995–2013. The reasons adduced to limiting the scope to SSA are because (1) with the exception of very few countries (Botswana, Namibia and may be South Africa), statistics have shown that resource-rich countries in SSA are ensnared with RCH; (2) resource rents have been the major source of revenue for SSA countries; (3) the region is the least in the global HDI rankings and (4) the region has the highest prevalence of poverty and inequality. The selected countries are based on data availability.

The rest of the paper is structured as follows: section two dwells on inclusive growth issues and further argued for the beneficial effects of inclusive growth. In section three, we discuss the data and provide a detailed trend analysis of the key variables in the study. Model specification and methodological related issues are offered in section four. Sections five and six house the empirical result and conclusion respectively.

2 Expositions on inclusive growth

It is the intention of this section to provide a general overview of inclusive growth, by examining its definitions/meaning, determinants as well as measurement.

2.1 Concept of inclusive growth

More than ever before, institutions, governments and organizations have been actively talking about inclusive growth. This is a fall out of the fact that it has been observed that increase in income (GDP) of countries does not necessarily mean growth in the first instance, not to talk of sustainable growth. This notion is justified because in most developing countries, there is high unemployment rate, wide income disparity as well as increasing rate of poverty. Despite this, such countries still record incidence of growth. Hence, the growth recorded is the product of a section of the population and not the entire population. To ensure justice and equity, the burgeoning arguments have tilted towards ensuring that all economic agents contribute their quota to the growth process of their country.

Although, there is no absolute acceptable definition of inclusive growth, a situation that cut across all branches of economics in agreeing to common definition(s) of any term, there is however, near unison in terms of what inclusive growth generally meant.Footnote 8 As the term “inclusive”, which means all; entire; total and whole, inclusive growth could then be defined as the one that aims to ensure that all income, social and economic groups/agents contribute their quota in the growth process of an economy. Based on this concept, it could be inferred that inclusive growth tends to mainly solve socio-economic/developmental problems such as poverty, inequality and unemployment. It could also be argued that the economic growth that solves these problems is inclusive in nature. For instance, a classical example of inclusive growth could be the one that the wage rate is higher than per capita income (GDP per capita) and/or economic growth is accompanied by fall in poverty rate, unemployment and inequality gap. However, it should be noted that inclusive growth is conditioned upon continuity/sustainability. That is, such growth must have a steady and relatively stable trend.

In order to have a sound understanding of the concept of inclusive growth, we limit our review to the two leading advocates of inclusive growth-the OECD and UNDP. Starting with the OECD, special attention was devoted to the socioeconomic adversities (unemployment, inequality and poverty) confronting the global economy. They defined inclusive growth as the one that reduces poverty and inequality and benefits the most marginalized section of the population. The poverty-inequality-growth debate has long been contested and this study does not attempt to delve into it. Rather, it attempts to demonstrate how this debate might lead to inclusive growth. Inclusive growth is linked to the debate in that it proves to the governments that growth is just a process and not an end (i.e. it is a mere necessary but not sufficient condition for long-term development). Growth should be seen as a tool to achieving wider objectives.Footnote 9 Emphasis must be placed on the quality of growth rather than quantity. Also, it helps to erase the notion that growth would eradicate these socio-economic problems. Hence, concerned stakeholders are put on their toes to forge policies that would enhance poverty and inequality-resistant growth.

2.2 Determinants of inclusive growth

Irrespective of the fact that inclusive growth has varying definitions across organizations, there are however, some common positions as regard its determinants. Using the concept of OECD and UNDP, it could be simply summarized that HCD indicators as well as other socioeconomic variables serve as valid and strong determinants of inclusive growth. To this end, variables such as investment in human capital,Footnote 10 job creation, structural transformation and broad-based growth,Footnote 11 good institutionsFootnote 12 and social protectionFootnote 13 have been found to aid the desired growth. The assumption that achieving growth first, and that the effect would later trickle down to alleviate poverty and inequality is rather unrealistic.Footnote 14

Discussions on inclusive growth would be incomplete without a mention of structural transformation. In the words of Matusyama (2008), “structural change is a complex, intertwined phenomenon, not only because economic growth brings about complementary changes in various aspects of the economy, such as the sector compositions of output and employment, organization of industry, etc., but also these changes in turn affect the growth process. The transformation from the rural agricultural society to the urban industrial society is just one of many aspects of structural change […]”. History has shown that structural transformation is critical to economic development. There are diverse forms of structural transformation: it could be diversification of the economy from an agrarian-based to manufacturing based. This is the first stage of transformation process. It could also be as a result of industrialization process of countries. This is evidenced considering the antecedents of China, Japan and South Korea.

Even though, Africa has witnessed major structural transformation as well as industrialization process, this has not translated to expected growth or growth rate compatible with other developing regions in the world. This is to say that structural transformation is not a homogenous process (Osei and Jedwab 2013). Productivity growth is quite essential to structural change and hence economic development. Data reveals that the productivity gap in Africa is about 2.5 %. This gap could have been reduced to 1.5, if Africa had similar productivity rate as that of Asia. This gap would have also been reduced to 1.7 should Africa had similar employment rate with Asia. To further drive home the importance of structural transformation, McMillan and Rodrik (2011) while using dataset for 38 developing countries, it was found that structural transformation is growth-enhancing for Asian countries while it is growth-reducing for Africa.Footnote 15

2.3 Measures of inclusive growth

Having given an overview of the concept of inclusive growth as well as its determinants, the next area that should be explored is the measurement related issues. Just as there is no consensus as regards a workable definition, measuring inclusive growth suffers similar fate. Ali and Son’s (2007) measurement used the concept of social opportunity function based on two conditions: (1) average opportunities available to the population, and (2) how opportunities are shared or distributed among the population. This function gives greater weight to the poor. As such, opportunities created for the poor are more important than the non-poor. The increase in these opportunities would lead to inclusive growth. Anand et al. (2013) built on the Ali and Son (2007) to develop a measure of inclusive growth using a macro social mobility function, following the micro literature on income distribution. Their measure provides a framework to study equity and efficiency together. The measure is equally used to study the dynamics and determinants of inclusive growth in low-income countries and emerging markets. The model assumes that inclusive growth depends on income growth and distribution. Using consumer’s theory, income and substitution effect was decomposed into growth and distributional components. The underlying social welfare function must satisfy two properties to capture these features: (1) it is increasing in its argument (to capture growth dimension) and (2) it satisfies the transfer property—any transfer of income from a poor person to a richer person reduces the value of the function (to capture distributional dimension).

The extant literature precludes any attempt to explicate the theoretical association between HCD measures and inclusive growth. This implies ample vagueness in the precise mechanisms through which the effects of HCD is transmitted to inclusive growth. Nonetheless, we lay out a plausible transmission mechanism, which is presumed to work via the fiscal behavior of the government. Specifically, it hinges on the effectiveness of both government tax efforts and government expenditures. On the revenue side, the government has to be able to tax the natural resource rents and allocate the tax revenue productively into the education and health sectors. For government spending, government priorities should be set in such a fashion that is de-linked from the gyration of resource revenues. However, the management of resource wealth in this manner is more difficult than depicted. Some of the challenges include, but are not limited to, the well-known volatility of resource prices; the non-renewable status of some of these natural resources and its implication on the optimality of expenditures; weak institutional quality and attendant narrow fiscal space.Footnote 16 Beyond these, also noteworthy is the time lag between “cause” and “effect” of natural resource rent on inclusive growth. Once government increases her expenditure of these HCD indicators, it takes some time before the effects, if any, on inclusive growth begin to manifest.Footnote 17

3 Data and trend analysis

The key variables of interest in this paper are inclusive growth, natural resource rent and government expenditure on human development indicators (education and health). In addition to economic growth being a prerequisite for the attainment of inclusive growth, productive employment has also remained one of the key drivers of inclusive economic growth since employment outcome is an important outcome of inclusiveness. In this regard therefore, we utilize log of GDP per person employed as a proxy for inclusive growth to reflect two factors of average opportunities available to the population and how these opportunities are distributed in the population. Consequently, the government expenditure variable is defined as the log of current operating expenditures in education, including wages and salaries and excluding capital investments in buildings and equipment. The health expenditure on the other hand is measure as log of per capita public health expenditure, which covers the provision of health services (preventive and curative), family planning activities, nutrition activities, and emergency aid designated for health but does not include provision of water and sanitation. More so, labour force and physical capital were measured as log of population and log of gross fiscal capital formation respectively. Control variables included in the analysis are trade openness measured as sum of export and import to GDP and price level (inflation rate). A balanced panel annual data set of 18 SSA countries covering the period of 1995–2014 would be utilized, and all data are sourced from World Development Indicators (WDI) of World Bank.

Our definition of natural resource rent is akin to that of the World Bank and this variable is proxied by total natural resource rent. In the World Bank definition, natural resources are classified under five categories: oil, natural gas, forest and mineral. The aggregation of these categories yields total natural resource rent, which is measured in proportion to GDP. Thus, Fig. 1 below partitioned countries in SSA to include those whose resource rents as a percentage of GDP is <10 % (countries in black bars), 10–20 % (countries in yellow bars) and 20 % and above are in red bars.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Average natural resource rents in SSA (1991–2013)

Figures 2 and 3 below provides on a regional basis, a graphically illustration of average resource rents as percentage of GDP (Fig. 2) and average GDP person employed (Fig. 3). It is only a common sense argument that natural resource endowments provide an opportunity to improve economic growth and alleviate poverty. In this regard one expects that if properly harnessed, natural resource rents have the potential of making growth more inclusive in the SSA countries. With the exception of the Arab, Middle East and countries from North Africa (MENA), natural resource rents, as a percentage of GDP, for SSA is slightly higher than that of other regions.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Source plotted by the authors

Average natural resource rent (1991–2013).

Fig. 3
figure 3

Source plotted by the authors

Average GDP per-person employed (1991–2013).

After the 2000s energy crisis and recent oil discoveries, natural resource boom have contributed significantly to increases in government revenue of SSA, and same is expected to have been used to accelerate economic growth inclusiveness. Paradoxically, Figs. 2 and 3 appears to be going in an opposite directions. On the one hand, growth in the less resource endowed regions such as Europe, Latin America and North America seems to be inclusive on the basis of their impressive GDP per person employed. On the other hand, the use of resource rents in SSA countries and other resource endowed regions has been disappointing and growth in these regions can be said not to be inclusive especially in the sense of the abysmal level of GDP per person recorded in these resource endowed regions.

Access to health and education and other vital infrastructure such as safe drinking water and adequate sanitation defines the quality of human capital. In order to make the working population possess the human capabilities necessary to be productively employed, investment on human capital development such as spending on health care and education cannot be ignored. For growth to be inclusive, it needs to enhance human capabilities. Also, within the analytical framework of inclusive growth, health and education expenditures can also be utilized as indicators of the degree of equality of opportunity that a country’s population enjoys. To this end, we equally demonstrate graphically if available resource rent determines the level of investment in Haman Capital Development (HCD) on regional basis.

Thus, Fig. 4 represents average health expenditure per capita of both the resource rich regions and the less resource rich regions. Not too surprising though, Europe and North America despite being the least resource endowed regions tend to give priority to HCD on the basis of health expenditure than other regions. Specifically, their average per capita health expenditures between 1995 and 2013 are well above 6000 and 11,000 US dollar, respectively. On the contrary, however, health per capita expenditure in SSA and other resource rich regions such as Arab and MENA are far much lower than 1000 US dollar.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Source plotted by the authors

Average per-capita health expenditure (1995–2013).

In addition to health expenditure, spending on education is another important means of enhancing the ability of the populace to partake in growth process. Thus, Fig. 5 though depicts oil-producing regions as being relatively impressive in terms of their average education spending in relation to the level of GDP. However, the percentage share of SSA education expenditure to their level of GDP is still relatively lower as compared to other regions with the exception being the East Asia countries. This is an indication that resource rich countries in Sub-Saharan Africa are not only inclusively backward on the basis of their poor GDP person employed, but also in terms of their health and education expenditures.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Source plotted by the authors

Average education expenditure as a ratio of GDP (1995–2013).

Among the signs to identify countries with inclusive growth are decline trend of unemployment, poverty, and income inequality. This being the case, citizen would be able to contribute their quota to the national development. Until 2008, the global economy had witnessed massive reduction in rate of poverty and income inequality. A large proportion of this reduction is attributed to the emergence of the “Asian Tigers”; notable countries are China, India and East Asian countries. The inverse is the case for the African story.

Figure 6 below presents a graphical illustration of percentage of population living in households with consumption or income per person below the poverty line between 1981 and 2012. The graph shows that SSA recorded highest poverty rate relative to other regions over the years. This suggests that the largest percentage of the population living in households is below poverty line relative to other region. Ironically, the region that is blessed with a lot of natural resource rents could not cater for its citizens. Europe and central Asia that have the least resource endowment could cater for its citizens. This clearly show that the resources meant for the provision of infrastructure and other basic amenities in Sub-Saharan Africa are either mismanaged or embezzled by so called “leader”.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Source World Bank website using polvcalnet

% of population living in households with consumption or income per person below the poverty line (1981–2012). Note South Asia, East Asia and Pacific and Sub-Saharan Africa values are rescaled by dividing the series by 2. This is to enable us show the trend clearly because the values of other regions are very small.

Figure 7 depicts the income disparities at a sub-regional level for the regions. The disaggregation of income inequality into sub-region further shows the problem inherent in the African economy. The southern part of Africa recorded the highest level of income disparities among its citizens with Gini indices ranging from 49 to 52. Also, West, East and Central Africa have recorded an increasing uneven distribution of income whereas Southern and North Africa have recorded oscillations resulting in lower Gini Indices from decade of 2000–2009 compared to 1980–1989.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Source Milcent (2014)

Income inequality.

3.1 Model specification and methodological framework

Given our desire to account for the contribution of human capital to inclusive growth in SSA, this study adopts an augmented neoclassical model by Mankiw et al. (1992) to empirically evaluate if expenditure on education and health makes growth process inclusive in SSA. To achieve this: (1) we look at the direct effect of government’s education and health expenditures as well as natural resource rents on inclusive growth process; and (2) we examine if natural resource rents is important for augmenting expenditures on education and health to enhance the inclusion of human capital for inclusive growth process. In view of this, the baseline equation denoting the inclusive growth model without natural resource rents interaction is represented as follows:

$$INGROWTH_{it}\,=\,\alpha_{0} + \alpha_{1} LAB_{it} + \alpha_{2} CAP_{it} + \alpha_{3} EDU_{it} + \alpha_{4} HLT_{it} + \alpha_{5} NRS_{it} + Z^{\prime}\gamma + \mu_{i} + \varepsilon_{it}$$
(1)

Equation (1) is the baseline inclusive-growth model where \(INGROWTH_{it}\) is the log of GDP per person. The number of countries \(i = 1, \ldots ,N\); the number of periods \(t = 1, \ldots ,T\), \(LAB_{it}\) is log of population denoting labour force, \(CAP_{it}\) is the log of gross physical capital formation representing stock of physical capital, \(EDU_{it}\) is log of government expenditure on education, \(HLT_{it}\) is log of health expenditure per capita, NRS it is total natural resource rents as a percentage of GDP, while \(Z\) is a \(k \times 1\) vector of control variables. The latter includes inflation rate (INF it ) foreign direct investment (FDI it ) and trade openness (TOP it ). The regression parameters are \(\alpha_{0} ,\alpha_{1} ,\alpha_{2} ,\alpha_{3} ,\alpha_{4} ,\alpha_{5}\) while \(\gamma\) denotes a \(1 \times k\) vector of parameters on the control variables; \(\mu_{i}\) is the country-specific effect while \(\varepsilon_{it}\) is the regression disturbance term.

Consequently, the extended inclusive-growth specifications allowing for interaction between the respective conventional growth drivers such as education and health expenditures and natural resource rents is represented in Eq. (2) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} INGROWTH_{it} &\,=\,\alpha_{0} + \alpha_{1} LAB_{it} + \alpha_{2} CAP_{it} + \alpha_{3} EDU_{it} + \alpha_{4} \left( {EDU_{it} *NRS_{it} } \right) + \alpha_{5} HLT_{it} \\ & \quad + \,\alpha_{6} \left( {HLT_{it} *NRS_{it} } \right) + \alpha_{7} NRS_{it} + Z^{\prime}\gamma + \mu_{i} + \varepsilon_{it} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(2)

As shown in Eq. (2), in order to verify if natural resource rents enhances the inclusion of human capital in growth process in SSA, we interact growth determinant variables namely education and health expenditures with natural resource rents (NRS it ).

To complement this study, we further adopt a simulation methodology based on the intuition that human capital is a key driver of growth in an economy. Following this logic, we estimate the potential growth that is accruable by increasing government expenditure on health and education. We argue that natural resource rent should fund these expenditures.Footnote 18 It is assumed that in the process of increasing government expenditure, more jobs would be created, investment increases, which thus increase tax-based revenue of the government. This would invariable boost capital formation, which is part of the key drivers of long-run economic growth. In an attempt to capture this, we use the incremental capital output ratio (ICOR) derived from historical values of government expenditures on health and education.

We draw inferences and inspiration from the financing gap model, which is known to be useful for forecasting and policy simulations. International organizations such as the World Bank and the United Nations have based their simulation policies on this model. Despite its laudable advantage, it is not free from criticism. First, there is no direct relationship in the variables used for simulation or forecasting (i.e. it is not every dollar spent on education or health would yield extra growth). Second, the principles of ICOR assume linearity between and/or among variables of interest. The first problem can be addressed using historical data on government expenditure on education and health as well as growth. Using historical data also partly help address the concern that some expenditure might be driven by bad policies. The second criticism is about the precision of point estimates; this is less of a concern about estimates of the average impact over a long period. Nonetheless, the simulation results should be interpreted with caution. That is, they are only illustrative and useful in providing an order of magnitude rather than precise estimates of the impact.

Based on the foregoing, the first step is to calculate ICOR that measures the amount of expenditure needed to produce one extra unit of growth. ICOR is calculated given the formula below:

$$ICOR_{it} = \frac{{Gov.Expenditure_{it} }}{{GDP\_Growth_{it} }}$$
(3)

It should be noted that some countries might experience negative growth, which thus might produce negative values for ICOR, which does not have any empirical meaning. Hence, we used the absolute value of ICOR. It is a known fact that trend of economic growth rate of African countries are susceptible to volatility. This problem is addressed using the median value of ICOR over a period of time as against the estimated annual values. In specific reference, we used the 5-year non-overlapping periods, except the last period that has 4 years.

Using Eq. (3) and assuming that natural resource rent would produce the same output per dollar as historical values of government expenditure, the additional output resulting from investing the resource in rent is given as follows:

$$\Delta GDP^{\prime}_{it}\,=\,\frac{{RES_{it} }}{{ICOR_{i} }}$$
(4)

The potential GDP, which is the level that would be achieved by increasing government expenditure, is given as:

$$GDP_{it}^{*}\,=\,\Delta GDP^{\prime}_{it} + GDP_{it}$$
(5)

The last stage is to calculate the potential growth of output per capita by comparing the potential output growth with actual or historical data. This is achieved by implanting the formula below:

$$g_{t}^{*} = {\raise0.7ex\hbox{${\left( {\sum\limits_{0}^{T} {\frac{{GDP_{t}^{*} }}{{GDP_{t} }}*100\% } } \right)}$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\left( {\sum\limits_{0}^{T} {\frac{{GDP_{t}^{*} }}{{GDP_{t} }}*100\% } } \right)} T}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$T$}};{\text{ where T is }}5{\text{ years}}.$$
(6)

4 Empirical results

4.1 Panel models regression results

The empirical outcomes resulting from the estimation of the three static panel models considered however, reveals fixed effect as the preferred model to the pooled and random effect models. This is as a result of the significance of both the *F-statistic and the Hausman test prompting the rejection of the null hypothesis on both instances. To this end, we are statistically constrained to concentrate on discussing the practical and empirical implications of estimates from the fixed effect model only.

Thus, the empirical result in Table 1 below shows that inclusive growth in SSA countries can be positively and significantly enhanced by human capital development via spending on education and health cares. The magnitude of this association seems be more pronounced when the natural resource rent is interacted with health expenditure, while the interaction between natural resource rent and education expenditure constitute inclusive growth drag (though this is insignificant).

Table 1 Empirical results of inclusive growth models

Hence, the economic implication of the above empirical findings is that, inclusive growth in SSA countries can be amplified through government spending on education and health care over the period under consideration. What this implies is that inclusive growth in SSA requires more than just large size of labour force; but labour force with quality to be complimented with available capital stocks. More importantly also, inclusive growth in the region can be attained directly via effective allocation of resource rents even though using it to augment spending on human development via health expenditure increases the inclusiveness impacts of resource rents on growth process in SSA.

In sum, the view that human capital development via spending on education and health conclusive can aid the attainment of inclusive growth tends to be supported by the panel evidence reported in this study. Also, the statistical significant of both the direct and indirect impacts of resource rents on inclusive growth process as shown in our empirical report is to a meaningful extent, an indication that development of human capital for the attainment of growth inclusiveness can be fostered through effective allocation of resource rents in SSA.

4.2 Simulation exercise

The comprehensive report of the simulation exercise, which is meant to complement the results of the estimated panel model, is presented in Table 2. Precisely, the study based the simulation results on the assumption that the total natural resource revenue are spent on health sector. The exclusion of the education is due to its insignificant coefficients when interacted with natural resource rent. The result of the simulation exercise show that on the average, the region could have had an increased GDP per capita on about 3 %. Among the top gainers are Senegal, Ethiopia and Mozambique. It is puzzling to infer that countries such as Congo, DR and Cote d’Ivoire would experience growth drag should they embark on increasing government expenditure in the health sector. On the average, countries like Madagascar and Kenya have no incentive into improvement government expenditures on the health sector. A plausible reason for these scenarios is difficult to infer.

Table 2 Simulation exercise.

5 Conclusion

The study considered empirical analysis of inclusive growth, human capital development and natural resource rents in SSA. It utilizes all the three classes of static panel model to examine if, augmenting education and health expenditure with natural resource rents in SSA would be significant for making growth process inclusive. In addition, a financing gap model was further employed to estimate the potential growth in GDP per capita that is accruable to the economy if government use natural resource rent to finance increase in health expenditure.

Using dataset for 18 SSA countries, it was found that education and health are good determinants of inclusive growth. This however, appears to be more significantly pronounced when the interaction is between health expenditure and natural resource rent. Results of the simulation exercise show that SSA would have had a potential GDP per capita growth of about 3.1 %. It was also established that countries with relative higher GDP per capita (for instance, South Africa and Cote d’Ivoire) tend not to benefit from the additional increase in government expenditure on health.

The policy relevance of this study suggests that in an attempt to enhance inclusive growth, it is imperative for government to increase expenditure on education and health. This being the case, the productivity level of the country would increase, investment would be on the rise, and employment generation would soar, which thus increases tax-based revenue of the government. Hence, an attempt to increase government’s investment in these sectors would further generate additional revenue for the government. It can be stated that the effect of increase in government expenditure is a vicious cycle. Hence, it is important for government to focus on improving her expenditure on health.

This study was unable to provide explanation for the reason why countries with relative higher GDP per capita tend not to benefit from increasing government expenditure. Based on this, an interesting area where future research can beam the search light on is the level of income at which increase in government expenditure ion education and health would ensure growth and development. By this, it is implied that future studies should verify the existence of a threshold effect (if any) between government expenditures and national income level. Lastly, a very promising area future studies should focus their beam light on is the time lag between “cause” and “effect” of natural resource rent on inclusive growth.