Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Lobbying for and Against Subsidizing Green Energy

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We consider a small open economy that operates a carbon emission trading scheme and subsidizes green energy. Taking cap-and-trade as given, we seek to explain the subsidy as the outcome of a trilateral tug of war between the green lobby, the brown lobby and the consumer lobby. With parametric functions we fully solve the competitive economic equilibrium and the lobbying Nash equilibrium. The rate of the green subsidy results from complementary or opposing political pressures of the three interest groups. If the brown lobby is stronger than the green one, our main results are (i) that the outcome of the three-party lobbying game is a green tax, if preferences are not green, and (ii) that green consumer preferences are necessary but not sufficient for generating a green subsidy in the lobbying game.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The EU climate and energy package (http://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/package/index_en.htm) is a set of binding legislation that aims to ensure the EU meets its ambitious climate and energy targets for 2020. One of the key objectives is raising the share of EU energy consumption produced rom renewable resources to 20 %.

  2. Depending on the energy aggregate under consideration (e.g. primary energy, electricity consumption etc.) the share of green energy in Germany is only in the range of 10 –15 % despite massive subsidization of green energy over the last years. See e.g. www.bdew.de/internet.nsf/id/DE-Energiedaten.

  3. In our model, total emissions are fixed by the emission cap and remain fixed throughout the paper. Hence, the small open economy’s contribution to climate damage is fixed and is therefore ignored in our formal analysis.

  4. Below we present some references for the argument that a green subsidy in addition to emission trading or emission taxes is welfare reducing.

  5. Note that if preferences are green, welfare maximization requires adding a green subsidy to the ETS—as shown in Proposition 1 below.

  6. To promote their vision of sustainability, individuals may be willing to substitute non-renewable fossil energy consumption with green energy consumption at an extra cost irrespective of whether carbon emissions generate a detrimental climate externality. Replacing the consumption of a non-renewable by a renewable resource may be considered per se as a step toward a more sustainable development.

  7. For a literature survey see Mueller (2003).

  8. The competing approaches to political-economic modeling of Becker (1983) and Grossman and Helpman (1996) have different strengths and weaknesses. Our own assessment of the ’energy turn-around’ (Energiewende) in Germany is that to a large extent the government accommodates to the strong pressures exerted by stakeholders which suggests that Becker’s modeling approach appears to be realistic in the present context.

  9. We make use of the parametric functions throughout the paper. The general functional signs \(B\), \(G\) and \(X\) only serve to ease the notation where appropriate.

  10. Although green and brown energy are not always perfect substitutes, the homogeneity assumption is often used as an approximation in the theoretical literature, e.g. by Tsur and Zemel (2003) or Chakravorty et al. (2006, 2008).

  11. Note also that the fossil-fuel import assumption is not essential, because one can reinterpret the world market price \(p_e\) as a fixed technical coefficient (\(=\)capital input per unit output of fossil fuel) of the domestic production/extraction of fossil fuel.

  12. Alternatively, \(t\) can be interpreted as an emission tax whose rate is set as to satisfy (6). Here we stick to the ETS interpretation which implies that the cap is politically determined and fixed, while the permit price \(t\) is an endogenous variable.

  13. The more realistic modeling in form of a feed-in tariff would require a mark-up, say \(\tau \), on the consumer price of energy satisfying \(\tau \sum \nolimits _j z_{dj}=s g\). Consumer \(i\)’s corresponding budget constraint would then read \(x_{di} +(p_z + \tau ) z_{di} =(\pi _i/n_i) + (\bar{k} + t \bar{e})/n\). The lump sum tax in the present paper is assumed for analytical relief.

  14. For analytical convenience—rather than for empirical relevance—we will also allow for a green energy tax \((s < 0)\), but we will not place much attention on scenarios where the outcome is a tax.

  15. \(\hat{\Pi }^x (s)=0\) for all \(s\) is obvious due to the linear production technology.

  16. The negatively sloped branch of the profit curve is outside the domain of feasible subsidy rates.

  17. In “Appendix 2” we show that there is some threshold value \(\tilde{n} > 0\) such that \(w_{x1} \gtreqless 0\), if and only if \(n \lesseqgtr \tilde{n}\). Since we envisage an economy with a large population, we proceed assuming \(w_{x1} < 0\).

  18. One could argue that it should be in the interest of the consumer group \(j=b, g\) to engage in lobbying itself rather than delegating the lobbying to the industry it owns, because \(\hat{U}^j(s) \ne \frac{\hat{\Pi }^j (s)}{n_j}\) according to (18). The assumption that the consumers owning the green or brown energy industry, respectively, do not form a lobby themselves but rather let ’their’ industry do the lobbying job for them is realistic, in our view, because the industry lobby is more effective in solving the free-rider problem associated with collective action than the lobby formed by the owners themselves. One can expect, therefore, that the former promotes its owners’ interests more effectively than the latter.

  19. In Hillman and Ursprung’s (1992) study of trade policy formation, an environmental interest group plays an important role comparable to that of the consumer lobby in our model. According to these authors, the environmentalists are capable to cope with problems of information and coordination and thus exert significant influence on the political allocation via strategic decision-making.

  20. Due to our simplifying assumption of linear production technology in the consumption-good industry, these profit incomes are zero and hence completely independent of the green subsidy rate.

  21. The consumer of groups \(b\) and \(g\) do not form a lobby by assumption which implies that all consumers of these groups take the provision of green energy, \(g\), as given. Hence the size of \(\gamma \) does not matter for their consumption plans.

  22. Note also that the capital market clearing condition (4) is now replaced by \(\bar{k} = k_g+k_x + r_b+r_g+r_x\).

  23. The definition is \(r_{-i}:= (r_j, r_k)\) for \(i, j,k= b, g, x\); \(i \ne j,k\) and \(j \ne k\).

  24. In the comparative static effects of \(\partial \rho _x^N / \partial \psi \) and \(\partial s / \partial a_x\) it is assumed that \(a_x>0\).

References

  • Aidt TS (1997) Cooperative lobbying and endogenous trade policy. Public Choice 93:455–475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aidt TS (2002) Strategic political participation and redistribution. Econ Polit 14:19–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aidt TS (2003) Redistribution and deadweight cost: the role of political competition. Eur J Polit Econ 19:205–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aidt TS (2010) Green taxes: refunding rules and lobbying. J Environ Econ Manag 60:31–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker G (1983) A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Q J Econ 98:371–400

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker G (1985) Public policies, pressure groups and dead weight costs. J Public Econ 28:329–347

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bennear LS, Stavins RN (2007) Second-best theory and the use of multiple policy instruments. Environ Resour Econ 37:111–129

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Böhringer C, Löschel A, Moslener U, Rutherford TF (2009) EU climate policy up to 2020: an economic impact assessment. Energy Econ 31:295–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chakravorty U, Moreaux M, Tidall M (2008) Ordering the extraction of pollution nonrenewable resources. Am Econ Rev 98:1128–1149

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chakravorty U, Mague B, Moreaux M (2006) A hotelling model with a ceiling on the stock of pollution. J Econ Dyn Control 30:2875–2904

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichner T, Pethig R (2014) Efficient management of insecure fossil fuel imports through taxing domestic green energy? J Public Econ Theory (in press)

  • European Commission (2013) EU energy in figures. Statistical Pocketbook 2013

  • Fischer C, Newell RG (2008) Environmental and technological policies for climate mitigation. J Environ Econ Manag 55:142–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischer C (2008) Emissions pricing, spillovers, and public investment in environmentally friendly technologies. Energy Econ 30:487–502

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson PG (1997) The political economy of pollution taxes in a small open economy. J Environ Econ Manag 33:44–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman GM, Helpman E (1996) Electoral competition and special interest politics. Rev Econ Stud 63:265–285

  • Hillman AL, Ursprung H (1992) The influence of environmental concerns on the political determination of trade policy. In: Anderson K, Blackhurst R (eds) The greening of world trade issues. Harvester Wheatsheaf, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Maxwell JW, Lyon TP, Hackett SC (2000) Self-regulation and social welfare: the political economy of corporate environmentalism. J Law Econ 43:583–617

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mulligan CB, Sala-i-Martin X (2004) Political and economic forces sustaining social security. Adv Econ Anal Policy 4, Article 5

  • Mueller DC (2003) Public choice III. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mozunder P, Vásquez WF, Marathe A (2011) Consumers’ preference for renewable energy in the southwest USA. Energy Econ 33:1119–1126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson M (1965) The logic of collective action. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Pethig R, Wittlich C (2009) Interaction of carbon reduction and green energy promotion in a small fossil-fuel importing country. In: CESifo Working Paper No. 2749

  • Poe GL, Clark JE, Rondeau D, Schulze WD (2002) Provision point mechanisms and field validity test of contingent valuation. Environ Resour Econ 23:105–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reichenbach J, Requate T (2012) Subsidies in the presence of learning effects and market power. Resour Energy Econ 34:236–254

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Requate T (2010) Climate policy between activism and rationalism. Anal Krit 01:159–176

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik D (1986) Tariffs, subsidies and welfare with endogenous policy. J Int Econ 21:285–299

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Toman MA (1993) The economics of energy security: theory, evidence policy. In: Kneese AV, Sweeney JM (eds) Handbook of natural resource and energy economics, vol III. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1167–1218

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Tsur Y, Zemel A (2003) Optimal taxation to backstop substitutes for nonrenewable resourees. J Econ Dyn Control 27:551–572

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wellisz S, Wilson J (1986) Lobbying and tariff formation: a dead weight loss consideration. J Int Econ 20:367–375

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wiser RH (2007) Using contingent valuation to explore willingness to pay for renewable energy: a comparison of collective and voluntary payment vehicles. Ecol Econ 62:419–432

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thomas Eichner.

Additional information

Helpful comments from an associate editor and three anonymous referees are gratefully acknowledged.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Social Optimum

For an interior solution, the FOCs of solving (7) are:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{lll} {\mathcal L}_e = \lambda _b B'(e) - \lambda _e - \lambda _t p_e =0, &{} {\mathcal L}_b = \lambda _z - \lambda _b =0, &{} {\mathcal L}_x = - \lambda _x + \lambda _t =0, \\ {\mathcal L}_g =n \gamma + \lambda _z - \lambda _g =0, &{} {\mathcal L}_{x_d} =n - n \lambda _t =0, &{} {\mathcal L}_z = -\lambda _z + \lambda _\psi =0, \\ {\mathcal L}_{k_g} = \lambda _g G'(k_g) - \lambda _k =0, &{} {\mathcal L}_{z_d} = n V'(z_d) - n \lambda _\psi =0, &{} {\mathcal L}_{k_x} = \lambda _x - \lambda _k =0. \\ \end{array}\quad \end{aligned}$$
(39)

These FOCs imply \(\lambda _k= \lambda _t = \lambda _x=1\), \(\lambda _b = \lambda _z\), \(\lambda _g = \lambda _z + n \gamma \) and give rise to the equations \(\lambda _z = V'(z_d)\), \((\lambda _z + n \gamma ) G'(k_g)=1\) and \(\lambda _z B'(e) = \lambda _e + p_e\), which imply (8), in turn.

Appendix 2: Proofs

1.1 Proof of Proposition 2

  1. (i)

    From profit maximization of the green industry [\(\pi _g'=0\), see also (11)], follows

    $$\begin{aligned} k_g = (p_z+s)^2 \mu , \quad g = 2 \mu (p_z+s) \quad \text{ and } \quad \pi _g= \mu (p_z+s)^2. \end{aligned}$$
    (40)

    Inserting \(z_{d}= c - p_z\) and \(g\) from (40) in the equilibrium condition of the domestic energy market \(n z_d = \bar{b} +g\) we obtain after rearrangement of terms

    $$\begin{aligned} \hat{p}_z = \bar{\kappa } - (1 - \kappa ) s \quad \text{ and } \quad \hat{p}_z + s = \bar{\kappa } + \kappa s, \end{aligned}$$
    (41)

    where \(\kappa := \frac{n}{n+2\mu } \in ]0, 1[, \bar{\kappa } := \kappa (c - \frac{\bar{b} }{n} )>0\) and \(\bar{b}:= \bar{e}^\beta \). The ’hat’ indicates that \(\hat{p}_z\) is the equilibrium price. Observe that \( \bar{\kappa } = c - \frac{\bar{b} }{n} = \hat{p}_z + \frac{\hat{g} }{n}>0\). In view of (40) and (41) we obtain the equilibrium profit (14).

  2. (ii)

    From profit maximization of the brown industry [\(\pi _b'=0\), see also (10)] follows

    $$\begin{aligned} t = \beta p_z \bar{e}^{\beta - 1} - p_e>0 \end{aligned}$$
    (42)

    taking into account that the emission cap \(\bar{e}\) is strictly binding. Hence for given \(p_z\) the maximum profit is

    $$\begin{aligned} \pi _b= (1-\beta ) \bar{b} p_z. \end{aligned}$$
    (43)

    In view of (43) and (41) we obtain the equilibrium profit (15).

  3. (iii)

    Next, we consider the utility of consumer group \(x\):

    $$\begin{aligned} \hat{u}_x = c \hat{z}_d - \frac{\hat{z}_d^2}{2} + \hat{y}_x -p_z \hat{z}_d + \gamma \hat{g} = \left[ (c - \hat{p}_z) \hat{z}_d - \frac{\hat{z}_d^2}{2} \right] + \frac{\bar{k} + \hat{t} \bar{e} - s \hat{g}}{n} + \gamma \hat{g}. \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
    (44)

Combine the term in square brackets with \(z_d = c -p_z\) and (41) to get

$$\begin{aligned} (c- \hat{p}_z) \hat{z}_d - \frac{\hat{z}_d^2}{2} = \frac{(c - \hat{p}_z)^2}{2} = \frac{\left[ c - \bar{\kappa } + (1-\kappa ) s \right] ^2}{2}. \end{aligned}$$
(45)

Insert (40)

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{k} + \hat{t} \bar{e} - s \hat{g} = (\bar{k} + \beta \bar{b} \bar{\kappa } - p_e \bar{e}) - \left[ 2 \bar{\kappa } \mu + (1- \kappa ) \beta \bar{b} \right] s - 2 \kappa \mu s^2 \end{aligned}$$
(46)

to obtain the equilibrium utility

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{U}^x(s)&= \frac{\left[ c - \bar{\kappa } + (1-\kappa ) s \right] ^2}{2} + \frac{\bar{k} + \beta \bar{b} \bar{\kappa } -p_e \bar{e}- \left[ 2 \bar{\kappa } \mu + (1- \kappa ) \beta \bar{b} \right] s - 2 \kappa \mu s^2}{n}\nonumber \\&+ 2 \gamma \mu (\bar{\kappa } + \kappa s) = 2 \kappa \mu \left[ \bar{w}_x + (\gamma + w_{x1}) s - w_{x2} s^2 \right] , \end{aligned}$$
(47)

where \(\bar{w}_x:= \frac{(c - \bar{\kappa })^2}{4 \kappa \mu } + \frac{\bar{\kappa } + \beta \bar{b} \bar{\kappa } - p_e \bar{e}}{2 \kappa \mu n} + \frac{\gamma \bar{\kappa }}{\kappa }\), \(w_{x1} := \frac{(1- \kappa ) (c - \bar{\kappa }) }{2 \kappa \mu } - \frac{ 2 \bar{\kappa } \mu + (1- \kappa ) \beta \bar{b}}{2 \kappa \mu n}\) and \(w_{x2}:= \frac{1}{n} - \frac{(1-\kappa )^2}{4 \kappa \mu }\). Maximization of \(\hat{U}^x(s)\) with respect to \(s\) leads to the consumer group’s favorite subsidy rate (17).

The sign of \(w_{x1}\) and \(w_{x2}\): To prove \(w_{x2} >0\) we insert \(\kappa = \frac{n}{n+2 \mu }\) in \(w_{x2}= \frac{1}{n} - \frac{(1-\kappa )^2}{4 \kappa \mu }\) and rearrange terms to get \(w_{x2} = \frac{n+ \mu }{ n(n+ 2 \mu )}\).

Next, we prove

$$\begin{aligned} w_{x1} \gtreqless 0 \quad \Longleftrightarrow \quad n \lesseqgtr \frac{(2-\beta ) \bar{b}}{2c} + \sqrt{\frac{(2-\beta )^2 \bar{b}^2}{4 c^2} + \frac{2(1-\beta )\bar{b}\mu }{c}}=: \tilde{n}. \end{aligned}$$
(48)

Verify that

$$\begin{aligned} w_{x1}&:= \frac{(1-\kappa ) (c - \bar{\kappa })}{2 \kappa \mu } - \frac{2 \bar{\kappa } \mu + (1-\kappa )\beta \bar{b}}{2 \kappa \mu n} \gtreqless 0 \nonumber \\&\iff (1-\kappa ) \left[ (c - \bar{\kappa }) n - \beta \bar{b} \right] - 2 \bar{\kappa } \mu \gtreqless 0 \nonumber \\&\iff \frac{1}{n + 2 \mu } \left[ (c - \bar{\kappa }) n - \beta \bar{b} \right] - \bar{\kappa } \gtreqless 0 \nonumber \\&\iff \left[ (c - \bar{\kappa }) n - \beta \bar{b} \right] - (n+2\mu ) \bar{\kappa } \gtreqless 0 \nonumber \\&\iff \left[ (c - \bar{\kappa }) n - \beta \bar{b} \right] - c n + \bar{b} \gtreqless 0 \nonumber \\&\iff - \bar{\kappa } n +(1-\beta ) \bar{b} \gtreqless 0 \nonumber \\&\iff - \frac{n}{n+2 \mu } (c n - \bar{b}) + (1-\beta ) \bar{b} \gtreqless 0 \nonumber \\&\iff - c n^2 + (2-\beta ) \bar{b}n+2(1-\beta ) \bar{b} \mu \gtreqless 0 \nonumber \\&\iff -n^2 + \frac{(2-\beta ) \bar{b}}{c} n + \frac{2(1-\beta ) \bar{b} \mu }{c} \gtreqless 0. \end{aligned}$$
(49)

The last equivalence establishes (48).

  1. (iv)

    For sufficiently large \(n\) the function \(\hat{U}^g\) is progressively increasing in \(s\): The quadratic term in \(\hat{U}^g\) is: \(- 2 \mu \kappa w_{x2} s^2 + \frac{1}{n_g} \mu \kappa ^2 s^2\) which is equivalent to \(\left( - 2 w_{x2} + \frac{\kappa }{n_g}\right) \kappa \mu s^2\). Insert \(w_{x2} = \frac{n+c\mu }{n(n+2\mu )}\) and \(\kappa = \frac{n}{n+2\mu }\) to obtain

    $$\begin{aligned} - 2 w_{x2} + \frac{\kappa }{n_g}>0 \quad&\iff \quad -2 \frac{n+ \mu }{n(n+2\mu ) }+ \frac{n}{n_g(n+2 \mu )} >0 \\&\iff \quad - 2n -2 \mu +\frac{n^2}{n_g}>0. \end{aligned}$$

1.2 Proof of (19)

The sum of utilities of all consumers is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \sum \limits _j \hat{u}_j = n \left( c \hat{z}_d - \frac{\hat{z}_d^2}{2} + \gamma g \right) + \sum \limits _jx_{jd}. \end{aligned}$$
(50)

Making use of the trade balance (3) and \(x = k_x =\bar{k}- k_g\) in (50) we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \sum \limits _j \hat{u}_j = n \left( c \hat{z}_d - \frac{\hat{z}_d^2}{2} + \gamma g \right) + \bar{k} - k_g - p_e e. \end{aligned}$$
(51)

Next, we insert \(\hat{z}_d = c - \hat{p}_z\), (40) and (41) in (51) to obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\sum \nolimits _j \hat{u}_j}{n}&= c \hat{z}_d - \frac{\hat{z}_d^2}{2} + \gamma g + \frac{ \bar{k} - k_g - p_e e}{n} = c \left( \bar{\xi } + (1-\kappa ) s \right) \nonumber \\&-\, \frac{1}{2} \left( \bar{\xi } + (1-\kappa ) s \right) ^2 + \gamma 2 \mu (\bar{\kappa } + \kappa s) + \frac{ \bar{k} - \mu \left( \bar{\kappa } + \kappa s\right) ^2 - p_e e}{n}, \end{aligned}$$
(52)

where \(\bar{\xi } : = c - \bar{\kappa }\). Further rearrangements of (52) yield

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\sum \nolimits _j \hat{u}_j}{n}&= c \bar{\xi } - \frac{ \xi ^2}{2} + 2 \gamma \mu \bar{\kappa } + \frac{\bar{k} - \mu \bar{\kappa }^2 -p_e e}{n}\nonumber \\&+ \left( c (1-\kappa ) - \bar{\xi } (1- \kappa ) + 2 \gamma \mu \kappa - \frac{2 \mu \bar{\kappa } \kappa }{n} \right) s -\, \left( \frac{ (1-\kappa )^2}{2} + \frac{\mu \kappa ^2}{n} \right) s^2 \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(53)

Next, observe that

$$\begin{aligned} c (1-\kappa ) - \bar{\xi } (1- \kappa ) + 2 \gamma \mu \kappa - \frac{2 \mu \bar{\kappa } \kappa }{n} = \bar{\kappa } \left( 1-\kappa - \frac{2 \mu \kappa }{n} \right) + 2 \gamma \mu \kappa = 2 \gamma \mu \kappa \end{aligned}$$
(54)

and that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ (1-\kappa )^2}{2} + \frac{\mu \kappa ^2}{n} = \frac{(2 \mu )^2}{2 (n +2 \mu )^2} + \frac{\mu n^2}{n (n +2 \mu )^2}= \frac{\mu }{n+2\mu } = \frac{\mu \kappa }{n}. \end{aligned}$$
(55)

Making use of (54) and (55) in (53) establishes

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\sum \nolimits _j \hat{u}_j}{n} = \nu + 2 \gamma \mu \kappa s - \left( \frac{\mu \kappa }{n} \right) s^2, \end{aligned}$$
(56)

where \(\nu := c \bar{\xi } - \frac{ \xi ^2}{2} + 2 \gamma \mu \bar{\kappa } + \frac{\bar{k} - \mu \bar{\kappa }^2 -p_e e}{n}\).

1.3 Proof of Proposition 3

(ii) Rewrite (28) to get

$$\begin{aligned} \rho ^N_g = \frac{a_g \mu \kappa ^2}{1-a^2_g \kappa ^2 \mu } \left[ \frac{\bar{\kappa }}{\kappa } + S\left( \rho ^N_b, 0, \rho ^N_x\right) \right] . \end{aligned}$$

Observe that the producer price \(p_z + s = \bar{\kappa } + \kappa s\) from (41) has to be strictly positive. Then we immediately get \(\frac{\bar{\kappa }}{\kappa } + s > 0\) which ensures \(\rho ^{N}_g > 0\) and hence we obtain \(S (\rho ^N_b, \rho ^N_g, \rho ^N_x) > S(\rho ^N_b, 0, \rho ^N_x)\).

(i) I. Proof of:

$$\begin{aligned} S\left( \rho ^N_b, \rho _g^N, \rho _x^{N}\right) \gtreqless S\left( \rho ^N_b, \rho _g^N, 0\right) \quad \Longleftrightarrow \quad s^*_x (\gamma ) \gtreqless S \left( \rho ^N_b, \rho _g^N, 0\right) . \end{aligned}$$

From (29) we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \rho ^N_x = \frac{a_x \kappa \mu n_x}{1+2a^2_x \kappa \mu w_{x2}} \left[ s^*_x (\gamma ) - S\left( \rho ^N_b, \rho ^N_g, 0\right) \right] \end{aligned}$$
(57)

where

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathrm {sign}} \,a_x = {\mathrm {sign}} \,\left[ s^*_x (\gamma ) - S(\rho ^N_b, \rho _g^N, 0)\right] \end{aligned}$$
(58)

From (57) and (58) we infer

$$\begin{aligned} s^*_x (\gamma ) \gtreqless S\left( \rho ^N_b, \rho _g^N, 0\right) \quad \Longrightarrow \quad a_x \gtreqless 0 \quad \Longrightarrow \quad S\left( \rho ^N_b, \rho _g^N, \rho ^{N}_x\right) \gtreqless S\left( \rho ^N_b, \rho _g^N, 0\right) \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} S\left( \rho ^N_b, \rho _g^N, \rho ^{N}_x\right) \gtreqless S\left( \rho ^N_b, \rho _g^N, 0\right) \quad \Longrightarrow \quad a_x \gtreqless 0 \quad \Longrightarrow \quad s^*_x (\gamma ) \gtreqless S\left( \rho ^N_b, \rho _g^N, 0\right) . \end{aligned}$$

II. Proof of:

$$\begin{aligned} s^*_x (\gamma ) \gtreqless S\left( \rho ^N_b, \rho _g^N, \rho ^{N}_g\right) \quad \Longleftrightarrow \quad s^*_x (\gamma ) \gtreqless S\left( \rho ^N_b, \rho _g^N, 0\right) . \end{aligned}$$

For \(\rho ^{N}_x > 0\) the equation \(\Pi ^x_{r_x} = 0\) from (26) reads

$$\begin{aligned} \rho ^{N}_x = 2 \kappa \mu n_x w_{x2} \left\{ a_x \left[ s^*_x (\gamma ) - S\left( \rho ^N_b, \rho _g^N, \rho ^{N}_x\right) \right] \right\} . \end{aligned}$$
(59)

Comparing (57) and (59) immediately yields

$$\begin{aligned} s^*_x (\gamma ) \gtreqless S\left( \rho ^N_b, \rho _g^N, \rho ^{N}_x\right) \quad \Longleftrightarrow \quad s^*_x (\gamma ) \gtreqless S\left( \rho ^N_b, \rho _g^N, 0\right) . \end{aligned}$$

1.4 Proof of Proposition 4:

  1. (i)

    From (29) with \(a_g = 0\) we obtain

    $$\begin{aligned} \rho ^{BX}_x = \frac{a_x \kappa \mu n_x 2 w_{x2}}{1+2a^2_x \kappa \mu w_{x2}} \left[ s^*_x (\gamma ) - S \left( \rho ^N_b, 0, 0\right) \right] , \end{aligned}$$
    (60)

    where

    $$\begin{aligned} {\mathrm {sign}} \,a_x = {\mathrm {sign}} \,\left[ s^*_x (\gamma ) - S\left( \rho ^N_b, 0, 0\right) \right] . \end{aligned}$$
    (61)

    Next, \(\Pi ^x_{r_x} = 0\) from (26) implies

    $$\begin{aligned} \rho ^{BX}_x = 2 \kappa \mu n_x w_{x2} \left\{ a_x \left[ s^*_x (\gamma ) - S\left( \rho ^N_b, 0, \rho ^{BX}_x\right) \right] \right\} . \end{aligned}$$
    (62)

    (60)–(62) estabish

    $$\begin{aligned} s^*_x (\gamma ) \gtreqless S\left( \rho ^N_b, 0, \rho ^{BX}_x\right) \gtreqless S\left( \rho ^N_b, 0, 0\right) \quad \iff \quad s^*_x (\gamma ) \gtreqless S\left( \rho ^N_b, 0, 0\right) . \end{aligned}$$
  2. (ii)

    For \(a_x = 0\), (28) turns into

    $$\begin{aligned} \rho ^{BG}_g = \frac{a_g \mu \kappa ^2}{1- a^2_g \kappa ^2 \mu } \left( \frac{\bar{\kappa }}{\kappa } - a_b \rho ^N_b \right) = \frac{a_g \mu \kappa ^2}{1-a^2_g \kappa ^2 \mu } \left[ \frac{\bar{\kappa }}{\kappa } + S\left( \rho ^N_b, 0, 0\right) \right] . \end{aligned}$$
    (63)

    Due to \(\frac{\bar{\kappa }}{\kappa } + s > 0\), we get \(\rho ^{BG}_g > 0\) which implies \(S(\rho ^N_b, \rho ^{BG}_g, 0) > S(\rho ^N_b, 0, 0)\).

  3. (iii)

    For \(a_b= 0\), we rewrite (28) as

    $$\begin{aligned} \rho ^{GX}_g = \frac{a_g \mu \kappa ^2}{1-a^2_g \kappa ^2 \mu } \left[ \frac{\bar{\kappa }}{\kappa } + S\left( 0, 0, \rho _x^{GX}\right) \right] . \end{aligned}$$
    (64)

    Due to \(\frac{\bar{\kappa }}{\kappa } + s > 0\), we get \(\rho ^{GX}_g > 0\) and hence \(S(0, \rho ^{GX}_g, \rho _x^{GX}) > S(0, 0, \rho _x^{GX})\).

From (29) with \(a_b = 0\) we have

$$\begin{aligned} \rho ^{GX}_x = \frac{a_x \kappa \mu n_x}{1 + 2 a^2_x \kappa \mu w_{x2}} \left[ s^*_x (\gamma ) - S\left( 0, \rho ^{GX}_g, 0\right) \right] \end{aligned}$$
(65)

where

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathrm {sign}} \,a_x = {\mathrm {sign}} \,\left[ s^*_x (\gamma ) - S\left( 0, \rho ^{GX}_g, 0\right) \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(66)

Next, the equation \(\Pi ^x_{r_x}=0\) from (26) can be written as

$$\begin{aligned} \rho ^{GX}_x = \kappa \mu n_x 2 w_{x2} \left\{ a_x \left[ s^*_x (\gamma ) - S\left( 0, \rho ^{GX}_g, \rho ^{GX}_x\right) \right] \right\} . \end{aligned}$$
(67)

From (65)–(67) we infer

$$\begin{aligned} s^*_x (\gamma ) \gtreqless S\left( 0, \rho ^{GX}_g, \rho ^{GX}_x\right) \gtreqless S\left( 0, \rho ^{GX}_g, 0\right) \quad \Longleftrightarrow \quad s^*_x \gtreqless S\left( 0, \rho ^{GX}_g, 0\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Appendix 3: Comparative Statics of the Nash Equilibrium

Differentiation of \(\rho ^N_b = \frac{a_b (1-\beta ) \bar{e}^{\beta } (1-\kappa )}{2}\) yields

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \rho ^N_b}{\partial a_b}&= \frac{(1-\beta )\bar{e}^{\beta } (1-\kappa )}{2} > 0, \\ \frac{\partial \rho ^N_b}{\partial a_g}&= \frac{\partial \rho ^N_b}{\partial a_x} = \frac{\partial g^N_b}{\partial \gamma } = 0, \\ \frac{\partial \rho ^N_b}{\partial \bar{e}}&= \frac{a_b (1-\beta ) \beta \bar{e}^{\beta - 1} (1-\kappa )}{2} > 0. \end{aligned}$$

Differentiation of

$$\begin{aligned} \rho ^N_x = \frac{a_x n_x\kappa \mu \left[ (w_{x1}+ \gamma ) \left( 1- a_g^2 \kappa ^2 \mu \right) + a_b^2 w_{x2} (1-\kappa ) (1-\beta ) \bar{b} - 2 a_g^2 \kappa w_{x2} \mu \bar{\kappa } \right] }{1- a_g^2\kappa ^2 \mu + 2 a_x^2 n_x \kappa w_{x2} \mu } \end{aligned}$$

yields

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \rho ^N_x}{\partial a_b}&= \frac{2a_b a_x n_x \bar{b} \mu (1-\kappa ) \kappa (1-\beta ) w_{x2} }{1-a^2_g \kappa ^2 \mu + 2 a^2_x n_x \kappa w_{x2} \mu } > 0, \\ \frac{\partial \rho ^N_x}{\partial \gamma }&= \frac{ a_b^2 a_x n_x (1-\kappa )(1-\beta ) \kappa w_{x2} \mu }{1-a^2_g \kappa ^2 \mu + 2 a^2_x n_x \kappa w_{x2} \mu } > 0, \\ \frac{\partial \rho ^N_x}{\partial \bar{b}}&= \frac{a_x n_x\kappa \mu \left[ \left( 1- a_g^2 \kappa ^2 \mu \right) \frac{\partial w_{x1}}{\partial \bar{b}} + a_b^2 w_{x2} (1-\kappa ) (1-\beta ) \ - 2 a_g^2 \kappa w_{x2} \mu \frac{ \partial \bar{\kappa }}{\partial \bar{b}} \right] }{1- a_g^2\kappa ^2 \mu + 2 a_x^2 n_x \kappa w_{x2} \mu } > 0, \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \bar{\kappa }}{\partial \bar{b}}&= - \frac{\kappa c}{n}<0, \\ \frac{\partial w_{x1}}{\partial \bar{b}}&= -\frac{(1-\kappa ) \beta }{2 \kappa \mu n } - \left( \frac{1-\kappa }{2c \kappa \mu } +\frac{2 \mu }{ 2 \kappa \mu n} \right) \cdot \underbrace{\frac{\partial \bar{\kappa }}{\partial \bar{b}}}_{= - \frac{\kappa c}{n}} = \frac{(1-\beta ) c}{n} + \frac{1-\kappa }{2 \mu n}>0. \end{aligned}$$

Differentiating

$$\begin{aligned} \rho ^N_g = \frac{a_g \kappa \mu \left[ a_x^2 n_x \kappa ^2 \mu (w_{x1}+\gamma ) + (1+ 2 a_x^2 n_x \kappa w_{x2} \mu ) \bar{\kappa } -0.5 a_b^2 \kappa (1-\kappa ) (1-\beta ) \bar{b} \right] }{1- a_g^2\kappa ^2 \mu + 2 a_x^2 n_x \kappa w_{x2} \mu } \end{aligned}$$

we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \rho _g^N}{\partial a_b}&= - \frac{a_b a_g \bar{b} (1-\kappa ) (1-\beta ) \kappa ^2 \mu }{1-a^2_g \kappa ^2 \mu + 2 a^2_x n_x \kappa w_{x2} \mu } < 0, \\ \frac{\partial \rho _g^N}{\partial \gamma }&= \frac{a_g a^2_x n_x \kappa ^3 \mu ^2}{1-a^2_g \kappa ^2 \mu + 2 a^2_x n_x \kappa w_{x2} \mu } > 0, \end{aligned}$$

Finally, differentiation of

$$\begin{aligned} S\left( \rho ^N_b, \rho ^N_g, \rho ^N_x\right)&= \frac{a_x^2 n_x \kappa \mu (w_{x1} +\gamma )+ a_g^2 \kappa \mu \bar{\kappa } - a_b \rho _b^N}{1- a_g^2\kappa ^2 \mu + 2 a_x^2 n_x \kappa w_{x2} \mu } \\&= \frac{\kappa \mu \left[ a_x^2 n_x (w_{x1} +\gamma )+ a_g^2 \bar{\kappa }\right] - 0.5 a_b^2 (1-\kappa ) (1-\beta ) \bar{b}}{1- a_g^2\kappa ^2 \mu + 2 a_x^2 n_x \kappa w_{x2} \mu } \end{aligned}$$

leads to

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial S\left( \rho ^N_b, \rho ^N_g, \rho ^N_x\right) }{\partial a_b}&= -\frac{a_b \bar{b} (1-\kappa ) (1-\beta ) }{1-a^2_g \kappa ^2 \mu + 2a_{x}^{2}\, n_x \kappa w_{x2} \mu } <0,\\ \frac{\partial S\left( \rho ^N_b, \rho ^N_g, \rho ^N_x\right) }{\partial a_g}&= \frac{2 a_g \kappa \mu \left[ \left( a_x^2 n_x \kappa \mu (w_{x1} + \gamma ) - a_b \rho _b^N\right) \kappa \right] + \left( 1+ 2 a_x^2 n_x \kappa w_{x2} \mu \right) \bar{\kappa }}{\left( 1-a^2_g \kappa ^2 \mu + 2 a_{x}^{2}\, n_x \kappa w_{x2} \mu \right) ^2},\\ \frac{\partial S\left( \rho ^N_b, \rho ^N_g, \rho ^N_x\right) }{\partial a_x}&= \frac{2 a_x n_x \kappa \mu \left[ w_{x1} +\gamma + 2 a_b w_{x2} \rho _b^N - a_g^2 \kappa \mu \left[ (w_{x1}+ \gamma ) \kappa + 2 w_{x2} \bar{\kappa } \right] \right] }{\left( 1-a^2_g \kappa ^2 \mu + 2 a_{x}^{2}\, n_x \kappa w_{x2} \mu \right) ^2},\\ \frac{\partial S\left( \rho ^N_b, \rho ^N_g, \rho ^N_x\right) }{\partial \gamma }&= \frac{a^2_x \kappa n_x \mu }{1-a^2_g \kappa ^2 \mu + 2a_{x}^{2}\, n_x \kappa w_{x2} \mu } > 0. \end{aligned}$$

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Eichner, T., Pethig, R. Lobbying for and Against Subsidizing Green Energy. Environ Resource Econ 62, 925–947 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-014-9852-2

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-014-9852-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation