Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Substitutability and the Cost of Climate Mitigation Policy

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We explore how and by how much the values of elasticities of substitution affect estimates of the cost of emissions reduction policies in computable general equilibrium (CGE) models. We use G-Cubed, an intertemporal CGE model, to carry out a sensitivity and factor decomposition analysis. The decomposition analysis determines the contributions of changes in average abatement costs and changes in baseline emissions to the change in total mitigation costs. The latter has not previously been considered. Average abatement cost rises non-linearly as elasticities are reduced. Changes in the substitution elasticities between capital, labor, energy, and materials have a greater impact on mitigation costs than do inter-fuel elasticities of substitution. The former have more effect on business as usual emissions and the latter on average abatement costs. As elasticities are reduced, business as usual emissions and GDP growth also decrease so that there is not much variation in the total costs of reaching a given target across the parameter space. Our results confirm that the cost of climate mitigation policy is at most a few percent of global GDP.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. It does seem to be becoming more common to report tests of sensitivity to few key parameters in papers using CGE models (e.g. Dessus and O’Connor 2003; Meng et al. 2013; Schenker 2013; Lanzi and Wing 2013).

  2. The choice of discount rate is discussed in the “Appendix”.

  3. Though we only assess the impact of the policy up to 2030, as agents in G-Cubed are forward looking it is important to model the path of the carbon price after 2030.

  4. As most participating models failed to simulate the EMF22 \(450\hbox {CO}_{2}\)e scenario (comparable to RCP2.6), we compare our default carbon prices with the “Full participation and not-to-exceed” scenarios of \(650\hbox {CO}_{2}\)e (comparable to RCP4.5) and \(550\hbox {CO}_{2}\)e targets (comparable to a path somewhere between RCP2.6 and RCP4.5).

  5. However, in terms of average abatement costs (GDP losses/emissions abated), India ($80 per tonne of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)) has a similar cost to China ($87 per tonne of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\)) in 2030. BAU emissions intensity is higher in China—in 2030 it is 1.29 kg of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) per dollar versus 0.91 kg of \(\hbox {CO}_{2}\) per dollar in India. The latter does increase costs in China. The main difference, however, is from the amount of abated emissions. The cut in emissions in percentage terms as a result of the common carbon tax is much less in India. As a result the loss of GDP is much less in India. There may be various reasons for this difference including differences in industrial structure, which we do not explore further.

  6. There is also a household capital producing sector in a similar nesting; but the elasticity of substitution is not of interest here in this study.

  7. The growth rate of effective labor is the sum of the growth rate of population and the growth rate of technology, which is a steady state assumption. In G-Cubed, the model is computed till far in the future (i.e. 2130) to approximate the steady state, but the reported projection is only till 2100. In our analysis, we only look at the period till 2030.

References

  • Abler DG, Rodriguez AG, Shortle JS (1999) Parameter uncertainty in CGE modeling of the environmental impacts of economic policies. Environ Resour Econ 14:75–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Aghion P, Bursztyn L, Hemous D (2012) The environment and directed technical change. Am Econ Rev 102(1):131–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ang BW (2004) Decomposition analysis for policymaking in energy: which is the preferred method? Energy Policy 32(9):1131–1139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ang BW, Liu FL (2001) A new energy decomposition method: perfect in decomposition and consistent in aggregation. Energy 26(6):537–548

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Babonneau F, Haurie A, Loulou R, Vielle M (2012) Combining stochastic optimization and Monte Carlo simulation to deal with uncertainties in climate policy assessment. Environ Model Assess 17(1–2):51–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beckman J, Hertel T (2009) Why previous estimates of the cost of climate mitigation are likely too low. GTAP Working Papers 2954, Center for Global Trade Analysis, Department of Agricultural Economics, Purdue University

  • Belgodere A, Vellutini C (2011) Identifying key elasticities in a CGE model: a Monte Carlo approach. Appl Econ Lett 18(17):1619–1622

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya SC (1996) Applied general equilibrium models for energy studies. Energy Econ 18:145–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bossetti V, Carraro C, De Cian E, Duval R, Massetti E, Tavoni M (2009) The incentives to participate in and the stability of international climate coalitions: a game-theoretic approach using the WITCH model. OECD Economics Department Working Papers 702, OECD Publishing

  • Boyd O (2012) China’s energy reform and climate policy: the ideas motivating change. CCEP Working Paper 1205

  • Butler MP, Reed PM, Fisher-Vanden K, Keller K, Wagener T (2014) Identifying parametric controls and dependencies in integrated assessment models using global sensitivity analysis. Environ Model Softw 59:10–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvin K, Patel P, Fawcett A, Clarke L, Fisher-Vanden K, Edmonds J, Kim SH, Sands S, Wise M (2009) The distribution and magnitude of emissions mitigation costs in climate stabilization under less than perfect international cooperation: SGM results. Energy Econ 31(Supplement 2):S187–S197

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carraro C, Massetti E (2011) Energy and climate change in China. FEEM Working Paper 16.2011

  • Clarke L, Edmonds J, Krey VC, Richels R, Rose S, Tavoni M (2009) International climate policy architectures: overview of the EMF 22 International Scenarios. Energy Econ 31(Supplement 2):S64–S81

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clements KW (2008) Price elasticities of demand are minus one-half. Econ Lett 99(3):490–493

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de La Grandville O (1989) In quest of the Slutsky diamond. Am Econ Rev 79(3):468–481

    Google Scholar 

  • Dessus S, O’Connor D (2003) Climate policy without tears: CGE-based ancillary benefits estimates for Chile. Environ Resour Econ 25:287–317

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dietz S, Stern N (2008) Why economic analysis supports strong action on climate change: a response to the Stern Review’s critics. Rev Environ Econ Policy 2(1):94–113

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edmonds J, Clarke L, Lurz J, Wise M (2008) Stabilizing CO\(_{2}\) concentrations with incomplete international cooperation. Clim Policy 8:355–376

  • Elliott J, Franklin M, Foster I, Munson T, Loudermilk M (2012) Propagation of data error and parametric sensitivity in computable general equilibrium models. Comput Econ 39:219–241

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2007) World energy technology outlook-2050—WETO-\(H_{2}\)-Update 2007

  • Garnaut R (2008) The Garnaut climate change review: final report. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Goettle RJ, Ho MS, Jorgenson DW, Slesnick DT, Wilcoxen PJ (2007) IGEM, an inter-temporal general equilibrium model of the U.S. economy with emphasis on growth, energy and the environment. Prepared for the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA), Office of Atmospheric Programs, Climate Change Division

  • Gurney A, Ahammad H, Ford M (2009) The economics of greenhouse gas mitigation: insights from illustrative global abatement scenarios modeling. Energy Econ 31(Supplement 2):S174–S186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling H (1931) The economics of exhaustible resources. J Polit Econ 39:137–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hourcade J-C, Pottier A, Espagne E (2011) The environment and directed technical change: comment. Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei Working Papers, Paper 646

  • Houser T, Bradley R, Childs B, Werksman J, Heilmayr R (2008) Leveling the carbon playing field: international competition and US climate policy design. Peterson Institute of International Economics/World Resources Institute, Washington DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Jackson T (2009) Prosperity without growth: economics for a finite planet. Earthscan, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson DW, Goettle RJ, Wilcoxen PJ, Ho MS (2000) The role of substitution in understanding the costs of climate change policy. Report prepared for the Pew Center on Global Climate Change

  • Jacoby HD, Reilly JM, McFarland JR, Paltsev S (2006) Technology and technical change in the MIT EPPA model. Energy Econ 28(5—-6):610–631

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kennedy AB (2013) China’s search for renewable energy: pragmatic techno-nationalism. Asian Surv 53(5):909–930

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koetse MJ, de Groot HLF, Florax RJGM (2008) Capital-energy substitution and shifts in factor demand: a meta-analysis. Energy Econ 30:2236–2251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kriegler E, Petermann N, Krey V, Schwanitz VJ, Luderer G, Ashina S, Bosetti V, Eom J, Kitous A, Méjean A, Paroussos L, Sano F, Turton H, Wilson C, Van Vuuren DP (2015) Diagnostic indicators for integrated assessment models of climate policy. Technol Forecast Soc Change 90A:45–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lanzi E, Wing IS (2013) Capital malleability, emission leakage and the cost of partial climate policies: general equilibrium analysis of the European Union emission trading system. Environ Resour Econ 55:257–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lu Y, Stegman A, Cai Y (2013) Emissions intensity targeting: from China’s 12th five year plan to its Copenhagen commitment. Energy Policy 61:1164–1177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKibbin WJ, Wilcoxen PJ (1999) The theoretical and empirical structure of the G-Cubed model. Econ Model 16:123–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKibbin WJ, Wilcoxen PJ (2013) A Global approach to energy and the environment: the G-Cubed model. In: Dixon PB, Jorgenson DW (eds) Handbook of computable general equilibrium modeling. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 995–1068

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • McKibbin WJ, Ross MT, Shackleton R, Wilcoxen PJ (1999) Emissions trading, capital flows and the Kyoto Protocol. Energy Journal. Special Issue: The Costs of the Kyoto Protocol, pp 287–334

  • McKibbin WJ, Wilcoxen PJ, Woo WT (2008) China can grow and still help prevent the tragedy of the carbon dioxide commons. CAMA Working Paper 14/2008

  • McKibbin WJ, Morris AC, Wilcoxen PJ (2011) Comparing climate commitments: a model-based analysis of the Copenhagen accord. Clim Change Econ 2:79–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meng S, Siriwardana M, McNeill J (2013) The environmental and economic impact of the carbon tax in Australia. Environ Resour Econ 54:313–332

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moss RH, Edmonds JA, Hibbard KA, Manning MR, Rose SK, van Vuuren DP, Carter TR, Emori S, Kainuma M, Kram T, Meehl GA, Mitchell JF, Nakicenovic N, Riahi K, Smith SJ, Stouffer RJ, Thomson AM, Weyant JP, Wilbanks TJ (2010) The next generation of scenarios for climate change research and assessment. Nature 463(7282):747–756

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus WD (1993) Rolling the ‘DICE’: an optimal transition path for controlling greenhouse gases. Resour Energy Econ 15:27–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus W (2007) A review of the Stern Review on the economics of climate change. J Econ Lit 45:686–702

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paltsev S, Capros P (2013) Cost concepts for climate mitigation. Clim Change Econ 4:1340003

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pezzey JCV, Lambie NR (2001) CGE models for evaluating domestic greenhouse policies in Australia: a comparative analysis. Consultancy Report for the Productivity Commission

  • Pindyck R (2013) Climate change policy: what do the models tell us? J Econ Lit 51(3):860–872

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riahi K, Rao S, Krey V, Cho C, Chirkov V, Fischer G, Kindermann G, Nakicenovic N, Rafai P (2011) RCP 8.5: a scenario of comparatively high greenhouse gas emissions. Clim Change 109:33–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saunders HD (1992) The Khazzoom–Brookes postulate and neoclassical growth. Energy J 13(4):131–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saveyn B, Paroussos L, Ciscar J-C (2012) Economic analysis of a low carbon pathway to 2050: a case for China, India and Japan. Energy Econ 34(Supplement 3):S451–S458

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schenker O (2013) Exchanging goods and damages: the role of trade on the distribution of climate change costs. Environ Resour Econ 54:261–282

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stern DI (2012) Interfuel substitution: a meta-analysis. J Econ Surv 26(2):307–331

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stern DI, Pezzey JCV, Lambie NR (2012) Where in the world is it cheapest to cut carbon emissions? Aust J Agric Resour Econ 56(3):315–331

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stern NH (2007) The economics of climate change: the Stern Review. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge and New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Stern NH (2013) The structure of economic modeling of the potential impacts of climate change: grafting gross underestimation of risk onto already narrow science models. J Econ Lit 51(3):838–859

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sunstein CR (2007–2008) The world versus the United States and China: the complex climate change incentives of the leading greenhouse gas emitters. UCLA Law Rev 55(6):1675–1700

  • Tavoni M, Tol RSJ (2010) Counting only the hits? The risk of underestimating the costs of a stringent climate policy. Clim Change 100:769–778

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tol RSJ (2009) The feasibility of low concentration targets: an application of FUND. Energy Econ 31(Supplement 2):S121–S130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tol RSJ (2011) Modified Ramsey discounting for climate change. ESRI Working Paper No.368

  • Treasury (2008) Australia’s low pollution future: the economics of climate change mitigation. Commonw Aust

  • van Vuuren DP, Edmonds J, Kainuma M, Riahi K, Thomson A, Hibbard K, Hurtt GC, Kram T, Krey V, Lamarque J-F, Masui T, Meinshausen M, Nakicenovic N, Smith SJ, Rose SK (2011) The representative concentration pathways: an overview. Clim Change 109(1–2):5–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Webster M, Sokolov A, Reilly J, Forest C, Paltsev S, Schlosser A, Wang C, Kicklighter D, Sarofim M, Melillo J, Prinn R, Jacoby H (2012) Analysis of climate policy targets under uncertainty. Clim Change 112(3–4):569–583

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank the Australian Research Council for providing funding under grant DP120101088 ‘Energy Transitions: Past, Present, and Future” and Warwick McKibbin and Peter Wilcoxen for allowing us to use the G-Cubed model in this project. We also thank Frank Jotzo for much helpful advice, and participants at the Australian Agricultural and Resource Economics Society annual conference in Port Macquarie, NSW and two anonymous referees for useful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to David I. Stern.

Ethics declarations

Conflicts of interest

We received funding from the Australian Research Council and have no conflicts of interest.

Appendix: The G-Cubed Model

Appendix: The G-Cubed Model

G-Cubed has some important features that make it particularly suitable for our analysis. G-Cubed has various tiers of nesting on the production and consumption sides, which allows us to explore the substitutability of the economy at different levels (see Fig. 7). In the following, we describe the features of the model that are most relevant to our sensitivity analysis. McKibbin and Wilcoxen (1999, 2013) provide a more complete description of the model. There are twelve production sectors where the top tier level of production is modeled as a CES function of capital, labor, energy and materials:

$$\begin{aligned} Q_i =A_i^o \left( {\sum \limits _{j=K,L,E,M} \left( {\delta _{ij}^o } \right) ^{\frac{1}{\sigma _i^o }}\left( {A_j^o X_{ij} } \right) ^{\frac{\sigma _i^o -1}{\sigma _i^o }}} \right) ^{\frac{\sigma _i^o }{\sigma _i^o -1}}, \end{aligned}$$
(5)

where \(Q_{i}\) is the output for sector i, the \(X_{ij}\) are the inputs for sector \(i; A_{i}^{O}, \sigma _{i}^{O}\), and \(\delta _{ij}^{O}\) are parameters that reflect technology, elasticity of substitution, and input weights, respectively. Particularly, \(A_{j}^{O} (j=K, L, E, M)\) is the factor-specific technology parameter at the top tier. The energy \((X_{iE})\) and materials \((X_{iM})\) inputs in (1) are also modeled as CES functions of component energy carriers and materials:

$$\begin{aligned} X_{iE} =\left( {\sum \limits _{j=1,\ldots ,6} \left( {\delta _{ij}^E } \right) ^{\frac{1}{\sigma _i^E }}\left( {X_{ij}^E } \right) ^{\frac{\sigma _i^E -1}{\sigma _i^E }}} \right) ^{\frac{\sigma _i^E }{\sigma _i^E -1}} \end{aligned}$$
(6)

where \(X_{,iE}\) is the aggregate energy used in sector i. The \(X_{ij}^{E}\) represent outputs of the six energy producing sectors including: electricity, crude oil, coal, petroleum, natural gas and its utility; \(\sigma _{i}^{E}\) and \(\delta _{ij}^{E}\) are inter-fuel elasticity and input weights parameters, respectively. Similarly the aggregate material input is a CES aggregate of the outputs from the six “materials” producing sectors of the economy. Materials in fact include transportation and services inputs. Each of these lower tier inputs—both materials and energy—are a CES aggregate of domestic and imported commodities where the elasticity of substitution is the Armington elasticity.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Production and consumption structure in G-Cubed. a Production nesting. b Consumption structure

In addition to the twelve ordinary industrial sectors, there are also a capital goods production sector, which has a similar nesting, with \(\sigma ^{OR}\) and \(\sigma ^{ER}\) being the elasticity parameters in the two tiers.Footnote 6

In common with most studies using G-Cubed, the major sources of technological change are in the form of labor augmenting technical change and autonomous energy efficiency improvement (AEEI) (McKibbin and Wilcoxen 1999; McKibbin et al. 2008). Our assumptions about the rates of labor productivity growth and AEEI are documented in Tables 10 and 11. These technological change parameters have an impact on both the BAU projections of GDP and emissions as well as on the costs of mitigation. The relative price of labor and energy will regulate the energy consumption and emissions paths over time. The higher the prices of other factors of production are relative to the price of energy in the BAU projection, the higher mitigation costs will be. Labor augmentation and capital-energy substitution can increase the amount of electricity produced per unit input of fossil fuels over time up to some limit of productivity as assumed.

Table 10 Labor productivity assumptions
Table 11 Autonomous energy efficiency improvement (AEEI) assumptions

On the household side, the representative household utility function is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} U_t =\int _t^\infty \left( {\hbox {ln}C\left( s \right) +\hbox {ln}G\left( s \right) } \right) e^{-\theta \left( {s-t} \right) }ds \end{aligned}$$
(7)

where C is aggregate consumption and G is government consumption, which is intended to measure the provision of public goods; \(\theta \) is the rate of pure time preference. Aggregate consumption C also has two layers of CES nesting: one is the top tier nesting of household capital, labor, energy, and materials; the lower tier consists of inter-fuel nesting for energy (with elasticity \(\sigma ^{EH}\)) and nesting for material goods (with elasticity \(\sigma ^{MH}\)). Therefore, the top tier consumption aggregate is as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} C=\left( {\sum \limits _{j=K,L,E,M} \left( {\delta _{Cj}^C } \right) ^{\frac{1}{\sigma _C^{OH} }}\left( {X_{Cj} } \right) ^{\frac{\sigma _C^{OH} -1}{\sigma _C^{OH} }}} \right) ^{\frac{\sigma _C^{OH} }{\sigma _C^{OH} -1}} \end{aligned}$$
(8)

in which \(\sigma _{C}^{OH}\) and \(\delta _{Cj}^{C}\) are the elasticity of substitution between the 12 consumption goods and the corresponding weights parameters, respectively. The elasticities: \(\sigma _{i}^{O}, \sigma _{i}^{E}, \sigma ^{OR}, \sigma ^{ER}, \sigma ^{OH}\), and \(\sigma ^{EH}\) are the parameters of interest in our sensitivity analysis.

We set the rate of time preference to 2.2 % and the annual growth rate of effective labor in the steady state to 1.8 %.Footnote 7 Since the quantity and value variables in the model are scaled by the number of effective labor units, the growth rate of effective labor units appears in the discount factor. These quantity and value variables must be converted back to their original form (McKibbin and Wilcoxen 2013). Since utility is in a log-linear form as in Eq. (7), the elasticity of marginal utility is 1 and our discounting rule is consistent with the modified Ramsey discounting rule in climate economic modeling (e.g. Tol 2011). Therefore, G-Cubed assumes that the long-term real interest rate converges to 4 % at the steady state, which is comparable to the discount rate of 4.3 % in Nordhaus (2007)’s DICE model. This rate is used in computing the net present value of mitigation costs in our study.

The G-Cubed model also features macro-economic characteristics such as partly rational expectations, price stickiness, and a central bank policy rule. These distinctive features that most recursive CGE models do not have, give the model rich short-run dynamics and make the model more suitable for short to medium term scenario analysis. While long-run consequences are the usual focus of climate scientists, the short-run to medium run (two to three decades) dynamics are probably more relevant to policy-makers and economists. G-Cubed also features a comprehensive representation of international trade, which is important for issues in a global context, such as climate change.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lu, Y., Stern, D.I. Substitutability and the Cost of Climate Mitigation Policy. Environ Resource Econ 64, 81–107 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-015-9936-7

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-015-9936-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation