Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Measuring the Impact of Water Supply Interruptions on Household Welfare

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Water scarcity frequently leads to a need for rationing. The choice of an adequate rationing method should be based on the impact on consumer welfare that is produced by each rationing plan. Some rationing schemes, such as the frequently used supply interruption method, can be regarded as changes in the characteristics of the good (in this case, time availability) that do not modify the pre-set consumer budget. Under the standard theoretical restrictions on consumer behavior compensating or equivalent variations/surpluses cannot be used to identify the impacts of these methods on household welfare. In this paper, we propose a set of sufficient conditions with respect to the utility function that allows for the evaluation of the compensating or equivalent variations/surpluses associated with changes in goods’ quality, even if those goods are considered to be essential for consumers. We use these conditions to compare the welfare losses associated with the water supply cuts implemented in Seville (Spain) to those that would result if water was instead rationed using price changes.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The United Nations (2011) projects the current world population of nearly 7 billion to grow to 9.3 billion by the middle of this century and to 10.1 billion within the next 90 years.

  2. Baisa et al. (2010) analyzes the consequences of extremely severe water shortages in Mexico.

  3. Many cities and towns in both developed and developing countries suffer from water supply interruptions and discontinuous water-related services (OECD 2003, 2008).

  4. Compensating or equivalent surpluses are welfare losses measures due to changes in quantity-constrained goods Freeman et al. (2014).

  5. In particular, in the case of Seville households are recommended to reduce water consumption, but no other rationing measure is implemented. Therefore, households are allowed to maintain their previous consumption if they wish. As a result, any reduction in water consumption will be due to changes in the household’s utility function generated by the reduced availability of the good.

  6. Bockstael and McConnell (1993) show that consumer surplus could be considered as an approximation to compensated and equivalent variations if, additionally to non-essentiality and weak complementarity, the so-called “Willig condition” holds (Willig 1978).

  7. In Roibas et al (2007) a dual approach is used to demonstrate the impossibility of identifying compensated or equivalent surpluses associated to supply cuts under the standard theoretical restrictions. However, no restrictions allowing their identification are typified.

  8. See Arbues et al. (2003), Worthington and Hoffman (2008) or Reynaud (2015) for broader surveys on residential water demand.

  9. The expenditure function dual to the Stone-Geary utility function can be expressed in an analytic form and this is an important advantage in this study as it avoids the use of numerical methods to calculate the compensating surplus which, additionally, allow for their standard deviations to be calculated.

  10. There was another drought at the beginning of the XXI century, but no supply restrictions were implemented in Seville to address this drought (EMASESA 2005).

  11. Although supply cuts are legally permitted under certain circumstances, regulations require users to be notified in advance regarding the initiation, intensity and estimated duration of these cuts (Molina 2001). It should be noted that supply cuts also forbid the use of water stored in storage devices.

  12. These restrictions were not applied to users that provided services that were deemed to be essential to the public interest, such as health centers.

  13. It is worth noting that most people in Spanish cities reside in apartment blocks and not in single-family houses. In particular, all the households in the sample reside in apartment blocks and residential water uses such as car washing or garden irrigation are not taking place in our sample.

  14. It is worth noting that the whole sample period is prior to the Directive 2000/60/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 23 October 2000 (Water Framework Directive, WFD) that requires complying with the full-cost recovery principle. During the period analyzed in this research, household expenditures were lower than the cost of water provision and water provision was consequently a subsidized activity. Even several years later, WDF has not been yet fully applied in Spain (European Environment Agency 2013).

  15. Seville city council classified streets into 8 categories.

  16. Olmstead (2009) shows that instrumental variables could be a valid technique in this case.

  17. See Greene (2008) for details on the non-linear least squares estimator.

  18. As aforementioned, water provision was a subsidized activity and therefore the lower the households’ expenditure the larger the subsidy (and consequently, the larger the taxation) necessary to cover the difference between revenues and costs.

  19. Note that these results should be interpreted with caution, since the income used in the empirical exercise is an approximation that could be far from the real households’ income.

  20. For a broader discussion on affordability issues on water residential sector, check García-Valiñas et al. (2010).

  21. Unfortunately, no information about these costs was provided by the public utility.

  22. In 1991, 197967 households were registered in Seville. Further information about the number of households living in the municipality is available at http://www.ine.es.

References

  • Al-Qunaibet MH, Johnston RS (1985) Municipal demand for water in Kuwait: methodological issues and empirical results. Water Resour Res 2(4):433–438

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arbues F, Garcia-Valiñas MA, Martínez-Espiñeira R (2003) Estimation of residential water demand: a state-of-the-art review. J Socio Econ 32:81–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baisa B, Davis LW, Salant SW, Wilcox W (2010) The welfare costs of unreliable water service. J Dev Econ 92:1–12

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bates BC, Kundzewicz ZW, Wu S, Palutikof JP (eds) (2008) Climate change and water. Technical Paper of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. IPCC Secretariat, Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  • Bockstael NE, McConnell KE (1993) Public goods as characteristics of non-market commodities. Econ J 103:1244-12

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caixa La (2000) Anuario comercial Español. Servicio de Estudios de La Caixa, Barcelona

    Google Scholar 

  • Chung JW (1994) Utility and production functions. Blackwell, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarke AJ, Colby BG, Thompson GD (2017) Household water demand seasonal elasticities: a stone-geary model under an increasing block rate structure. Land Econ 93(4):608–630

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton A, Muellbauer J (1980) Economics and consumer behaviour. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dharmaratna D, Harris E (2012) Estimating residential water demand using the Stone-Geary functional form: the case of Sri Lanka. Water Resour Manage 26(8):2283–2299

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • EMASESA (1997) Crónica de una Sequía: 1992–1995. EMASESA, Sevilla

    Google Scholar 

  • EMASESA (2005) Así Éramos, Así Somos, 1975–2005. EMASESA, Sevilla

    Google Scholar 

  • European Environment Agency (2009). Water resources across Europe. Confronting water scarcity and drought. European Environment Agency, technical report 2/2009. Luxembourg

  • European Environment Agency (2013). Assessment of cost recovery through water pricing. European Environment Agency, technical report 16/2013, Luxembourg

  • Freeman AM, Herriges JA, Kling CL (2014) The measurement of environmental and resource values, 3rd edn. RFF Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Garcia-Valiñas MA (2006) Analysing rationing policies: drought and its effects on urban users’ welfare. Appl Econ 38(8):955–965

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garcia-Valiñas MA, Martínez-Espiñeira R, González-Gómez FJ (2010) Affordability of residential water tariffs: alternative measurement and explanatory factors in southern Spain. J Environ Manage 91(12):2696–2706

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garcia-Valiñas MA, Martínez-Espiñeira R, To H (2015) The use of non-pricing instruments to manage residential water demand: What have we learnt? In: Grafton Q, Daniell KA, Nauges C, Rinaudo J-D (eds) Understanding and managing urban water in transition. Springer, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaudin S, Griffin RC, Sickles RC (2001) Demand specification for municipal water management: evaluation of the Stone-Geary form. Land Econ 77(3):399–422

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Genius M, Hatzaki E, Kouromichelaki EM, Kouvakis G, Nikiforaki S, Tsagarakis KP (2008) Evaluating consumer’s willingness to pay for improved potable water quality and quantity. Water Resour Manage 22:1825–1834

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grafton QP, Ward MB (2008) Prices versus rationing: Marshallian surplus and mandatory water restrictions. Econ Rec 84:S57–S65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (2008) Econometric analysis. Prentice Hall, New Jersey

    Google Scholar 

  • Hensher D, Shore N, Train K (2005) Households’ willingness to pay for water service attributes. Environ Resour Econ 32(4):509–531

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • INE (2011) Cifras de Población Referidas al 1/1/11. Población de Municipios por Sexo. Instituto Nacional de Estadística, Madrid

    Google Scholar 

  • IPCC (2013) Climate change 2013: the physical science basis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Madhoo YN (2009) Policy and nonpolicy determinants of progressivity of block residential water rates: a case study of Mauritius. Appl Econ Lett 16(2):211–215

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mäler KG (1971) A method of estimating social benefits from pollution control. Swed J Econ 73(1):121–133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansur ET, Olmstead SM (2012) The value of scarce water: measuring the inefficiency of municipal regulations. J Urban Econ 71(3):332–346

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martínez-Espiñeira R, Nauges C (2004) Is really all domestic water consumption sensitive to price control? An empirical analysis. Appl Econ 36(9):1697–1703

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McDonald DH, Morrison MD, Barnes MB (2010) Willingness to pay and willingness to accept compensation for changes in urban water customer standards. Water Resour Manage 24:3145–3158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meran G, von Hirschhausen C (2009) Increasing block tariffs in the water sector: a semi-welfarist approach. D.WI Berlin discussion papers 902, June 2009. http://www.diw.de/documents/publikationen/73/diw_01.c.99475.de/dp902.pdf

  • Molina A (2001) El Servicio Público de Abastecimiento de Agua en Poblaciones. El Contexto Liberalizador. Tirant lo Blanch, Valencia

    Google Scholar 

  • Moncur J (1987) Urban water pricing and drought management. Water Resour Res 23:393–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monteiro H (2010) Residential water demand in Portugal: checking for efficiency-based justifications for increasing block tariffs. Working Papers ercwp0110, ISCTE, UNIDE, Economics Research Centre

  • Nauges C, Garcia-Valiñas M, Reynaud A (2009) How much water do residential users really need? An estimation of minimum water requirements for French households. In: Paper presented at the XVII annual conference of the European association of environmental and resource economists, Amsterdam

  • OECD (2003) Improving water management: recent OECD experience. OECD, Paris

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2008) Household behaviour and the environment. Reviewing the evidence. OECD, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Olmstead SM (2009) Reduced-form versus structural models of water demand under nonlinear prices. J Bus Econ Stat 27(1):84–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olmstead SM, Stavins RN (2009) Comparing price and non-price approaches to urban water conservation. Water Resour Res 45:W04301

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olmstead SM, Hanemann WM, Stavins RN (2007) Water demand under alternative price structures. J Environ Econ Manag 54(2):181–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phaneuf DJ, Kling CL, Herriges JA (2000) Estimation and welfare calculations in a generalized corner solution model with an application to recreation demand. Rev Econ Stat 82(1):83–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Renwick ME, Archibald SO (1998) Demand side management policies for residential water use: Who bears the conservation burden? Land Econ 74:343–359

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Renzetti S, Brandes O, Dupont DP, Stinchombe K (2015) Using demand elasticity as an alternative approach to modelling future community water demand under a conservation-oriented pricing system: an exploratory investigation. Can Water Resour J 40(1):62–70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reynaud A (2015) Modelling household water demand in Europe. Insights from a cross-country econometric analysis of EU 28 countries. JRC report, European Commission, Joint Research Centre Institute for Environment and Sustainability

  • Roibas D, Garcia-Valiñas MA, Wall A (2007) Measuring welfare losses from interruption and pricing as responses to water shortages: an application to the case of Seville. Environ Resour Econ 38(2):213–229

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosen S (1974) Hedonic prices and implicit markets: product differentiation in pure competition. J Polit Econ 82(1):34–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schleich J (2009) How long can you go? Price responsiveness of German residential water demand. In: Paper presented at the XVII annual conference of the European association of environmental and resource economists, Amsterdam

  • United Nations (2011) World population prospects. The 2010 revision. Highlights. Population Division of the Department of Economic and Social Affairs of the United

  • Vasquez WF, Moxumbder P, Hérandez-Arce J, Berrerns RP (2009) Willingness to pay for safe drinking water: evidence from Parral, Mexico. J Environ Manage 90:3391–3400

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Haefen RH (2008) Latent consideration sets and continuous demand systems. Environ Resource Econ 41:363–379

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Haefen RH, Phaneuf DJ (2003) Estimating preferences for outdoor recreation: a comparison of continuous and count data demand system frameworks. J Environ Econ Manag 45:612–630

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Willig RD (1978) Incremental consumer’s surplus and hedonic price adjustment. J Econ Theory 17(2):227–253

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winpenny J (1994) Managing water as an economic resource. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Worthington AC, Hoffman M (2008) An empirical survey of residential water demand modeling. J Econ Surv 22(5):842–871

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Maria A. Garcia-Valiñas.

Additional information

We would like to thank the financial support of the Spanish Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness and the European Regional Development Fund (through the projects with reference ECO2012-32189 and ECO2016-75237-R).

Appendices

Appendix A

Given a monotonic twice differentiable transformation f, the function \( f\left( U \right) \) only verifies P2\( \left( {\frac{{\delta^{2} f\left( U \right)}}{{\delta x_{2} \delta c}} = 0} \right) \) if f is an affine transformation. The marginal utility of x2 becomes:

$$ \frac{\delta f\left( U \right)}{{\delta x_{2} }} = \frac{\delta f\left( U \right)}{\delta U}\left( {\frac{\delta U}{{\delta U^{0} }}\frac{{\delta U^{0} }}{{\delta x_{2} }} + \frac{\delta U}{{\delta U^{1} }}\frac{{\delta U^{1} }}{{\delta x_{2} }}} \right) $$
(A1)

which, taking into account that \( \frac{{\delta U^{0} }}{{\delta x_{2} }} = 0 \) and \( \frac{\delta U}{{\delta U^{1} }} = 1 \) becomes:

$$ \frac{\delta f\left( U \right)}{{\delta x_{2} }} = \frac{\delta f\left( U \right)}{\delta U}\frac{{\delta U^{1} }}{{\delta x_{2} }} $$
(A2)

and, therefore:

$$ \frac{{\delta^{2} f\left( U \right)}}{{\delta x_{2} \delta c}} = \frac{{\delta^{2} f\left( U \right)}}{{\delta U^{2} }}\frac{\delta U}{\delta c}\frac{{\delta U^{1} }}{{\delta x_{2} }} + \frac{\delta f\left( U \right)}{\delta U}\frac{{\delta^{2} U^{1} }}{{\delta x_{2} \delta c}} $$
(A3)

Taking into account that \( \frac{{\delta^{2} U^{1} }}{{\delta x_{2} \delta c}} = 0 \), P2 is verified only if \( \frac{{\delta^{2} f\left( U \right)}}{{\delta U^{2} }} = 0 \) which implies that f is an affine transformation.

Appendix B

Table 8 Residential water demand functions based on a Stone-Geary utility function

Appendix C

Table 9 Fixed fee (€)
Table 10 Block dimension and price

Appendix D

The baseline linear demand model estimated is the following:

$$ \begin{aligned} x_{1} & = b_{1} + b_{NPER} NPER_{i} + b_{TEMP} TEMP_{t} + b_{RAIN} RAIN_{t} + b_{QUAL} QUAL_{t} + \mathop \sum \limits_{T = 1992}^{2000} b_{T} D_{T} \\ & \quad + b_{R} R + b_{c} c + b_{p} p \\ \end{aligned} $$
(D1)

Tables 11 and 12 show the main results of the estimation/simulation based on the previous linear demand function and the consumer surplus as a welfare method.

Table 11 Baseline linear demand model estimationa
Table 12 Consumer surplus (€) under alternative rationing schemes: baseline model

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Roibas, D., Garcia-Valiñas, M.A. & Fernandez-Llera, R. Measuring the Impact of Water Supply Interruptions on Household Welfare. Environ Resource Econ 73, 159–179 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-018-0255-7

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-018-0255-7

Keywords

Navigation