Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Supply-Side Climate Policy: On the Role of Exploration and Asymmetric Information

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In the world economy with interdependent markets for fossil fuel deposits and extracted fossil fuel, a coalition of countries may fight climate change by purchasing fossil fuel deposits for preservation. Harstad (J Polit Econ 120:77–115, 2012) has shown that the coalition’s supply-side climate policy implements the first-best. The present paper focuses on the role exploration and asymmetric information with respect to climate damage plays for the efficiency of unilateral supply-side climate policy. Under the assumption of non-strategic exploration and truthful reporting of climate damage, the deposit policy turns out to be efficient. If exploration is used strategically or the coalition misreports its climate damage, however, the deposit policy becomes inefficient.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Demand-side climate policies are policies that reduce the consumption of fossil fuels within the subglobal climate coalition.

  2. In the section on conclusions and limitations, Harstad (2012, p. 107) points to the possibility that the non-participants’ incentive to search for new deposits may weaken his efficiency result.

  3. We could also consider asymmetric information with respect to extraction costs and/or exploration investments. However, in our view misreporting extraction costs is difficult and avoidable by appropriate contracts, since the country that has purchased fuel reserves is able to reveal the true costs. In contrast, the coalition’s climate damage is information that cannot easily be acquired by other countries.

  4. Wheat is the numeraire and the price of labor is unity as well due to the linear production function.

  5. Our extraction cost function with exploration is consistent with Pindyck (1978) and Pesaran (1990) who assume that extraction costs are the lower the greater the deposit reserves which in turn are increasing in exploration investments. Alternatively, the extraction cost function extended by effort e may be interpreted as an improvement in extraction technology.

  6. A straightforward way to decentralize the social planner’s solution is to set \(B^{'*}_M = B^{'*}_N = p\) and to impose an emissions tax at the uniform rate \(t = H'(x^{*}_M + x^{*}_N)\) on the fuel output of both countries. The decentralization via trade in deposits is also possible but less straightforward. See Eichner and Pethig (2017a).

  7. We denote the sequence of stages by 0, 1, 2 and 3 (rather than 1, 2, 3, 4) to ease the comparison with the games in Harstad (2012) and Eichner and Pethig (2017a).

  8. It is also conceivable that country N explores after—or even before and after—the deposit market cleared. Since we find exploration at stage 0 particularly plausible and want to keep complexity low, we will proceed by assuming that exploration takes place at stage 0 only.

  9. In Harstad (2012) as well as in Eichner and Pethig (2017a), M buys deposits for preservation in some interval \( \left[ \underline{\xi }, \overline{\xi } \right] _{C'_N}\) with \(\overline{\xi } > \underline{\xi }\). Here we assume that M buys the deposits \([ \overline{\xi }, \infty [_{C'_N}\) for preservation in addition to \(\left[ \underline{\xi }, \overline{\xi } \right] _{C'_N}\). As we will explain below, the exploitation of the deposits \([\overline{\xi }, \infty [_{C'_N}\) is unprofitable for country N and therefore country N would not have exploited these deposits anyway. Thus, the purchases of \(\left[ \underline{\xi }, \overline{\xi } \right] _{C'_N}\) and \([\underline{\xi }, \infty [_{C'_N}\) for preservation are equivalent. Here we proceed with the purchase of deposits in the interval \([\underline{\xi }, \infty [_{C'_N}\) for the benefit of analytical simplicity.

  10. Here we assume that the socially optimal allocation of the economy under review exhibits \(y_M^{*}>x_M^{*}\). For details see Eichner and Pethig (2017a).

  11. The deposit transaction \([\underline{\chi }, \overline{\chi }]_{C'_N}\) leaves the shape of N’s marginal extraction curve unchanged because we assume that N’s extraction firm extracts and sells the fuel from \([\underline{\chi }, \overline{\chi }]_{C'_N}\) and then transfers the profits to M. See also Eq. (18) and the subsequent text.

  12. If \(\underline{\xi }\) were not strictly binding, M’s unilateral climate policy were completely ineffective.

  13. See Lemma 1 in Eichner and Pethig (2017a).

  14. Observe that this equation equals the optimal allocation rule (8b) for N.

  15. For details see Eichner and Pethig (2017a).

  16. In other words, trading the deposits \([\underline{\chi }, \overline{\chi }]_{C'_N}\) at a price equal to the profits of exploiting them leaves both countries’ welfare unaffected.

  17. Alternatively, we could adopt a more appealing concept to solve the bargaining subgame, e.g. the Nash bargaining solution. But that would raise the complexity of the formal analysis without changing the qualitative results concerning the (in)efficiency of strategic action. Besides, we would also need to assume that the ‘rule’ to apply that solution concept is common knowledge.

  18. The graph of the marginal cost curve \(K'\)(\(x_M\), \(\underline{\xi }\), \(e_1\)) is given by the kinked line \(A_1 B_1 D_1\).

  19. The timing of game E excludes the possibility that country B may decide to explore for new deposits after having traded deposits for conservation in the future. This amounts to the implicit assumption that the two parties conducted a contract which excludes future exploration.

  20. In (26), country N’s “initial” endowment of deposits is given by \(C_N(x_N, e=0)\). Therefore, N’s curves of total and marginal costs lie above the respective curves of the coalition for all exploration efforts \(e < \phi / \sigma \). Results are sensitive with regard to the form of parametrization.

  21. The equilibrium of game E is marked by a tilde.

  22. That country N imports and the coalition exports fuel is a result that is driven by the assumptions of identical benefit functions and country N’s higher extraction cost in the absence of exploration \((C_N(x_N, 0) > C_M(x_M))\).

  23. \(\ldots \) disregarding the exceptional case in which \((p-C_N') \frac{\partial \underline{\xi }_N}{\partial e}- (y_N - \underline{\xi }) \frac{\partial \hat{P}}{\partial e} + \frac{\partial \theta }{\partial e}=0\).

  24. The allocative displacement effects may change for parametric functions satisfying \(\frac{\partial \theta }{\partial e} \ne 0\).

  25. Analogous to \(\theta (e,1)\) in (24), the specification of the deposit price \(\theta (e^{*}, g)\) in (27) requires assuming that the share parameter \(\mu \) is agreed upon at stage 0.

  26. The equilibrium of game G is marked by a tilde (without risk of confounding it with the equilibrium of game E).

  27. Observe that although (31) equals (25b) and (32) equals (28) at face value, these equations are not identical, because in (25b) it holds \(g=1\), in (28) it holds \(e=e^{*}\) whereas (31) and (32) depend both on g and e.

  28. Since the marginal effects and the allocative displacement effects are similar to those of Sects. 4.1 and 4.2 we refrain from presenting them here.

  29. For the efficiency of the game A in that case we refer to Harstad 2012, Theorem 1(v).

  30. See http://amazonwatch.org/news/2010/0119-yasuni-itt-chronicle-of-a-death-foretold and http://amazonwatch.org/news/2016/1212-as-oil-companies-dig-into-yasuni-national-park-ecuadorians-are-fighting-back. Sites accessed on June 13, 2017.

  31. http://amazonwatch.org/news/2016/1212-as-oil-companies-dig-into-yasuni-national-park-ecuadorians-are-fighting-back.

  32. Observe that \(\frac{\beta +c}{\alpha c - (\beta +3c)h} -\frac{2(\beta +c)}{2 \alpha c + \beta h } = \frac{3(\beta +c)(2c+\beta ) h}{[\alpha c - (\beta +3c)h](2 \alpha c + \beta h)}>0\).

References

  • Bohm P (1993) Incomplete international cooperation to reduce \(\text{CO}_2\) emissions: alternative policies. J Environ Econ Manag 24:258–271

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Copeland B, Taylor S (1995) Trade and transboundary pollution. Am Econ Rev 85:716–717

    Google Scholar 

  • Eichner T, Pethig R (2017a) Buy coal and act strategically on the fuel market. Eur Econ Rev 99:77–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichner T, Pethig R (2017b) Self-enforcing environmental agreements and trade in fossil energy deposits. J Environ Econ Manag 85:1–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichner T, Pethig R (2017c) Trade in fossil fuel deposits for preservation and strategic action. J Publ Econ 147:50–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harstad B (2012) Buy coal! A case for supply-side environmental policy. J Polit Econ 120:77–115

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoel M (1994) Efficient climate policy in the presence of free riders. J Environ Econ Manag 27:259–274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kiyono K, Ishikawa J (2013) Environmental management policy under international carbon leakage. Int Econ Rev 54:1057–1083

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markusen J (1975) International externalities and optimal tax structures. J Int Econ 5:15–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pesaran MH (1990) An econometric analysis of exploration and extraction of oil in the U.K. continental shelf. Econ J 100:367–390

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pindyck RS (1978) The optimal exploration and production of non-renewable resources. J Polit Econ 86:841–861

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Postlewaite A (1979) Manipulation via endowments. Rev Econ Stud 2:255–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ulph A (1996) Environmental policy instruments and imperfectly competitive international trade. Environ Resour Econ 24:258–271

    Google Scholar 

  • Van der Meijden G, van der Ploeg F, Withagen C (2015) International capital markets, oil producers and the green paradox. Eur Econ Rev 76:275–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thomas Eichner.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Financial support from the German Science foundation (DFG Grant Nos. EI 847/1-2 and PE 212/9-2) is gratefully acknowledged. Thanks also to Mark Schopf and two anonymous referees for helpful comments. Remaining errors are the authors’ sole responsibility.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Proposition 1

Conditional on e and g the efficient allocation rules are

$$\begin{aligned}&B'_M (y_M) = B'_N (y_N), \end{aligned}$$
(A1a)
$$\begin{aligned}&B'_M (y_M)- g H'(x_M + x_N) = C'_M (x_M), \, B'_N(x_N) - g H'(x_M + x_N) = C'_N (x_N, e). \end{aligned}$$
(A1b)

The equilibrium of game A is characterized by

$$\begin{aligned} B'_N =p, \quad p= C'_N + g H' \,\, (\text{see } \, (16)). \end{aligned}$$
(A2)

Accounting for (18) in (12) and (13) we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} B'_M =p, \quad p= C'_M + g H'. \end{aligned}$$
(A3)

Comparing (A2) and (A3) with (A1a) and (A1b) establishes Proposition 1(i). The proof of Proposition 1(ii) is straightforward. \(\square \)

1.2 Parametric Model

Efficiency. For the parametric functions

$$\begin{aligned}&B(y_i) = \alpha y_i - \frac{\beta }{2} y_i^2, \quad C_M(x_M) =\frac{c}{2} x_M^2, \quad C_N(x_N, e) = \frac{c}{2} \left[ x_N+ (\phi - \sigma e) \right] ^2, \\&H (x_M+x_N) = h (x_M +x_N) \end{aligned}$$
(A4)

(with \(C_N'= c \left[ x_N + (\phi - \sigma e) \right] \), \(\frac{\partial C_N}{\partial e}= - c \sigma \left[ x_N + (\phi - \sigma e) \right] \)) we solve

$$\begin{aligned}&\alpha - \beta y_M = \alpha - \beta y_N, \end{aligned}$$
(A5)
$$\begin{aligned}&\alpha - \beta y_M = c x_M + h, \end{aligned}$$
(A6)
$$\begin{aligned}&\alpha - \beta y_N =c \left[ x_N+ (\phi - \sigma e) \right] + h, \end{aligned}$$
(A7)
$$\begin{aligned}&y_M + y_N = x_M + x_N, \end{aligned}$$
(A8)
$$\begin{aligned}&c \sigma \left[ x_N+ (\phi - \sigma e) \right] = 1 \end{aligned}$$
(A9)

to obtain

$$\begin{aligned} y_M^{*}&= y_N^{*} = \frac{(\alpha -h) \sigma -1}{\beta \sigma }, \quad x_M^{*} = \frac{1}{c \sigma } , \quad x_N^{*} = \frac{2c [(\alpha -h) \sigma -1] - \beta }{\beta \sigma }, \\ e^{*}&= \frac{2c [(\alpha - h) \sigma -1] - \beta (2 -c \sigma \phi )}{\beta c \sigma ^2}, \end{aligned}$$
(A10)

which implies

$$\begin{aligned} p^{*} = h + \frac{1}{\sigma }. \end{aligned}$$
(A11)

Stages 1–3 of the games. For the parametric functions it holds

$$\begin{aligned} y_M&= y_N = \frac{\alpha -p}{\beta }, \quad x_M =\frac{p-g h}{c}, \quad x_N = \underline{\xi }, \end{aligned}$$
(A12)
$$\begin{aligned} p&= C'_N(\underline{\xi }, e )+ gh \quad \iff \quad \underline{\xi } = \frac{p- g h}{c} - (\phi - \sigma e) \end{aligned}$$
(A13)

and

$$\begin{aligned} p = C'_N(\overline{\xi }, e ) \quad \iff \quad \overline{\xi } =\frac{p}{c} - (\phi - \sigma e). \end{aligned}$$
(A14)

Inserting (A12) and (A13) into the fuel market clearing condition

$$\begin{aligned} y_M + y_N = x_M +x_N \quad \iff \quad 2 \frac{\alpha -p}{\beta } =\frac{p- g h}{c} + \frac{p-g h}{c} -(\phi - \sigma e) \end{aligned}$$
(A15)

and solving with respect to p we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} p = \hat{P} (e, g):= \frac{2 (\alpha c + \beta g h ) + (\phi - \sigma e) \beta c}{2 (\beta +c)}. \end{aligned}$$
(A16)

Differentiating (A16) with respect to e and g gives \(\hat{P}_e=- \frac{ \beta c \sigma }{2 (\beta + c)}\) and \(\hat{P}_g= \frac{\beta h}{\beta +c}\).

Inserting (A16) into (A12)–(A15) yields

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{Y}_M (e, g) = \hat{Y}_N (e, g)&= \frac{2 (\alpha - gh ) -(\phi - \sigma e) c}{2 (\beta +c)}, \end{aligned}$$
(A17)
$$\begin{aligned} \hat{X}_M (e, g)&= \frac{2 (\alpha - gh ) + (\phi - \sigma e) \beta }{2 (\beta +c)}, \end{aligned}$$
(A18)
$$\begin{aligned} \overline{\xi } (e, g)&= \frac{2 (\alpha c +\beta gh ) - (\phi - \sigma e) c (\beta +2c)}{2 (\beta +c) c}, \end{aligned}$$
(A19)
$$\begin{aligned} \underline{\xi } (e, g)&= \frac{2 (\alpha - gh ) - (\phi - \sigma e) (\beta +2c)}{2 (\beta +c)}. \end{aligned}$$
(A20)

Next, straightforward calculations lead to

$$\begin{aligned} \theta _{\max } (e, g)&= g h (\overline{\xi } - \underline{\xi }) = \frac{g^2 h^2}{c}, \end{aligned}$$
(A21)
$$\begin{aligned} \theta _{\min } (e, g)&= p (\overline{\xi } - \underline{\xi }) - \frac{c}{2} \left[ \left( \frac{p}{c}\right) ^2 - \left( \frac{p-gh}{c}\right) ^2 \right] = \frac{p gh}{c} - \frac{1}{2 c} \left( 2p g h - g^2 h^2 \right) \\&= \frac{g^2 h^2}{2 c}, \end{aligned}$$
(A22)
$$\begin{aligned} G(e,g)&= \theta _{\max } - \theta _{\min } = \frac{g^2 h^2}{2c}, \end{aligned}$$
(A23)
$$\begin{aligned} \theta (e,g)&= \theta _{\min } + \mu G = (1+\mu ) \frac{g^2 h^2}{2c}. \end{aligned}$$
(A24)

Exploration (GameE). For the parametric functions the first-order condition (25b) turns into

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}} U_N}{{\mathrm {d}} e}&= \underbrace{(p-C'_N)}_{=h} \frac{\partial \underline{\xi }}{\partial e} - (y_N - \underline{\xi } ) \frac{\partial \hat{P}}{\partial e} + \frac{\partial \theta }{\partial e} - \frac{\partial C_N (\underline{\xi }, e)}{\partial e} - 1 \\&= \frac{(\beta +2c) \sigma h}{2(\beta +c)} - \left[ \frac{\alpha -p}{\beta } - \frac{p-h}{c} + (\phi - \sigma e) \right] \left( \frac{\beta c \sigma }{2(\beta +c)} \right) \\&\quad + (p-h) \sigma - 1 =0. \end{aligned}$$
(A25)

Solving \(p = \hat{P}(e,1)\) from (A16) and (A25) with respect to p and e we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{p} = \frac{2(\beta +c) + (\alpha c + 2 \beta h) \sigma }{3(\beta +c)\sigma }, \quad \tilde{e} = \frac{4c(\alpha \sigma -1) + \beta [(3c\phi +2h) \sigma -4 ]}{3 \beta c \sigma ^2}. \end{aligned}$$
(A26)

Observe that

$$\begin{aligned} p^{*} - \tilde{p} = \frac{\beta +c+(3ch + \beta h -\alpha c) \sigma }{(3 \beta +c)\sigma }, \quad e^{*} - \tilde{e} = - \frac{2[\beta +c+(3ch + \beta h-\alpha c) \sigma ]}{3 \beta c \sigma ^2}. \end{aligned}$$
(A27)

From (A27) we infer

$$\begin{aligned} p^{*} \,\gtreqless \,\tilde{p} \quad\iff & \quad \sigma\, \lesseqgtr \, \frac{\beta +c}{\alpha c-(\beta +3c)h} =: \bar{\sigma }, \\ e^{*} \, \gtreqless \, \tilde{e} \quad\iff & \quad \sigma \, \gtreqless \, \bar{\sigma }. \end{aligned}$$
(A28)

Next, we prove \(\sigma < \bar{\sigma }\). From \(\phi - \sigma e \ge 0\) and \(\tilde{e}=\frac{4c(\alpha \sigma -1) + \beta [(3c\phi +2h) \sigma -4 ]}{3 \beta c \sigma ^2}\) follows \(\sigma \le \frac{2(\beta +c)}{2 \alpha c +\beta h}\). Due toFootnote 32\(\frac{2(\beta +c)}{2 \alpha c + \beta h } < \frac{\beta +c}{\alpha c - ( \beta +3c)h} = \bar{\sigma }\) we get \(\sigma \le \bar{\sigma }\). Hence, in view of (A28) we conclude

$$\begin{aligned} p^{*} > \tilde{p}, \quad e^{*} < \tilde{e}. \end{aligned}$$
(A29)

From \(y_M=y_N=\frac{\alpha -p}{\beta }\) and \(x_M=\frac{p-h}{c}\) we infer

$$\begin{aligned} y_M^{*}=y_N^{*} < \tilde{y}_M=\tilde{y}_N, \quad x_M^{*} > \tilde{x}_M. \end{aligned}$$
(A30)

From \(x_N= y_M+y_N-x_M\) we get

$$\begin{aligned} x_N^{*} < \tilde{x}_N. \end{aligned}$$
(A31)

The marginal effects in (25b) have the signs

$$\begin{aligned} (p -C_N') \frac{\partial \underline{\xi }}{\partial e}&= \frac{(\beta +2c) \sigma h}{2(\beta +c)} >0, \end{aligned}$$
(A32)
$$\begin{aligned} - (y_N - \underline{\xi } ) \frac{\partial \hat{P}}{\partial e}&= \underbrace{(y_N - \underline{\xi } )}_{+} \frac{\beta c \sigma }{2(\beta +c)}>0, \end{aligned}$$
(A33)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \theta }{\partial e}&= 0. \end{aligned}$$
(A34)

Misreporting (GameG). For the parametric functions the coalition’s first-order condition (28) turns into

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}} U_M}{{\mathrm {d}} g}&= \left[ (g-1) \frac{\partial \hat{X}_M}{\partial g} - \frac{\partial \underline{\xi }}{\partial g} \right] H' - (y_M - x_M) \frac{\partial \hat{P}}{\partial g} - \frac{\partial \theta }{\partial g} \\&= \frac{(2-g) h^2}{\beta +c } - \left( \frac{\alpha - p}{\beta } -\frac{p-gh}{c} \right) \frac{\beta h}{\beta +c} -\frac{(1+\mu ) g h^2}{c} =0. \end{aligned}$$
(A35)

Solving \(p = \hat{P}(e ,g)\) from (A16) and (A35) with respect to p and g we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{g}&= \frac{[4h + \beta (\phi -\sigma e) ]c}{2 [(1+ \mu ) \beta +(2+\mu ) c] h}, \end{aligned}$$
(A36)
$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{p}&= \frac{[(2+\mu ) (\phi - \sigma e) \beta (\beta +c)+ (2+ \mu ) 2 c \sigma + \beta (4 h+ 2(2+\mu ) \alpha )]c}{ 2 [(1+ \mu ) \beta +(2+\mu ) c] (\beta +c) \sigma }. \end{aligned}$$
(A37)

It can be shown that

$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{g} =1 \quad \iff \quad \mu = \frac{[(\phi - \sigma e) c - 2 h] \beta }{2 (\beta + c) h} =: \bar{\mu } \left( e, \beta , c, h, \sigma \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(A38)

In the sequel we focus on the displacement effects of g and therefore set \(e=e^{*}\) to avoid distortions stemming from two different sources, from the inefficiency of g and e. For \(\mu =\bar{\mu } \left( e^{*}, \beta , c, h, \sigma \right) \) follows \(\tilde{p} = p^{*}\).

Next, straightforward differentiation leads to

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \tilde{g}}{\partial \mu }&= - \frac{(\beta +c) c [4 h +(\phi - \sigma e^{*}) b]}{ 2[(1+ \mu ) \beta +(2+\mu ) c]^2 h \sigma } <0, \end{aligned}$$
(A39)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \tilde{p}}{\partial \mu }&= - \frac{\beta c [4 h +(\phi - \sigma e^{*}) b]}{2 [(1+ \mu ) \beta +(2+\mu ) c]^2 \sigma } <0. \end{aligned}$$
(A40)

Taking advantage of (A39) and (A40) in (A38) we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{g} \, \gtreqless \, 1 \quad \iff \quad \tilde{p} \, \gtreqless \, p^{*} \quad \iff \quad \mu \lesseqgtr \bar{\mu } \left( e^{*}, \beta , c, h, \sigma \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(A41)

From \(y_M = y_N = \frac{\alpha -p}{b}\) we get

$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{y}_M = \tilde{y}_N \lesseqgtr y_M^{*}=y_N^{*} \quad \iff \quad \mu \lesseqgtr \bar{\mu } \left( e^{*}, \beta , c, h, \sigma \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(A42)

Differentiating \(x_M\) and \(x_N\) from (A12) with respect to \(\mu \) yields

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial x_M}{\partial \mu } = \frac{\partial x_N}{\partial \mu } = \frac{1}{c} \left[ \frac{\partial \tilde{p}}{\partial \mu } - h \frac{\partial \tilde{g}}{\partial \mu } \right] = \frac{[(\phi - \sigma e^{*}) b + 4h]}{2 [(1+ \mu ) \beta +(2+\mu )c]^2 } >0 \end{aligned}$$
(A43)

and hence we get

$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{x}_M \lesseqgtr x_M^{*} \quad \iff \quad \tilde{x}_N \lesseqgtr x_N^{*} \quad \iff \quad \mu \lesseqgtr \bar{\mu } \left( e^{*}, \beta , c, h, \sigma \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(A44)

The marginal effects in (28) have the signs

$$\begin{aligned} \left[ (g-1) \frac{\partial \hat{X}_M}{\partial g} - \frac{\partial \underline{\xi }}{\partial g} \right] H' &= \frac{(2- \tilde{g}) h}{\beta +c } >0, \end{aligned}$$
(A45)
$$\begin{aligned} - (y_M- x_M) \frac{\partial \hat{P}}{\partial g}&= -\underbrace{(y_M-x_M)}_{-} \frac{\beta h}{\beta +c} = \left( \frac{\phi - \sigma e^{*}}{2} \right) \frac{\beta h}{\beta +c} >0, \end{aligned}$$
(A46)
$$\begin{aligned} - \frac{\partial \theta }{\partial g}&= \frac{(1+\mu ) \tilde{g}h^2}{c} <0. \end{aligned}$$
(A47)

Finally, the function \(\bar{\mu } \left( e^{*}, \beta , c, h, \sigma \right) \) has the properties

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{\mu }_{\beta }&= \frac{[(\phi - \sigma e^{*}) c - 2 h] c}{ 2 (\beta +c)^2 h}, \end{aligned}$$
(A48)
$$\begin{aligned} \bar{\mu }_{c}&= \frac{[(\phi - \sigma e^{*}) c + 2 h] c}{ 2 (\beta +c)^2 h} >0, \end{aligned}$$
(A49)
$$\begin{aligned} \bar{\mu }_{h}&= -\frac{(\phi - \sigma e^{*}) \beta c}{ 2 (\beta +c)^2 h}<0, \end{aligned}$$
(A50)
$$\begin{aligned} \bar{\mu }_{\sigma }&= - \frac{\beta c e^{*}}{ 2(\beta +c) h}<0. \end{aligned}$$
(A51)

Exploration and misreporting (GameEG).

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}} U_N}{{\mathrm {d}} e}&= \underbrace{(p-C'_N)}_{=g h} \frac{\partial \underline{\xi }}{\partial e} - (y_N - \underline{\xi } ) \frac{\partial \hat{P}}{\partial e} + \frac{\partial \theta }{\partial e} - \frac{\partial C_N (\underline{\xi }, e)}{\partial e} - 1 \\&= \frac{(\beta +2c) \sigma g h}{2(\beta +c)} - \left[ \frac{\alpha -p}{\beta } - \frac{p-h}{c} + (\phi - \sigma e) \right] \left( \frac{\beta c \sigma }{2(\beta +c)} \right) \\&\quad + (p-gh) \sigma - 1 =0, \end{aligned}$$
(A52)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}} U_M}{{\mathrm {d}} g}&= \left[ (g-1) \frac{\partial \hat{X}_M}{\partial g} - \frac{\partial \underline{\xi }}{\partial g} \right] H' - (y_M - x_M) \frac{\partial \hat{P}}{\partial g} - \frac{\partial \theta }{\partial g} \\&= \frac{(2-g) h^2}{\beta +c } - \left( \frac{\alpha - p}{\beta } -\frac{p-gh}{c} \right) \frac{\beta h}{\beta +c} -\frac{(1+\mu ) g h^2}{c} =0. \end{aligned}$$
(A53)

Solving (A52), (A53) and \(p=\hat{P}(e,g)\) with respect to e, g and p yields

$$\begin{aligned} \breve{g}&= \frac{\beta (2h-\sigma ) - 2c(\alpha \sigma -3h\sigma -1)}{3[(1+\mu ) \beta +(2+\mu ) c] h\sigma }, \end{aligned}$$
(A54)
$$\begin{aligned} \breve{e}&= \frac{4c(\alpha \sigma -1) +\beta [(3c\phi +2h) \sigma -4]}{3 \beta c \sigma ^2}, \end{aligned}$$
(A55)
$$\begin{aligned} \breve{p}&= \hat{P}(\breve{e}, \breve{g}) \\&= \frac{\beta ^2(2-h\sigma ) (2+\mu ) +c^2(2+\alpha \sigma ) (2+\mu ) +\beta c[h \sigma (4-\mu ) -\alpha \sigma (1-\mu ) +4(2+\mu )] }{3 (\beta + c) \sigma [(1+\mu ) \beta +(2+\mu ) c]}. \end{aligned}$$
(A56)

Comparing (A54) and (A55) with the efficient allocation yields

$$\begin{aligned} \breve{g} \, \gtreqless \, 1 \quad\iff & \quad \mu \, \gtreqless \, \frac{2[\beta +c -(2\beta h+\alpha c) \sigma ]}{3(\beta +c) h \sigma }=: \breve{\mu } (\beta , c, h, \sigma ), \end{aligned}$$
(A57)
$$\begin{aligned} \breve{e} \, \gtreqless \, e^{*} \quad\iff & \quad \sigma \, \gtreqless \, \frac{\beta +c}{\alpha c -(\beta +3c) h } \equiv \bar{\sigma }. \end{aligned}$$
(A58)

Since (A58) is equivalent to (A28) we get \(\sigma < \bar{\sigma }\) and hence \(\breve{e} > e^{*}\).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Eichner, T., Pethig, R. Supply-Side Climate Policy: On the Role of Exploration and Asymmetric Information. Environ Resource Econ 74, 397–420 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-019-00323-0

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-019-00323-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation