Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Promotion Incentives and Environmental Regulation: Evidence from China’s Environmental One-Vote Veto Evaluation Regime

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper applies a difference-in-differences approach to examine the effectiveness of China’s One-Vote Veto environmental regulation regime, which links pollution reduction targets with local officials’ promotion. Using a rich set of data for 286 Chinese cities, we show that the new political incentive induced significant tradeoff between economic growth and environmental protection. The regime shifts significantly reduced industrial SO2 emissions; however, the environmental improvement was limited only to the reduction of the targeted pollutants that are linked to performance evaluation. Firm-level evidence shows that emission reduction was mainly achieved by reducing new polluting production activities, increasing pollution abatement capacity and improving abatement performance. It is also found that compliance with emissions reduction targets indeed increases the promotion chances of local officials.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Comprehensive cost–benefit analyses are difficult and few in existing studies. On the one hand, the estimates of compliance costs are dropping due to ongoing innovations and technological breakthroughs in pollution abatement (Currie and Walker 2019), on the other hand, our understanding of the full benefits of improving air quality are changing rapidly with continued scientific discovery. See Currie and Walker (2019) for a review of the related literature.

  2. For a full description of the environmental protection measures under the 11th FYP and the new EOVV rule, please see: http://www.gov.cn/jrzg/2007-06/03/content_634545.htm (in Chinese).

  3. Notice of the State Environmental Protection Agency on Issuing the Measures for the Evaluation of Total Emission Reduction of Major Pollutants in the Eleventh Five-Year Plan (Trial). (No.124 (2007): http://www.gov.cn/gongbao/content/2008/content_961664.htm (in Chinese).

  4. Notice of the State Council on Issuing the Comprehensive Working Schemes on Energy Conservation and Emission Reduction (No. 15 [2007] of the State Council): http://www.gov.cn/jrzg/2007-06/03/content_634545.htm (in Chinese).

  5. Decision on Implementing the Scientific Outlook on Development and Strengthening Environmental Protection (No.39, 2005, State Council, in Chinese): http://www.gov.cn/zwgk/2005-12/13/content_125680.htm

  6. Reply of the State Council on the Plan for Controlling the Nationwide Total Discharge Volume of Major Pollutants in the 11th Five-year Plan Period (No. 70, 2006, State Council, in Chinese): http:/ www.gov.cn/gongbao/content/2006/content_394866.htm

  7. Guiding Opinions on the Allocation of Total Sulfur Dioxide (No.182, 2006, MEE, in Chinese): http://www.mee.gov.cn/gkml/zj/wj/200910/t20091022_172430.htm

  8. Reduction targets in absolute values do not reflect the difference in marginal abatement costs (MAC) in cities with different levels of emissions. However, relative reduction targets are not an ideal fix either. There has been a large literature on the estimation of MACs of pollutants but no consensus that MAC is empirically related to the size of emissions in any systematic manner. This is because MAC is essentially a reflection of production technology associated with a specific industry structure. Production technology can be heterogeneous across regions and so is industry structure. It is not uncommon that an underdeveloped region with relatively low level of emissions also has lower MAC. This complexity perhaps partly explains the fact that scholars have argued for and used both absolute (Chen et al., 2018b; Fan et al., 2019) and relative targets (Shi and Xu, 2018).

  9. In China, mayor is the executive officer of a city government by law. The division of labor is that secretary is in charge of the personnel and other political duties, while the mayor is in charge of the daily operation of government including economic growth and environmental protection (Zheng et al. 2014; Yao and Zhang 2015). Therefore, we follow Zheng et al. (2014) and use city mayors. However, we also provide results on party secretaries as supplementary materials.

  10. The party secretary is considered a higher level than the mayor because key decisions are often made in the party committee.

  11. As GDP growth is most directly related to industrial rather than residential SO2 emissions, this paper uses industrial SO2 emissions which account for most of the SO2 emissions in China.

  12. China’s national industrial classification standard GB/T 4754–2002 classifies all industrial production into 39 two-digit industries, ranging from 6 to 46 with 12 and 38 left vacant in the classification.

  13. We do not include longer data periods (e.g. 12th FYP) in the main analysis. This is to avoid possible influences from confounding policies introduced later, the Air Pollution Prevention and Control Action Plan implemented in 2013 in particular. Although this plan mainly addresses emissions of PM2.5, its impacts on SO2 emissions are also obvious. Focusing on the 10th FYP and 11th FYP thus reduces possible confounding effects and provides us a cleaner identification. We provide additional results based on longer datasets in Table A2 in the Supplementary Materials. The results are largely similar to those reported here.

  14. Cultural Relics Protection Law of the People's Republic of China (2013 Amendment) (No. 5 [2013], Standing Committee of the National People’s Congress): http://www.gov.cn/flfg/2013-06/30/content_2437158.htm (in Chinese).

  15. A city being nationally listed FHCC or historical treaty ports is likely to have a stronger economic base or a characterized industrial structure. or have a significant impact on attracting labor and investment. Jia (2014) indicated that commerce and service sector are the major support of treaty ports. As a robustness check, we included FDI, total labor and the share of tertiary industry in GDP as additional controls. The results are similar to those reported in Table 3. We provide these results in Table A5 as supplementary materials.

  16. Beijing, Tianjin, Shanghai, Qingdao, Shenyang, Qinhuangdao, Tangshan, Zhangjiakou, Baoding, Cangzhou, and Chengde.

  17. A total of 44 cities are removed from the sample. The calculated mean and standard deviation of the differences in SO2.reduction targets of bordering cities are -0.007 and 3.093 respectively.

  18. The five most SO2-polluting industries include “production and supply of electric power and heat power”, “manufacture of non-metallic mineral products”, “melting and pressing of ferrous metals”, “manufacture of raw chemical materials and chemical products” and “melting and pressing of non-ferrous metals”. These five most polluting industries comprise 85% of total industrial SO2 emissions. The five least SO2-polluting industries include “production and distribution of water”, “printing, reproduction of recording media”, “recycling and disposal of waste”, “manufacture of measuring instruments and machinery for cultural activity and office work” and “manufacture of tobacco”. These five least SO2- polluting industries account for less than 1% of total industrial SO2 emissions.

  19. We also provide the results using the most polluting and least polluting five industries in appendix Table A6. The results are similar to Table 7.

  20. We also provide the analysis and results on party secretaries in Table A8 in the Supplementary Materials. The literature on the effects on secretaries are rather mixed (Zheng et al. 2014; Yao and Zhang 2015; Wang and Lei, 2021). Zheng et al. (2014) and Wang and Lei (2021) both found that the effects are different for mayors and secretaries. Zheng et al. (2014) found the effect on party secretaries is insignificant. The results provide in Table A8 also show that the effect on party secretaries is statistically insignificant.

References

  • Au CC, Henderson JV (2006) How migration restrictions limit agglomeration and productivity in China. J Dev Econ 80(2):350–388

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blackman A, Lahiri B, Pizer W, Planter MR, Piña CM (2010) Voluntary environmental regulation in developing countries: Mexico’s clean industry program. J Environ Econ Manag 60(3):182–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O, Shleifer A (2000) Federalism with and without political centralization. China versus Russia. IMF Staff Pap 48(1):171–179

    Google Scholar 

  • Bracken G (2019) Treaty ports in China: their genesis, development, and influence. J Urban Hist 45(1):468–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandt L, Van Biesebroeck J, Zhang Y (2012) Creative accounting or creative destruction: firm level productivity growth in Chinese manufacturing. J Dev Econ 97(2):339–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cai X, Lu Y, Wu M, Yu L (2016) Does environmental regulation drive away inbound foreign direct investment? Evidence from a quasi-natural experiment in China. J Dev Econ 123:73–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen Y, Li H, Zhou LA (2005) Relative performance evaluation and the turnover of provincial leaders in China. Econ Lett 88(3):421–425

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen YJ, Li P, Lu Y (2018a) Career concerns and multitasking local bureaucrats: evidence of a target-based performance evaluation system in China. J Dev Econ 133:84–101

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen Z, Kahn ME, Liu Y, Wang Z (2018b) The consequences of spatially differentiated water pollution regulation in China. J Environ Econ Manag 88:468–485

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chetty R, Looney A, Kroft K (2009) Salience and taxation: theory and evidence. Am Econ Rev 99(4):1145–1177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Combes PP, Démurger S, Li S (2013) Urbanization and migration externalities in China. Aix-Marseille school of economics working papers No. 1307

  • Currie J, Walker R (2019) What do economists have to say about the clean air act 50 Years after the establishment of the environmental protection agency? J Econ Perspect 33(4):3–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deng Y, Wu Y, Xu H (2019) Political turnover and firm pollution discharges: an empirical study. China Econ Rev 58:101363

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • der Kamp V, Lorentzen DP, Mattingly D (2017) Racing to the bottom or to the top? Decentralization, revenue pressures, and governance reform in China. World Dev 95:164–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fan H, Zivin JS, Kou Z, Liu X, Wang H (2019). Going green in China: Firms’ responses to stricter environmental regulations (No. w26540). National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Farzanegan MR, Mennel T (2012) Fiscal decentralization and pollution: institutions matter. magks joint discussion paper series in economics, No. 22–2012. https://www.unimarburg.de/fb02/makro/forschung/magkspapers/22-2012_farzanegan.pdf.

  • Feng GF, Dong M, Wen J, Chang CP (2018) The impacts of environmental governance on political turnover of municipal party secretary in China. Environ Sci Pollut Res 25:24668–24681

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferrara EL, Chong A, Duryea S (2012) Soap operas and fertility: evidence from Brazil. Am Econ J Appl Econ 4(4):1–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gao N, Liang P (2016) Fresh cadres bring fresh air? Personnel turnover, institutions, and China’s water pollutions. Rev Dev Econ 20(1):48–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenstone M, Jack BK (2014) “Effortless perfection:” Do Chinese cities manipulate air pollution data? J Environ Econ Manag 68(2):203–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenstone M, Jack BK (2015) Envirodevonomics: a research agenda for an emerging field. J Econ Lit 53(1):5–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • He G, Fan M, Zhou M (2016) The effect of air pollution on mortality in China: evidence from the 2008 Beijing Olympic Games. J Environ Econ Manag 79:18–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • He G, Wang S, Zhang B (2020) Watering down environmental regulation in China. Q J Econ 135(4):2135–2185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hering L, Poncet S (2014) Environmental policy and exports: evidence from Chinese cities. J Environ Econ Manag 68(2):296–318

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho M, Jorgenson D (2002) Pollution taxes and public health. In: Economics of the environment in China. Boyds: Aileen International, Maryland. China council for international cooperation on environment and development environmental economics working group, pp 165–200

  • Ho M, Jorgenson D (2003) Air pollution in China: sector allocation emissions and health damage. China council for international cooperation on environment and development

  • Huang J, Yu Y, Ma C (2018) Energy efficiency convergence in China: catch-up, lock-in and regulatory uniformity. Environ Resour Econ 70:107–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jia R (2014) The legacies of forced freedom: China’s treaty ports. Rev Econ Stat 96(4):596–608

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jia R, Kudamatsu M, Seim D (2015) Political selection in China: the complementary roles of connections and performance. J Eur Econ Assoc 13(4):631–668

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jiang L, Lin C, Lin P (2014) The determinants of pollution levels: firm-level evidence from Chinese manufacturing. J Comp Econ 42(1):118–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jiang Q, Yang S, Tang P, Bao L (2020) Promoting the polluters? The competing objectives of energy efficiency, pollutant emissions, and economic performance in Chinese municipalities. Energy Res Soc Sci 61:101365

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahn ME, Li P, Zhao D (2015) Water pollution progress at borders: the role of changes in China’s political promotion incentives. Am Econ J Econ Policy 7(4):223–242

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landry Pierre Francois (2008) Decentralized authoritarianism in China: the communist party’s control of local elites in the post-mao era. Cambridge Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Li H, Zhou LA (2005) Political turnover and economic performance: the incentive role of personnel control in China. J Public Econ 89(9–10):1743–1762

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li F, Wang Z, Huang L (2022) Economic growth target and environmental regulation intensity: evidence from 284 cities in China. Environ Sci Pollut Res 29(7):10235–10249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lopez R, Mitra S (2000) Corruption, pollution, and the Kuznets environment curve. J Environ Econ Manag 40(2):137–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maskin E, Qian Y, Xu C (2000) Incentives, information, and organizational form. Rev Econ Stud 67(2):359–378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro JS, Walker R (2018) Why is pollution from US manufacturing declining? The roles of environmental regulation, productivity, and trade. Am Econ Rev 108(12):3814–3854

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shi X, Xu Z (2018) Environmental regulation and firm exports: evidence from the eleventh FYP in China. J Environ Econ Manag 89:187–200

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sigma H (2014) Decentralization and environmental quality: an international analysis of water pollution levels and variation. Land Econ 90(1):114–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tang P, Jiang Q, Mi L (2021) One-vote veto: the threshold effect of environmental pollution in China’s economic promotion tournament. Ecol Econ 185:107069

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Rooij B, Lo CW (2010) Fragile convergence: understanding variation in the enforcement of China’s industrial pollution law. Law Policy 32(1):14–37

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang J, Lei P (2021) The tournament of Chinese environmental protection: Strong or weak competition? Ecol Econ 181:106888

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whiting SH (2004) The cadre evaluation system at the grass roots: the paradox of party rule. In: Yang D, Naughton B (eds) Holding China together: diversity and national integration in the post-Deng Era. Cambridge University Press, New York, pp 101–119

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (1997) Clear water, blue skies: China’s environment in the New Century. Technical report, Washington D.C

  • World Bank (2007) Cost of pollution in China: economic estimates of physical damages. Technical report. World Bank, East Asia and Pacific Region, Washington, DC

  • Wu M, Cao X (2021) Greening the career incentive structure for local officials in China: Does less pollution increase the chances of promotion for Chinese local leaders? J Environ Econ Manag 107:102440

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu J, Ma C (2019) The convergence of China’s marginal abatement cost of CO2: an emission-weighted continuous state space approach. Environ Resour Econ 72(4):1099–1119

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu J, Deng Y, Huang J, Morck R, Yeung B (2013) Incentives and outcomes, China’s environmental policy. Capital Soc 9(1):1–41

    Google Scholar 

  • Wu J, Wu Y, Guo X, Cheong TS (2016) Convergence of carbon dioxide emissions in Chinese cities: a continuous dynamic distribution approach. Energy Policy 91:207–219

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yao Y, Zhang M (2015) Subnational leaders and economic growth: evidence from Chinese cities. J Econ Growth 20(4):405–436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zheng S, Kahn ME (2013) Understanding China’s urban pollution dynamics. J Econ Lit 51(3):731–772

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zheng S, Kahn ME, Sun W, Luo D (2014) Incentives for China’s urban mayors to mitigate pollution externalities: the role of the central government and public environmentalism. Reg Sci Urban Econ 47:61–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zho LA (2008) Local governments in transition: incentive and governance of officials in China. Shanghai People’s Press, Shanghai

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

All authors have materially participated in the research and article preparation. JXW and CM designed research; JXW and XLZ collected data; CM, JXW, and XLZ performed research and analyzed data; and CM and JXW wrote the paper.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chunbo Ma.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare no known interests related to their submitted manuscript.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file 1 (DOCX 1487 KB)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Wu, J., Feng, Z. & Ma, C. Promotion Incentives and Environmental Regulation: Evidence from China’s Environmental One-Vote Veto Evaluation Regime. Environ Resource Econ 87, 257–286 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-023-00824-z

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-023-00824-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation