Skip to main content
Log in

Welfare gains from the adoption of proportional taxation in a general-equilibrium model with a grey economy: the case of Bulgaria’s 2008 flat tax reform

  • Published:
Economic Change and Restructuring Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper provides a quantitative evaluation of the welfare effect of the introduction of proportional taxation in Bulgaria in 2008, an effect that operates through the grey economy channel. Using a general-equilibrium model, augmented with informal sector, a computational experiment is performed to evaluate the welfare gain from the adoption of proportional taxation. The lower effective tax burden in the new tax regime produces a relocation of people into the official sector, stimulates investment, and increases output and consumption. Finally, under the flat tax regime, the size of the informal sector is smaller, and quantitatively consistent with OECD (Is informal normal? Towards more and better jobs in developing countries. OECD, Paris, 2009) and European Commission (Tax reforms in EU member states, Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg, p 2012, 2012) figures.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Even though a flat corporate tax rate of 10 % (and a 5 % divident/capital gains tax) was introduced in 2007, the flat tax rate of 10 % on household’s income was introduced in 2008.

  2. Still, it is important to have the same tax rate applied to labor and capital income—otherwise small business owners would declare their income to be the one that is levied with the lower tax.

  3. In Bulgaria, the share of personal income tax revenue out of total government revenue is approximately 10 %.

  4. Given the lack of data on wages in the unofficial sector, it will be assumed that the most workers could earn there is the minimum wage. If that were not the case, those workers would have been better-off working in the official sector.

  5. As Conesa et al. (2001) point out, “those are neither illegal goods or services, nor home produced ones; the importance of this unregistered production is that it is non-tradables.”

  6. The description of the progressive tax system in Bulgaria in this section follows the structure used in Vasilev (2015).

  7. Since the introduction of the currency board arrangement in 1997, the lev is fixed to the Euro at the rate of 1 Euro =  BGN 1.95583.

  8. The second component, personal income tax revenue from business activities (14 %), is decreasing over the period, which reflects the financial crisis, but then rebounds in 2011.

  9. An alternative way to confirm the hypothesis that the increase in tax revenue is driven by improvements in tax compliance is to look at the implicit tax rate documented by the European Commission (2012): the rate before the introduction of the flat tax rate was 38.1 versus 24.4 % for the years after.

  10. As in Azacis and Gillman (2010), the model is a closed-economy one, which is a useful simplification. In a closed economy the return on capital is determined endogenously, and this assumption that cannot be relaxed so easily. However, under the assumption of a closed economy, the welfare gains from the introduction of a flat tax rate might be different from reality, as Bulgaria is a small open economy.

  11. The “wage rate” in the unofficial sector could also be interpreted as the opportunity cost of working in the unofficial sector.

  12. For simplicity, we shall assume that in this economy there are no financial assets and the public sector cannot issue debt.

  13. Notice that when \(\phi =0, \tau _{t}=\eta\), i.e., the tax rate is constant (“flat tax”), while \(\phi >0\) produces a tax rate that rises with total income (“progressive tax”).

  14. The low participation rate is consistent with the experience of Soviet and post-Soviet Baltic states, as documented in Smith (2014).

  15. In this way we can solve for the steady-state recursively, instead of solving for all variables jointly. Another advantage is that we can obtain the big ratios directly.

  16. For computational simplicity, steady-state output has been normalized to unity.

  17. More specifically, the average effective tax rate is approximated by the average amount of tax actually paid, divided by total income. Since the model is an infinitely-lived agents one, and the level of social contributions has not changed substantially, (except for the 3 % points cut in social security contributions in the last quarter of 2007, which was quickly reversed shortly after) the model will abstract away from those “taxes”.

  18. For the three tax brackets, \(\phi =0.43,0.57,0.70\), respectively. Robustness checks are performed in later sections of the paper to evaluate how welfare effect of the tax reform depends on the degree of progressivity of the previous regime.

  19. Enste (2002) calculate the average share of the grey economy in Bulgaria over the 1994–1995 period to be 0.327, while Nenovsky and Hristov (2000) compute that share to be 0.268 over the 1997–1999 period. Ahumada et al. (2009) obtain a conservative range of 0.122–0.175 for the share of the unofficial sector for the period 1998–2007.

  20. This long-term approach was preferred in order to abstract away from the effect of the financial crisis. After all, the tax reform in Bulgaria was introduced in the same year the financial crisis unravelled, so computation of the transition path was ruled out.

  21. On the other hand, Funke and Strulik (2006) find much smaller welfare gains using also an exogenous growth model to study the effect of the Estonian 2000 income tax act.

References

  • Ahumada H, Alvarado F, Canavese A, Grosman N (2009) The size of the shadow economy in Bulgaria: A measurement using the monetary method. BNB Discussion Paper 74, July 2009

  • Azacis H, Gillman M (2010) Flat tax reform: the Baltics 2000–2007. J Macroecon, 692–708

  • Charmes J (2000) Measurement of the contribution of informal sector/Informal employment to GDP in developing countries: some conceptual and methodological issues. 9th meeting of the Delhi group on informal sector statistics, Delhi, India, 11–12 May 2000

  • Conesa JC, Moreno CD, Sanchez JEG (2001) Underground economy and aggregate fluctuations. Span Econ Rev 3:41–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conesa JC, Kehoe TJ, Ruhl KJ (2007) Modeling great depressions: the depression in Finland in the 1990s. In: Prescott EC, Kehoe TJ (eds) Great Depressions Twentieth Century. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Minneapolis, pp 427–475

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2012) Tax reforms in EU member states, taxation paper 34. Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg, p 2012

  • Funke M, Strulik H (2006) Taxation, growth and welfare: dynamic effects of Estonia’s 2000 income tax act. Finn Econ Pap 19(1):25–38

    Google Scholar 

  • Ganev Kaloyan (2005) Measuring Total factor Productivity: Growth Accounting for Bulgaria. BNB Discussion paper, Sofia, Bulgaria

  • Ghez G, Becker G (1975) The Allocation of Time and Goods over the Life Cycle. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Guo J-T, Lansing KJ (1998) Indeterminacy and stabilization policy. J Econ Theory 82:481–490

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen G (1985) Indivisible labor and the business cycle. J Monet Econ 16:309–327

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King RG, Rebelo S (1990) Public policy and economic growth: developing neoclassical implications. J Polit Econ 98:S127–S150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas R (1990) Supply-side economics: an analytical review. Oxf Econ Pap 42(2):293–316

    Google Scholar 

  • Merz M (1995) Search in the labor market and the real business cycle. J Monet Econ 36(2):269–300

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nenovsky N, Hristov K (2000) Currency circulation after Currency Board Introduction in Bulgaria (Transactions Demand, Hoarding, Shadow Economy), Bulgarian National Bank Discussion Papers, 13/2000, October 2000

  • OECD (2009) Is informal normal? Towards more and better jobs in developing countries. OECD, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Paulus A, Peichl A (2009) Effects of flat tax reform in Western Europe. J Policy Model 31(5):620–636

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peichl A (2014) Flat-rate tax systems and their effect on labor markets. IZA World Labor 61:1–10

    Google Scholar 

  • Petkova L (2012) Tax Reform in Personal Income Taxation. Ministry of Finance, Republic of Bulgaria

    Google Scholar 

  • Prescott EC (2002) Prosperity and depression. Am Econ Rev 92:1–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogerson R (1988) Indivisible labor, lotteries and equilibrium. J Monet Econ 21:3–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith K (2014) Labour force participation in the Soviet and post-Soviet Baltic States. Econ Change Restruct 44(4):335–355

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vasilev A (2015) The welfare effect of flat income tax reform: the case of Bulgaria, Eastern European Economics, forthcoming

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Aleksandar Vasilev.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Vasilev, A. Welfare gains from the adoption of proportional taxation in a general-equilibrium model with a grey economy: the case of Bulgaria’s 2008 flat tax reform. Econ Change Restruct 48, 169–185 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-015-9159-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-015-9159-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation