Skip to main content
Log in

Policy Change Anticipation in the Buyback Context

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

To what degree might an anticipated policy change delay the fleet restructuring process initiated by a vessel buyback? This paper addresses the issue by estimating a restricted profit function to analyze an overcapitalized fishing fleet subject to restrictive regulation on the harvest of its primary target species. Fishermen’s expectations and likely responses to the future regulations regarding individual quotas are modeled in the context of a time-limited buyback program. The Polish trawler fleet targeting primarily cod provides an application. Analyzing potential individual quota tradability, we find that considerable shifts in disinvestment are to be found due to anticipated policy change. The mechanisms driving discrepancies include capitalized value of quota, as well as the tradability option capitalized into other inputs with inelastic supply.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Abel et al. (1996) state that “opportunities for future expansion or contraction [of capital] can be valued as options.”

  2. For profits conditional on owned capital \(z_k\) and quota \(q_i\), the shadow price, as noted earlier, is \(w_k^*=\partial \pi ^r(\mathbf {P^{-i}};q_i,z_k)/\partial z_k\). When \(w_k^*=w_k\), the firm’s profit function constrained by \(z_k\) and \(q_i\) (Eq. 4) is indistinguishable from the firm’s profit function unconstrained by all netputs but \(q_i\).

  3. The sunk cost is defined following Vestergaard et al. (2005) as \(s-S\), where s denotes the purchase price, S denotes the salvage value, and where \(s\ge S\ge 0\). This specification is reasonable in a fishery with excess capacity and over-capitalization with few or no opportunities to enter into other fisheries—precisely the conditions under which buybacks are implemented.

  4. The price \(w_k\) includes all non-variable, effort-level independent fixed costs conditional on positive utilization of capital (that is, \(w_k=0\) if vessel exits), such as annual insurance payments (that may be zero or below insured market value), dockage fees, license fees, etc. Note that \(w_k\) excludes capital interest as it has to be paid regardless of the exit decision. Therefore, it is irrelevant for our comparison with buyback payment.

  5. Note that the exit decision includes not just the decision to disinvest the physical capital stock, but also includes the decision to disinvest the quota holdings (Weninger and Just 1997; Vestergaard et al. 2005).

  6. The profit function is specified with a quadratic functional form as a second-order Taylor’s series approximation around the unit price vector in base period. All prices are scaled such that their mean in 2008 is one.

  7. The weights are obtained using method presented by Diewert and Wales (1992): \(\theta _i=|x_i|p_i^0/\sum _{i\in I}|x_i|p_i^0\), where \(p_i^0\) is average price of netput i in the base period.

  8. The entry-exit regime in EU is based on Article 13 of Council Regulation 2371/2002 and Articles 6 and 7 of Commission Regulation 1438/2003.

  9. Medium-term perspective is more than a single season, but not the infinite time horizon. For the present consideration, this could be thought as one-owner decision perspective.

  10. Revenue shares based on average 2008–2010 data from STECF (2012).

  11. On average approximately 7% of the cod catch over the period 2008–2010.

  12. FMC in Gdynia is a branch of the Fisheries Department within the Ministry of Agriculture and Rural Development in Warsaw. The individual vessel data is confidential and cannot be shared by authors without further aggregation.

  13. Landings of salmon, sea trout and rainbow trout are reported in a number of individuals. These values are converted to weight according to the mean weight per individual in the Polish harvest.

  14. OTB, PTB, OTM and PTM in accordance to abbreviations provided by the International Standard Statistical Classification of Fishing Gear (FAO 1997).

  15. The fleet structure in terms of size, age and main gear is available from European Commission Fleet Register: http://ec.europa.eu/fisheries/fleet/.

  16. Trawlers conduct an active type of fishing requiring constant movement in order to chase the targeted fish. Thus, costs are closely correlated to time at the sea. In contrast, passive gear is set in the water for certain time period and time at the sea do not necessarily reflect the variable cost. This unit of effort is also one of the indicators used by the Baltic Fisheries Assessment Working Group in ICES reports (ICES 2014).

  17. Individual vessels’ reports are confidential, cannot be directly combined with log book data, and are obtained through personal communication with Emil Kuzebski.

  18. The correlation coefficients based on available data were as follows: fuel cost and labor cost: 0.79, fuel cost and other costs: 0.72, labor cost and other costs: 0.67.

  19. Considering 2025, it would be 30% of the fleet; for 2030, 15% of the fleet.

  20. Note that model assumes current strict entry regime. Thus, the resultant fleet composition is based on the exactly the same subset of the Polish fleet, i.e. trawlers over 10 m with cod harvest permits, and presents the fleet in terms of the same vessels that would remain in the fishery under each analyzed scenario.

  21. We assume no transaction and information costs in the ITQ scenario that hamper the trade.

  22. We verified that optimal harvest derived in ITQ scenario does not imply unrealistic effort. This is done by calculating a sum of input demand equations outputs, i.e. time at sea using demersal and pelagic gear, following Eq. 8.

  23. Although the analysis was conducted within a partial equilibrium framework, use of shadow prices often accounts for secondary impacts.

References

  • Abel A, Dixit A, Eberly J, Pindyck R (1996) Options, the value of capital, and investment. Q J Econ 111(3):753–777

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson J (1988) The relative inefficiency of quotas. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Aps R, Lassen H (2009) Rebuilding depleted baltic fish stocks lessons learned. University of Tartu, Rostock

    Google Scholar 

  • Asche F (2001) Fishermens discount rates in ITQ systems. Environ Resour Econ 19:403–410

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asche F, Eggert H, Gudmundsson E, Hoff A, Pascoe S (2008) Fisher’s behaviour with individual vessel quotas—overcapacity and potential rent five case studies. Mar Policy 32:920–927

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bagge O, Thurow F, Steffensenm E, Bay J (1994) The Baltic cod. DANA 10:1–28

    Google Scholar 

  • Berck P, Perloff J (1984) An open access fishery with rational expectations. Econometrica 52(2):489–506

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bockstael N, Opaluch J (1983) Discrete modeling of supply response under uncertainty: the case of the fishery. J Environ Econ Manag 10:125–137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Branch TA, Hilborn R, Haynie AC, Fay G, Flynn L, Griffiths J, Marshall K, Randall J, Scheuerell J, Ward E, Young M (2006) Fleet dynamics and fishermen behavior: lessons for fisheries managers. Can J Fish Aquat Sci 63:1647–1688

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandt S (2003) A tale of two clams: policy anticipation and industry productivity. University of Massachusetts Department of Resource Economics, Amherst

    Google Scholar 

  • Burger J (2004) The policy anticipation hypothesis: evidence from the federal funds futures market. Contemp Econ Policy 22(4):544–554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark C, Munro G, Sumaila U (2005) Subsidies, buybacks, and sustainable fisheries. J Environ Econ Manag 50:47–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark C, Munro G, Sumaila U (2007) Buyback subsidies, the time consistency problem, and the ITQ alternative. Land Econ 83(1):50–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Curtis R, Squires D (2007) Fisheries buybacks. Blackwell, Ames

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Davidson R (2007) Bootstrapping econometric models. McGill University, Montreal

    Google Scholar 

  • Davidson R, MacKinnon J (2007) Wild bootstrap for IV regression. J Bus Econ Stat 28(1):128–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert W (1974) Applications of duality theory. North-Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Diewert W, Wales T (1987) Flexible functional forms and global curvature conditions. Econometrica 55:43–68

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert W, Wales T (1992) Quadratic spline models for producers supply and demand functions. Int Econ Rev 33:705–722

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drazen A, Helpman E (1988) The effect of policy anticipations on stabilization programs. Eur Econ Rev 32:680–686

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dupont D (1990) Rent dissipation in restricted access fisheries. J Environ Econ Manag 19:26–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • FAO (1997) Report of the seventeenth session of the coordinating working party on fishery statistics. Technical report, FAO, Hobart

  • Freedman D (1981) Bootstrapping regression models. Ann Stat 12:827–842

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fulginiti L, Perrin R (1993) The theory and measurement of producer response under quota. Rev Econ Stat 75(1):97–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graff-Zivin J, Mullins J (2015) Vessel buybacks in fisheries: the role of auction and financing structures. Mar Policy 53:188–197

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grainger C, Costello C (2014) Capitalizing property rights insecurity in natural resource assets. J Environ Econ Manag 67(2):224–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henningsen A (2014) Package miceconsnqp. http://micecon.org. Accessed 1 May 2016

  • Holland D, Steiner E, Warlick A (2017) Can vessel buybacks pay off: an evaluation of an industry funded fishing vessel buyback. Mar Policy 82:8–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoydal K (1983) ICES processing in formulating management advice. FAO Fish Rep 289:215–470

    Google Scholar 

  • Hutniczak B (2014) Increasing pressure on unregulated species due to changes in individual vessel quotas: an empirical application to trawler fishing in the Baltic Sea. Mar Resour Econ 29(3):201–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ICES (2014) Report of the Baltic Fisheries Assessment Working Group (WG-BFAS). Technical report, ICES, Copenhagen

  • Jorgensen H, Jensen C (1999) Overcapacity, subsidies and local stability. Center for the Economics and Management of Aquatic Resources, Portsmouth

    Google Scholar 

  • Karnicki Z (2012) Poczatek roku. Wiadomosci rybackie 1–2:1–4

    Google Scholar 

  • Koebel B, Falk M, Laisney F (2003) Imposing and testing curvature conditions on a Box–Cox cost function. J Bus Econ Stat 21(2):319–335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lagerkvist C (2005) Agricultural policy uncertainty and farm level adjustments: the case of direct payments and incentives for farmland investments. Eur Rev Agric Econ 32(1):1–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lau L (1976) A characterization of the normalized restricted profit function. J Econ Theory 12(1):131–163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Libecap G, Anderson T (2009) The allocation and dissipation of resource rents: implications for fishery reform. ICER working paper, vol 13, pp 1–37

  • Lindebo E (2005) Role of subsidies in EU fleet capacity management. Mar Resour Econ 20:445–466

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Livernois J, Ryan D (1989) Testing for non-jointness in oil and gas exploration: a variable profit function approach. Int Econ Rev 30(2):479–504

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morrison C (1985) Primal and dual capacity utilization: an application to productivity measurement in the US. J Bus Econ Stat 3(4):312–324

    Google Scholar 

  • Neary J, Roberts K (1980) The theory of household behavior under rationing. Eur Econ Rev 13:24–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nøstbakken L, Thebaud O, Sørensen L (2011) Investment behaviour and capacity adjustment in fisheries: a survey of the literature. Mar Resour Econ 26:95–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rockmann C, Schneider U, John M, Tol R (2005) Rebuilding the eastern Baltic cod. Research Unit for Sustainability and Global Change, Hamburg

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbarth E (1941) The measurement of changes in real income under income rationing. Rev Econ Stud 8:100–107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salas S, Gaertner D (2004) The behavioural dynamics of fishers: management implications. Fish Fish 5:153–167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Segerson K, Squires D (1990) On the measurement of economic capacity utilization for multi-product industries. J Econom 44:347–361

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Squires D (1987) Public regulation and the structure of production in multiproduct industries: an application to the New England Otter Trawl Industry. RAND J Econ 18(2):232–247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Squires D (1988) Production technology, costs, and multiproduct industry structure: an application of the long-run profit function to the New England Fishing Industry. Can J Econ 21(2):359–378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Squires D, Kirkley J (1996) Individual transferable quotas in a multiproduct common property industry. Can J Econ 29(2):318–342

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • STECF (2012) The 2012 annual economic report on the EU fishing fleet. Technical report, STECF, Copenhagen

  • Vestergaard N (1999) Welfare measurement in multiproduct industries: the case of multispecies individual quota fisheries. Can J Econ 32(2):729–743

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vestergaard N, Squires D, Kirkley J (2003) Measuring capacity and capacity utilization in fisheries: the case of the Danish Gill-net fleet. Fish Res 60:357–368

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vestergaard N, Jensen F, Jø rgensen H (2005) Sunk cost and entry–exit decisions under individual transferable quotas: when industry restructuring is delayed. Land Econ 81(3):363–378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weninger Q, Just R (1997) An analysis of transition from limited entry to transferable quota: non-Marshallian principles for fisheries management. Nat Resour Model 10(1):53–81

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilen J, Smith M, Lockwood D, Botsford L (2001) Avoiding surprises: incorporating fisherman behavior into management models. Bull Mar Sci 70(2):553–575

    Google Scholar 

  • Wossink A, Gardebroek C (2006) Environmental policy uncertainty and marketable permit systems: the Dutch phosphate quota program. Am J Agric Econ 88(1):16–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu C (1986) Jackknife, bootstrap and other resampling methods in regression analysis. Ann Stat 14:1261–1295

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Barbara Hutniczak.

Appendices

Appendix A Separability

Homothetic separability between all inputs and all outputs in the short run, conditional upon fixed netputs, implies a transformation of the form:

$$\begin{aligned} f(\mathbf {X_{out};Z_{out}})-g(\mathbf {X_{in};Z_{in}})=0, \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

where \(f(\cdot )\) and \(g(\cdot )\) are linearly homogeneous aggregator functions that provide a consistent composite output and input indices respectively. Input–output separability implies no specific interactions between outputs, whether quota-regulated or variable, and inputs, whether variable or quasi-fixed, implying that it is possible to specify one composite output and one composite input. This is of particular interest in the case of fisheries, where it is common to aggregate harvest to a composite output or use total effort as a composite input. Homothetic input–output separability implies that the composition of variable and quota-regulated outputs within a restricted profit function framework is independent of input prices and fixed inputs, and the relationship between the quota-regulated and unregulated species depends upon the functional form of the linearly homogeneous aggregator function for the composite output. This condition can be written as: (1) \(\partial \left( \frac{\partial \varPi ({\mathbf {P}},{\mathbf {W}};{\mathbf {Z}})/ \partial p_i}{\partial \varPi ({\mathbf {P}},{\mathbf {W}};{\mathbf {Z}})/ \partial p_{i'}}\right) /\partial p_{i''}=0\); \(i\ne i'\) for every \(i,i'\in I_{out}\) and \(i''\in I_{in}\), (2) \(\partial \left( \frac{\varPi ({\mathbf {P}},{\mathbf {W}};{\mathbf {Z}})/ \partial p_i}{z_j} \right) /\partial p_{i'}=0\) for every \(i\in I_{out},j\in J_{out}\) and \(i'\in I_{in}\), (3) \(\partial \left( \frac{\partial \varPi ({\mathbf {P}}, {\mathbf {W}}; {\mathbf {Z}})/ \partial p_i}{\partial \varPi ({\mathbf {P}},{\mathbf {W}};{\mathbf {Z}})/\partial p_{i'}}\right) /\partial z_j=0; i\ne i'\) for every \(i,i'\in I_{out}\) and \(j\in J_{in}\) and (4) \(\partial \left( \frac{\partial \varPi ({\mathbf {P}}, {\mathbf {W}}; {\mathbf {Z}})/\partial p_i}{z_j}\right) / \partial z_{j'}=0\); for every \(i\in I_{out}, j\in J_{out}\) and \(j'\in J_{in}\).

Appendix B Non-jointness

Input or output non-jointness implies that there are no benefits from combining the production of outputs or using combinations of inputs; the costs of producing outputs or using inputs individually are the same. In this case, the production process can be decomposed into a series of independent processes and the multiproduct or multiinput technology can be expressed as a sum of individual restricted profit functions. In the case of fisheries, a single output profit function implies a separate harvest of each species and there are no economies or diseconomies of scope, whereas a single-input profit function implies the sequential use of different inputs.

The extension of non-jointness of particular interest in this context is almost non-jointness (Livernois and Ryan 1989), in which the production process can be separated into individual processes that depend on the same vector of shared inputs (called public). In this context, elements of \({\mathbf {Z}}\) may be a factor of production that is endogenously selected by the firm in the long run (e.g., the vessel and its equipment in the case of fisheries), a factor of production that is supplied by the government with the properties of a public good or it may incorporate externalities such as crowding in fisheries. In this context, fixed inputs (\(\mathbf {Z_{in}}\)) are taken as elements of the shared inputs vector and the non-joint in inputs total profit function can be written as:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \varPi ({\mathbf {P}},{\mathbf {W}};{\mathbf {Z}})&= {} \sum _{i\in I_{out}}\pi ^{r(i)}(p_i,\mathbf {P_{in}};\mathbf {Z_{in}})\\&\quad + \sum _{j\in J_{out}}\left( w_j z_j+\pi ^{r(j)}(\mathbf {P_{in}};z_j,\mathbf {Z_{in}})\right) +\sum _{j\in J_{in}}w_j z_j. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(B.1)

Here \(\pi ^{r(i)}(p_i,\mathbf {P_{in}};\mathbf {Z_{in}}),i\in I_{out}\), is a single-output restricted profit function, \(w_j z_j+ \pi ^{r(j)}(\mathbf {P_{in}};z_j,\mathbf {Z_{in}})\), \(j\in J_{out}\), is a restricted profit from harvesting restricted output that consist of revenue and restricted profit function indicating the cost of quota harvest. The last expression (\(\sum _{j\in J_{in}}w_j z_j\)) is the cost of fixed inputs added for completeness. \(\mathbf {P_{in}}\) indicates the vector of variable input prices and \(\mathbf {P_{out}}\) the vector of unrestricted output prices. The requirement for non-jointness in inputs is: \(\partial ^2\varPi ({\mathbf {P}},{\mathbf {W}};{\mathbf {Z}})/\partial p_i p_{i'}=0\); \(i\ne i'\) for all \(i,i'\in I_{out}\) and \(\partial ^2 \varPi ({\mathbf {P}},{\mathbf {W}};{\mathbf {Z}})/\partial p_i z_j=0\) for all \(i\in I_{out}\) and \(j\in J_{out}\). Accepting non-jointness in inputs implies that harvest activities associated with any species, both unrestricted and restricted, are independent with the exception of sharing the fixed inputs. The total non-joint in outputs profit function is specified as:

$$\begin{aligned} \varPi ({\mathbf {P}},{\mathbf {W}};{\mathbf {Z}})=\sum _{i\in I_{in}}\pi ^{r(i)}(p_i,\mathbf {P_{out}};{\mathbf {Z}})+\sum _{j\in J}w_j z_j. \end{aligned}$$
(B.2)

Here \(\pi ^{r(i)}(p_i,{{\mathbf {P}}_{out}};{\mathbf {Z}}),i\in I_{in}\), is a single-input restricted profit function. The requirement for non-jointness in outputs is: \(\partial ^2\varPi ({\mathbf {P}}, {\mathbf {W}}; {\mathbf {Z}})/ \partial p_i p_{i'} = 0\); \(i\ne i'\) for all \(i,i'\in I_{in}\). In the case of non-jointness in outputs, there are multiple production functions for each type of variable input, for which the optimal choice depends on fixed factors.

Appendix C Estimation Procedure Details

The model is estimated using a modified micEconSNQP package for R software (Henningsen 2014). The modifications include adding third order terms for non-linear marginal relationships and rewriting the function for the variance-covariance matrix using the wild bootstrap method. The initial run violates the convexity in prices requirement, but convexity can still be imposed, and the model continues to identify elasticities between pairs of netputs. Koebel et al. (2003) describe the procedure. The procedure implies a correction of unrestricted parameters according to: \(\widehat{\alpha ^*}=\hat{\alpha }+\widehat{\varOmega _\alpha }\frac{\partial g'(\hat{\alpha })}{\partial \alpha } \left( \frac{\partial g(\hat{\alpha })}{\partial \alpha '}\widehat{\varOmega _\alpha } \frac{\partial g'(\hat{\alpha })}{\partial \alpha }\right) ^{-1} \left( \eta _H^*-\partial g(\hat{\alpha })\right) \), where \(\hat{\alpha ^*}\) is corrected for the convexity coefficient, \(\hat{\alpha }\) is the original regression coefficient, \(\widehat{\varOmega _\alpha }\) is the original regression variance-covariance matrix, \(g(\widehat{\alpha })\) is vector of linear independent values of the Hessian matrix for average prices and quantities of fixed factors, and \(\eta _H^*-\partial g(\hat{\alpha })\) is difference between the parameters for the convexity restricted and unrestricted Hessians. Because the SNQPF Hessian not only depends on coefficients but also on prices and netput levels, convexity is imposed locally at arithmetic average values or regressors. This procedure is necessary to keep a correct structure for all supply and demand equations, and allow the quota market simulation. Potential reasons include insufficient price variation, multicollinearity and the aggregation method (Squires 1987). In our case, we find aggregation of other species.

Due to optimization involved in the estimation process, the traditional methods for calculating standard errors are not applicable. Instead, the confidence intervals based on empirical distribution are derived applying bootstrap. First, all units are resampled to obtain an intermediate data sample to account for individual unobservable heterogeneity of the unit (Freedman 1981). Then, in order to assure a heteroscedasticity consistent covariance matrix, wild bootstrap (Wu 1986) is applied. The idea of the wild bootstrap is to use the actual residual for each observation, transform it, and multiply it by an IID drawing from a distribution with expectation 0 and variance 1 (Davidson 2007). Here, we use wild efficient residual bootstrap proposed by Davidson and MacKinnon (2007). The transformed residual is derived as: \(u_i^*=\sqrt{(N/(N-K)}u_i v_i\), where \(u_i\) is original residual, N is number of observations, K is number of coefficients, and \(v_i\) is a random variable from Rademacher distribution, according to which: \(v_i= \left\{ {\begin{array}{cc} 1\ \textit{with}\ \textit{probability}\ 0.5\\ -1\ \textit{with}\ \textit{probability}\ 0.5 \\ \end{array}}\right. \). The data generation process takes the form: \(x_{in}^*=\widehat{x_{i,n}}+u_{in}^*\), where \(\widehat{x_{i,n}}\) is the predicted value for netput i from the original input demand or output supply equation, and \(u_{in}^*\) is the residual bootstrap. In case of simultaneous equations model, all residuals for a given observation are multiplied by the same value of \(v_i\) to preserve the correlation between disturbances (Davidson and MacKinnon 2007). The p values calculated for a one-tailed test indicating probability of rejecting the value of opposite sign or zero follow: p value=\(\left\{ {\begin{array}{cc} \frac{1}{R}\sum _{r=1}^R I(\alpha _r\le 0) \ \textit{for}\ \hat{\alpha }>0 \\ \frac{1}{R}\sum _{r=1}^R I(\alpha _r\ge 0)\ for \ \hat{\alpha }>0\end{array}}\right. \), where r is bootstrap sample, R is sum of bootstrap samples calculated, here 999, \(\alpha _r\) is coefficient value for r-th bootstrap sample estimated with the same methods as the original model and \(\hat{\alpha }\) is the original estimate. Consequently, the p values are based on the empirical distribution and there is no need to make any assumption about the population’s distribution.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hutniczak, B., Vestergaard, N. & Squires, D. Policy Change Anticipation in the Buyback Context. Environ Resource Econ 73, 111–132 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-018-0252-x

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-018-0252-x

Keywords

Navigation