Skip to main content
Log in

Analyzing trade opening in Ukraine: effects of a customs union with the EU

  • Published:
Economic Change and Restructuring Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper analyzes the possible effects of a customs union between Ukraine and the European Union. The GTAP multi-country simulation model of Purdue University’s Center for Global Trade Analysis is applied. The welfare measure evaluated is the change in equivalent variation (EV). As all incomes in the model accrue to a representative household, EV fully assesses possible welfare benefits for Ukraine from bilateral tariff elimination on trade with the EU. As the model includes Ukraine in the aggregated “Former Soviet Union” region (FSU), EV is estimated for the FSU and then disaggregated on the industry level proportionally to trade shares. The results of our simulations suggest that Ukraine’s EV is particularly sensitive to the inclusion of the agricultural sector into a customs union. Due to the highly protected nature of this sector within the EU, Ukraine would be better off if agriculture were excluded from liberalization. If this scenario is assumed, Ukraine’s monetary gain would be in the order of $40 million.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In 2001, real GDP growth for the coming years was projected to be up to 6% yearly (Postup’s Infobank 2001). See also EBRD (2001). In the following years until 2007, growth was in the order of magnitude of 4 to 8% (IER 2008). For more information and data on economic development in those years, see also Broll and Forster (2007).

  2. Further, Chang and Winters (1999) demonstrate that if a country enters Preferential Trading Arrangements (PTA) “other contracting parties [who fail to enter it] may …. be affected adversely, because they are compelled to reduce their prices to meet competition from the suppliers within the PTA” (p. 33).

  3. The top five of Ukraine’s trade partners are ranked as follows (1998): Export—Russia, China (steel), Turkey, Germany, Belarus; Import—Russia, Germany, US, Poland, Italy.

  4. Literature exploring the effects of trade liberalization and specifically aspects of trade diversion include Harrison et al. (1996), Chang and Winters (1999), Kose and Riezman (2000). Kose/Riezman analyze a three-country model and conclude that a small country will have a preference for building a bilateral customs union with a larger country or region. Chang/Winters estimated trade diversion effects of MERCOSUR on the USA, Germany and Japan. Harrison et al. estimate Turkey’s benefits from a customs union with the EU.

  5. In the early 1990s, strong state regulation of foreign trade was prevalent and even in 1999, no time plan was set for Ukraine to join the World Trade Organization (WTO) (e.g., Michalopoulos 1999). In fact, from the point of view of the WTO, Ukraine could still not be considered to be a market economy. However, in the year 2000, in the context of an anti-dumping investigation the European Union recognized Ukraine as a market economy; in the same year, the WTO announced Ukraine could be accepted as a member in the near future if its Parliament approved changes to about 60 laws and provisions as a precondition (Postup’s Infobank 2000, WTO 2000).

  6. The basis for EU-Ukraine relations was laid down in the Partnership and Co-operation Agreement (PCA) on 14 June 1994. Ukraine was the first of the Newly Independent States (NIS) to sign this kind of document with the EU to replace former Agreement on Trade and Commercial and Economic Co-operation with the USSR. The aim of the Parties to the document was it to establish a free trade area by 1998 if appropriate (Article 4 of PCA). According to the Agreement, the Parties grant to each other most-favored-nation (MFN) treatment and the products of the other party should not be subject to discriminatory direct or indirect taxation (A10 and 15 respectively). However, textile and steel products are exempted from the latter clause. Further, the Agreement encourages “the approximation of Ukraine’s existing and future legislation to that of the Community” (A51).

  7. See Hertel (1997) for a comprehensive documentation of the model. Schiff and Winters (2003) generally discuss applicability and limitations of CGE models Sulamaa and Widgren (2002)present an application of GTAP to Russian trade opening; other CGE analyses of Russia’s trade policy options include Brenton et al. (1997) and Alekseev et al. (2003).

  8. A natural next step for Ukraine’s trade relations would then be WTO accession. For related aspects see Burakovsky et al. (2003).

  9. Without further aggregation, this would result in more than 20,000 variables in more than 15,000 equations.

  10. See Hertel and Tsigas (1997). Some authors (Rutherford and Tarr 1998) assume increasing returns to scale and monopolistic competition in the intermediate sector. The basic argument for this is the assumed presence of high fixed costs for starting business in this sector.

  11. See Geraci and Prewo (1982).

  12. The inclusion of savings in static models like the GTAP model is based on results showing that an intertemporal expenditure system can be derived from a static maximization problem with savings (Howe 1975, presented also in Hertel and Tsigas (1997, p. 46).

  13. Inclusion of government expenditure into households’ utility is motivated by Keller (1980); see also Hertel and Tsigas (1997, p. 47). Of course, using Cobb-Douglas implies constant expenditure shares for each good.

  14. “Asia” contains a number of Asian high-growth countries, China, and Japan. For a detailed mapping of regions and sectors see the appendix.

  15. CEA includes 7 countries: Poland, Hungary, Czech Republic, Slovakia, Slovenia, Romania, and Bulgaria.

References

  • Alekseev A, Tourdyeva N, Yudayeva K (2003) Estimation of Russia’s trade policy options with the help of a computable general equilibrium model. CEFIR/NES Academic Paper No. 39

  • Astrov V, Havlik P (2005) The Enlarged European Union and Its Eastern Neighborhood. J East-West Bus 11(1–2):13–44. doi:10.1300/J097v11n01_03

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brenton P, Tourdyeva N, Whalley J (1997) The Potential Trade Effect of an FTA between the EU and Russia. Weltwirtsch Arch 133:205–225. doi:10.1007/BF02707460

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broll U, Forster A (2007) Economic Data on Ukraine. J Eur Econ 6(1):49–59

    Google Scholar 

  • Burakovsky I, Handrich L, Hoffmann L (2003) Ukraine’s WTO accession: challenge for domestic economic reforms. Physica Verlag, Heidelberg

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang W, Allan Winters L (1999) How regional blocks affect excluded countries. The price effects of MERCOSUR, World Bank Working Paper # 2157

  • Chesnokov A (2004) The EU enlargement impacts on the Ukrainian economy: correlation of negative and positive factors. J Eur Econ 3(4):457–463

    Google Scholar 

  • EBRD (2001) Business Central Europe. Accessed at: www.bcemag.com/statsdb

  • Geraci VJ, Prewo W (1982) An empirical demand and supply model of multilateral trade. Rev Econ Stat 64:432–441. doi:10.2307/1925941

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanoch G (1975) Production and demand models with direct and indirect implicit additivity. Econometrica 43:395–420. doi:10.2307/1914273

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harbuzyuk O (2001) Customs union with the EU: GTAP analysis for Ukraine. Master’s Thesis, EERC, Kyiv, Ukraine

  • Harrison GW, Rutherford TF, Tarr DG (1996) Economic implications for turkey of a customs union with the European union. World Bank Working Paper # 1599

  • Hertel TW (ed) (1997) Global trade analysis: modeling and applications. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Hertel TW, Tsigas ME (1997) Structure of GTAP. In: Hertel TW (ed) Global trade analysis: modeling and applications. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Huff KM, Hanslow K, Hertel TW, Tsigas ME (1997) GTAP behavioral parameters. In: Hertel TW (1997) Global trade analysis: modeling and applications. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Howe H (1975) Development of the extended linear expenditure system from simple savings assumptions. Eur Econ Rev 6:305–310. doi:10.1016/0014-2921(75)90014-8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • IER (2008) Macroeconomic forecast Ukraine. Accessed at: http://www.ier.kiev.ua/English/mfu_eng.cgi

  • IMF (1998) Directions of trade statistics yearbook. IMF, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Keller WJ (1980) Tax incidence: a general equilibrium approach. North Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Kose M Ayahan and Raymond Riezman (2000) Small countries and preferential trade agreements: how severe is the innocent bystander problem? CESifo Working Paper # 253. February

  • Michalopoulos C (1999). The integration of transition economies into the world trading system. World Bank Working Paper #2182. September

  • OECD (2003) OECD agricultural outlook: 2003–2008. OECD, Paris and Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Pakhomov YM, Lukyanenko DG, Hubskyi BV (1997) Natsionalna ekonomika v hlobalnomu konkurentnomu ceredovyshchi (In Ukrainian—“The National Economy in a Global Competitive Environment”). “Ukrayina”. Kyiv

  • Partnership and Co-operation Agreement between the European Communities and their Member States, and Ukraine (1994) 14 June

  • Postup’s Infobank (2000) Accessed at: http://ukrainet.com.ua/eng/page1006.html. 11 October, 19 October, 2 November, 7 November

  • Postup’s Infobank (2001) Accessed at: http://ukrainet.com.ua/eng/page1006.html. 17 January

  • Rutherford TF, Tarr DG (1998) Trade liberalization and endogenous growth in a small open economy: a quantitative assessment. World Bank Working Paper #1970

  • Schiff M, Winters L (2003) Regional Integration and Development. World Bank and Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sulamaa P, Widgren M (2002) EU enlargement and the opening of Russia: lessons from the GTAP reference model. The research Institute of the Finnish Economy Working Paper No. 11

  • TSN (2001) News service on the channel “1 plus 1”. Accessed at: http://www.int.1plus1.tv/568. April 18

  • White S, Korosteleva J, McAllister I (2008) A wider Europe? The view from Russia, Belarus and Ukraine. J Common Mark Stud 46(2):219–241. doi:10.1111/j.1468-5965.2007.00775.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2001) World Bank development statistics. Available at: devdata.worldbank.org

  • WTO (2000) Monitoring country progress in central and eastern Europe and Eurasia. International Trade Statistics 2000. USAID/E&E/PCS

Download references

Acknowledgements

The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the institutions they are affiliated with. The authors acknowledge the hospitality of the National University “Kiev-Mohyla Academy” and financial support by the Kyiv EERC Program in Economics and by the Institute of Economic Research and Policy Consulting (IER), Kiev. They also would like to thank Charles Steele and Roy Gardner for helpful comments and suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Stefan Lutz.

Additional information

Lutz also holds Research Fellowships at the University of Bonn and at the University of Manchester.

Appendices

Appendix: Aggregation of regions

Definition of new (aggregated) regions

ase

Quickly growing Asian economies (including China) and Japan

usa

USA

eun

European Union

eft

EFTA

cea

Central European Associates

fsu

Former Soviet Union

tur

Turkey

row

Rest of the world

Regions mapping

Previous

Previous region definition

New

AUS

Australia

row

NZL

New Zealand

row

JPN

Japan

ase

KOR

Republic of Korea

ase

IDN

Indonesia

ase

MYS

Malaysia

ase

PHL

Philippines

ase

SGP

Singapore

ase

THA

Thailand

ase

VNM

Viet Nam

row

CHN

China

ase

HKG

Hong Kong

ase

TWN

Taiwan

ase

IND

India

row

LKA

Sri Lanka

row

RAS

Rest of South Asia

row

CAN

Canada

row

USA

United States of America

usa

MEX

Mexico

row

CAM

Central America and Caribbean

row

VEN

Venezuela

row

COL

Colombia

row

RAP

Rest of Andean Pact

row

ARG

Argentina

row

BRA

Brazil

row

CHL

Chile

row

URY

Uruguay

row

RSM

Rest of South America

row

GBR

United Kingdom

eun

DEU

Germany

eun

DNK

Denmark

eun

SWE

Sweden

eun

FIN

Finland

eun

REU

Rest of European Union

eun

EFT

European Free Trade Area

eft

CEA

Central European Associates

cea

FSU

Former Soviet Union

fsu

TUR

Turkey

tur

RME

Rest of Middle East

row

MAR

Morocco

row

RNF

Rest of North Africa

row

SAF

South African Customs Union

row

RSA

Rest of Southern Africa

row

RSS

Rest of Sub Saharan Africa

row

ROW

Rest of World

row

Aggregation of industries

Definition of new (aggregated) sectors

 1. agr

Food products, plant-based fibers, fishery, beverages and tobacco

 2. for

Forestry, wood and paper products

 3. col

Coal

 4. o_g

Oil, gas, petroleum and coal products

 5. min

Minerals and chemicals

 6. tex

Textiles, wearing apparels, and leather products

 7. fer

Metals and metal products

 8. mac

Motor vehicles, transport and electronic equipment, machinery

 9. ele

Electricity

10. ser

Utilities, trade, transport, construction, financial services

Industries mapping

Previous

Previous industry definition

New

 1. pdr

Paddy rice

agr

 2. wht

Wheat

agr

 3. gro

Other cereal grains

agr

 4. v_f

Vegetables, fruit, nuts

agr

 5. osd

Oil seeds

agr

 6. c_b

Sugar cane, sugar beet

agr

 7. pfb

Plant-based fibers

agr

 8. ocr

Other crops

agr

 9. ctl

Bovine cattle, sheep and goats, horses

agr

10. oap

Other animal products

agr

11. rmk

Raw milk

agr

12. wol

Wool silk-worm cocoons

agr

13. for

Forestry

for

14. fsh

Fishing

agr

15. col

Coal

col

16. oil

Oil

o_g

17. gas

Gas

o_g

18. omn

Other minerals

min

19. cmt

Bovine cattle, sheep and goat, horse meat prods

agr

20. omt

Other meat products

agr

21. vol

Vegetable oils and fats

agr

22. mil

Dairy products

agr

23. pcr

Processed rice

agr

24. sgr

Sugar

agr

25. ofd

Other food products

agr

26. b_t

Beverages and tobacco products

agr

27. tex

Textiles

tex

28. wap

Wearing apparel

tex

29. lea

Leather products

tex

30. lum

Wood products

for

31. ppp

Paper products, publishing

for

32. p_c

Petroleum, coal products

o_g

33. crp

Chemical, rubber, plastic products

min

34. nmm

Other mineral products

min

35. i_s

Ferrous metals

fer

36. nfm

Other metals

fer

37. fmp

Metal products

fer

38. mvh

Motor vehicles and parts

mac

39. otn

Other transport equipment

mac

40. ele

Electronic equipment

mac

41. ome

Other machinery and equipment

mac

42. omf

Other manufactures

mac

43. ely

Electricity

ele

44. gdt

Gas manufacture, distribution

ser

45. wtr

Water

ser

46. cns

Construction

ser

47. t_t

Trade, transport

ser

48. osp

Financial, business, recreational services

ser

49. osg

Public admin and defense, education, health

ser

50. dwe

Dwellings

ser

Trade data used for calculations

Two sources of trade data used in this work are IMF (1998) and Pakhomov et al. (1997). IMF data (Table A1) is used to calculate Ukraine’s share in FSU’s exports and imports.

Table A1 Exports and imports of FSU countries, millions of US$

Pakhomov et al. (1997) data is used to calculate percentage structure of Ukrainian exports and imports. The original data and calculations are presented in Table A2.

Table A2 The structure of Ukrainian exports and imports, millions of US$

The next table shows the calculation of adjusted trade flows for Ukraine. It uses only relative relationships among different sectors. The table contains exports and imports at market prices and the figures for the FSU are taken from GTAP.

Table A3 Calculating adjusted trade flows for Ukraine, millions of US$

Then the numbers for total adjusted export and import for Ukraine are calculated using shares from Table A1. Finally, the value of each sector’s export and import is computed by applying weights from Table A2 to previously calculated total values. Further, Ukrainian adjusted exports are divided by FSU exports from Table A3 and the same is done for imports. Also, the sum of Ukraine’s exports and imports is divided by sum of FSU’s exports and imports to get weighting coefficients for EV due to the change in world prices. Computed weights are put down into Table A4 (compare Table 6 in the main text above).

Table A4 Share of Ukraine’s trade in FSU’s trade

GDP data used for calculations

For disaggregating non-trade allocation effects the weighting coefficients computed from the table below are used. Input data are from the World Bank (2001).

GDP at market prices (current $US millions), 1995

 

Armenia

2887

Azerbaijan

2894

Belarus

20071

Estonia

4789

Georgia

1900

Kazakhstan

19925

Kyrgyz Rep.

3325

Latvia

4904

Lithuania

6445

Moldova

3093

Russia

337902

Tajikistan

1827

Turkmenistan

4505

Ukraine

49061

Uzbekistan

16294

FSU

479822

Ukraine, share

0.1022

  1. Source: World Bank (2001) and author’s calculations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Harbuzyuk, O., Lutz, S. Analyzing trade opening in Ukraine: effects of a customs union with the EU. Econ Change Restruct 41, 221–238 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-008-9050-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-008-9050-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation