Skip to main content
Log in

Green Technology Transfers and Border Tax Adjustments

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We develop a two-country general equilibrium model of foreign technology transfers tied to environmental clean-up and border tax adjustments in the presence of transboundary pollution. Pollution is generated in the aid recipient as a by-product in the production of a ‘dirty’ good, which it consumes, as well as exports to the donor country. In contrast to the literature which typically treats aid as a monetary transfer, we assume that foreign aid consists of a transfer of environmental technology that lowers the cost of public clean-up. We also consider a border tax adjustment (BTA) as a secondary policy instrument used in order to internalize the residual transboundary externality. We study the environmental and welfare outcomes of the technology transfer and the BTA as well as the interaction between the two policy instruments. We derive conditions under which the additional presence of a BTA may lead to a lower transfer and less public pollution abatement in the recipient, with counter-productive consequences for both the environment and welfare. Contrary to intuition, we find that the green technology transfer and the border tax adjustment are not always complements.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Substantive issues exist about how consistent BTAs are with World Trade Organization rules [see e.g. Goh (2004); de Cendra (2006); Hufbauer et al. (2009). However, this paper focuses on how effective BTAs would be at complementing green technology transfers.

  2. E.g. Articles 2 and 12 of the Stockholm Declaration urge developed countries to increase international technical and financial assistance available for environmental protection in developing countries (Roberts et al. 2009). In order to implement chapter 33 of Agenda 21, the sustainable development plan crafted in preparation for the Rio summit, developed countries pledged $141.9 billion to help their developing counterparts tackle global as well as local environmental issues (UNCED 1992). At the Copenhagen climate summit in December 2009, participants also agreed to establish a $100 billion a year ‘green climate fund’ to support projects, programmes, policies and other activities in developing countries related to climate change mitigation (UNFCCC 2009).

  3. From OECD’s International Development Statistics, Development Assistance Committee (DAC). See http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/50/17/5037721.htm, accessed May 14, 2010.

  4. Seminal papers on the interaction between trade and pollution policies include Copeland (1994) and Copeland and Taylor (1995). For a book-length treatment, also see Copeland and Taylor (2003).

  5. The welfare effects of various forms of foreign assistance have been studied extensively. Foreign aid can be unconditional or conditional (tied), and the existing literature differentiates between several different types of the latter form of assistance. Procurement tying—aid conditional on government purchases—is analyzed for instance in Kemp and Kojima (1985), Schweinberger (1990) and Hatzipanayotou and Michael (1995). Policy tying—aid conditional on the implementation of certain policies—is assumed in Lahiri (1997). Project tying—aid destined to finance certain projects—is considered in Schweinberger and Woodland (2008) and Chao and Yu (1999).

  6. See Schweinberger and Woodland (2008), pp. 322–323.

  7. Concrete examples of such projects are particularly numerous in Germany, which generally considers the transfer of technical know-how as a key component of its bilateral development assistance activities. One of the more prominent such ventures is the Profitable Environmental Management Project (PREMA), which has assisted many small and medium-sized companies in developing countries in their efforts to improve their environmental performance. The federally owned German Organization for Technical Cooperation (GTZ) has also provided technical environmental assistance to many developing countries to facilitate the implementation of Rio commitments, the convention on biological diversity (CBD), the convention to combat desertification (CCD), the Montreal protocol, etc. See http://www.un.org/esa/agenda21/natlinfo/countr/germany/eco.htm, accessed August 11, 2010. Also see Schweinberger and Woodland (2008), p. 310 for some additional examples.

  8. As an illustration, Hassler (2002) cites the case of the Swedish environmental assistance granted to other Baltic states such as Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania. Declaratively aimed at addressing general environmental issues of high importance for those countries, the Swedish green aid was disproportionately geared towards transboundary problems such as wastewater treatment, reduction of emissions from point sources and nuclear safety.

  9. It is widely accepted that OECD countries as a whole are net importers of embodied CO\(_{2}\) emissions, while developing countries as a whole are net exporters (e.g. Peters and Hertwich 2008).

  10. Throughout the paper, superscripts denote variable names and subscripts denote partial derivatives. For comparability, much of our notation throughout follows that of Chao and Yu (1999).

  11. One possibility is that the developing recipient sets its emission tax at a lower level than the developed donor since they weigh the different components of their welfare functions differently: while the donor has a higher marginal willingness to pay for abatement than the recipient, the reverse is true for the marginal utility of income.

  12. When \(\theta =0\) pollution is strictly local, and when \(0<\theta \le 1\) we are dealing with regional/global pollution.

  13. We thank the editor for this point.

  14. This assumption is in line with other papers such as Eyland and Zaccour (2012), who assume that the level of the BTA—for CO\(_{2}\) in their case—is proportional to the difference between the carbon tax rates of two trading countries.

  15. For model simplicity, public abatement is not an explicit option for the donor. First, polluters in the donor are already internalizing all self-produced pollution. Secondly, public clean-up of transboundary pollution is indirect and would be difficult to implement (e.g. acid rain).

  16. When \(\alpha =0\), the BTA is absorbed by the donor and it does not affect the recipient export price (i.e. donor is ‘very small’), and when \(\alpha =1\) the BTA is entirely absorbed by the recipient and it does not affect the donor import price (i.e. donor is ‘very large’).

  17. More details about the properties of \(c^{g}\Big ( w\left( p,t\right) , A\Big )\) are given in Appendix  .

  18. For more details about the properties of \(R\left( p,t,g\right) \), see Appendix .

  19. As emphasized by Brett and Keen (2000) as well as Schweinberger and Woodland (2008), this assumption is supported by substantial empirical evidence.

  20. Note that we can also have \(R_{tg}<0\) if the reverse holds.

  21. One can also have \(E_{pz}\le 0\) (\(E_{pz}^{*}\le 0\)) if good \(x\) and pollution are substitutes.

  22. Note that this assumption implies that \(C_{A}(=-R_{gA})\) is constant.

References

  • Abe K (1992) Tariff reform in a small open economy with public production. Int Econ Rev 33(1):133–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brett C, Keen M (2000) Political uncertainty and the earmarking of environmental taxes. J Public Econ 75(3):315–340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chao C-C, Yu ES (1999) Foreign aid, the environment, and welfare. J Dev Econ 59(2):553–564

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Copeland BR (1994) International trade and the environment: policy reform in a polluted small open economy. J Environ Econ Manag 26(1):44–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Copeland BR, Taylor MS (1995) Trade and transboundary pollution. Am Econ Rev 85(4):716–737

    Google Scholar 

  • Copeland BR, Taylor MS (2003) Trade and the environment: theory and evidence. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • de Cendra J (2006) Can emissions trading schemes be coupled with border tax adjustments? An analysis vis-a-vis WTO law. Rev Eur Comp Int Environ Law 15(2):131–145

  • Dissou Y, Eyland T (2011) Carbon control policies, competitiveness, and border tax adjustments. Energy Econ 33(3):556–564

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eyland T, Zaccour G (2012) Strategic effects of a border tax adjustment. Int Game Theory Rev 14(03): 1250016. doi:10.1142/S0219198912500168

  • Fischer C, Fox AK (2012) Comparing policies to combat emissions leakage: border carbon adjustments versus rebates. J Environ Econ Manag Elsevier 64(2):199–216

  • Ghosh M, Luo D, Siddiqui MS, Zhu Y (2012) Border tax adjustments in the climate policy context: CO\(_{2}\) versus broad-based GHG emission targeting. Energy Econ 34(S2):s154–s167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goh G (2004). The world trade organization, Kyoto and energy tax adjustments at the border. J World Trade, 38(3), 395–423

  • Haibara T (2009) Environmental funds, public abatement, and welfare. Environ Resour Econ 44(2):167–177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haibara T (2002) A note on technical assistance and the environment. Indian Econ Rev 37(2):175–182

    Google Scholar 

  • Hassler B (2002) Foreign assistance as a policy instrument. Cooper Confl 37(1):25–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks R, Parks B, Roberts J, Tierney M (2008) Greening aid? Understanding the environmental impact of development assistance. Oxford University Press, Oxford

  • Hufbauer GC, Kim, J (2009) Climate policy options and the world trade organization. Economics 3(29):1–15. (The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal, Kiel Institute for the World Economy)

  • ICTSD (2011) EU climate policies and developing country trade vulnerability: an overview of carbon leakage-sensitive trade flows. In: Transition to a low carbon future series, issue paper no. 19, International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development, Geneva, Switzerland, www.ictsd.org

  • Kemp MC, Kojima S (1985) Tied aid and the paradoxes of donor-enrichment and recipient-impoverishment. Int Econ Rev 26(3):721–729

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lahiri S, Raimondos-Møller P (1997) On the tying of aid to tariff reform. J Dev Econ 54(2):479–491

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hatzipanayotou P, Michael S (1995) Foreign aid and public goods. J Dev Econ Elsevier 47(2):455–467

  • Hatzipanayotou P, Lahiri S, Michael MS (2002) Can cross-border pollution reduce pollution? Can J Econ 35(4):805–818

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hatzipanayotou P, Lahiri S, Michael M (2008) Cross-border pollution, terms of trade, and welfare. Environ Resour Econ 41(3):327–345

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2010) International development statistics, development assistance committee (DAC), http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/50/17/5037721.htm

  • Peters GP, Hertwich EG (2008) CO2 embodied in international trade with implications for global climate policy. Environ Sci Technol 42(5):1401–1407

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roberts JT, Parks CT, Tierney MJ, Hicks RL (2009) Had Foreign Aid Been Greened? Environ: Sci Policy Sustain Dev 51(1):8–21

  • Schweinberger AG (1990) On the welfare effects of tied aid. Int Econ Rev 31(2):457–462

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schweinberger A, Woodland A (2008) The short and long run effects of tied foreign aid on pollution abatement, pilot model. J Environ Econ Manag 55(3):310–325

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turunen-Red AH, Woodland AD (2004) Multilateral reforms of trade and environmental policy. Rev Int Econ 12(3):321–336

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • UNCED (1992) The Rio declaration on environment and development. In: United Nations Conference on Environment and Development (UNCED) Chapter 33, Rio de Janeiro (2002)

  • UNFCCC (2009) Report of the conference of the parties on its fifteenth session. In: United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC), Copenhagen

  • Yomogida M, Tarui N (2011) Emission taxes and border adjustments for oligopolistic industries. University of Hawaii

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Horatiu A. Rus.

Additional information

We are grateful to James Amegashie, Hassan Benchekroun, Joel Bruneau, Joan Canton, Ujjayant Chakravorty, Martin Farnham, Pierre Lasserre, Andrew Leach, Justin Leroux, Ngo Van Long, Carol McAusland, and two anonymous referees for insightful comments and suggestions. We also thank participants at the 2010 CEA conference, the 2010 CREE workshop, the 2011 Montreal Natural Resources and Environmental Economics workshop, as well as seminar participants from the Economics departments at the University of Alberta and Brock University, for valuable comments. We take responsibility for all remaining errors.

Appendices

Appendix 1

1.1 Properties of the Public Abatement Cost Function \(c^{g}\Big ( w\left( p,t\right) , A\Big )\)

Following Hatzipanayotou and Michael (1995), the \(c^{g}\Big ( w\left( p,t\right) , A\Big )\) function is concave, and homogeneous of degree one in \(w\), i.e: (i) \(c_{w}^{g}w=c^{g}\) ; (ii) \(c_{ww}^{g}w=0\).

1.2 Properties of the Revenue Function \(R\left( p,t,g\right) \)

Following Abe (1992) and Hatzipanayotou and Michael (1995), and using the properties of the \(c^{g}\Big ( w\left( p,t\right) , A\Big )\) function as well as our assumption that the production of good \(x\) and public abatement of pollution compete for the same factors of production, the \(R\left( p,t,g\right) \) function has the following properties: (i) \(R_{p}=x\) ; (ii) \(R_{t}=-z\) ; (iii) \(R_{g}=-c^{g}\) ; (iv) \(R_{pp}>0\) ; (v) \(R_{pt}<0\) ; (vi) \(R_{pg}=-c_{p}^{g}< 0\); (vii) \(R_{tg}=-c_{t}^{g}> 0\); (viii) \(R_{gg}=0\).

Appendix 2

1.1 Derivation of Expression (12)

Totally differentiating (11), and assuming that third derivatives of the revenue and expenditure functions are zero,Footnote 22 we get:

$$\begin{aligned}&c_{A}^{g}dA+\left[ \theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zp}^{*}-R_{gp}\right] dp \nonumber \\&\quad +\left[ \theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) \left( E_{z}^{*}-\tau E_{pz}^{*}\right) c_{A}^{g}-\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zz}^{*}-R_{gg}\right] dg \nonumber \\&\quad +\left[ \theta \left( 1-\alpha \right) \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zp}^{*}+\alpha R_{gp}-\theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{pz}^{*}\right] d\tau \nonumber \\&\quad +\,\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zz}^{*}dz+\theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*}du^{*}=0 \end{aligned}$$
(18)

Substituting (2), (9), and (11) into (18), we get the following expression:

$$\begin{aligned}&\left[ \begin{array}{c} c_{A}^{g}-\frac{\theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*}}{\left( 1-\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}\right) } \\ -\left[ \begin{array}{c} \theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) \left( E_{z}^{*}-\tau E_{pz}^{*}\right) c_{A}^{g}-\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) ^{2}gc_{A}^{g}E_{zz}^{*} \\ -R_{gg}+\frac{\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) ^{2}gc_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*}\left( E_{z}^{*}-\tau E_{pz}^{*}\right) }{\left( 1-\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}\right) } \end{array} \right] \frac{gc_{A}^{g}}{c^{g}+tR_{tg}} \end{array} \right] dA \nonumber \\&\quad +\left[ \begin{array}{c} \theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zp}^{*}-R_{gp}-\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zz}^{*}R_{tp} \\ -\frac{\theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*}\left[ E_{p}^{*}-R_{p}^{*}-\tau \left( E_{pp}^{*}-R_{pp}^{*}\right) +\theta \left( \tau E_{pz}^{*}-E_{z}^{*}\right) R_{tp}\right] }{ \left( 1-\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}\right) } \\ -\left[ \begin{array}{c} \theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) \left( E_{z}^{*}-\tau E_{pz}^{*}\right) c_{A}^{g}-\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zz}^{*}-R_{gg} \\ -\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zz}^{*}R_{tg} \\ +\frac{\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) ^{2}gc_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*}\left( E_{z}^{*}-\tau E_{pz}^{*}\right) }{\left( 1-\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}\right) } \end{array} \right] \frac{tR_{tp}+gc_{p}^{g}}{c^{g}+tR_{tg}} \end{array} \right] dp \nonumber \\&\quad +\left[ \begin{array}{c} R_{tg}-R_{gt} \\ -\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zz}^{*}R_{tt} \\ +\frac{\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*}\left( E_{z}^{*}-\tau E_{pz}^{*}\right) R_{tt}}{\left( 1-\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}\right) } \\ -\left[ \begin{array}{c} \theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) \left( E_{z}^{*}-\tau E_{pz}^{*}\right) c_{A}^{g}-\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zz}^{*}-R_{gg} \\ -\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zz}^{*}R_{tg} \\ +\frac{\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) ^{2}gc_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*}\left( E_{z}^{*}-\tau E_{pz}^{*}\right) }{\left( 1-\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}\right) } \end{array} \right] \frac{R_{t}+tR_{tt}+gc_{t}^{g}}{c^{g}+tR_{tg}} \end{array} \!\!\right] dt \nonumber \\&\quad +\left[ \begin{array}{c} \theta \left( 1-\alpha \right) \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zp}^{*}+\alpha R_{gp}-\theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{pz}^{*} \\ +\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zz}^{*}\alpha R_{tp} \\ +\frac{\theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*}\left[ \alpha \left( E_{p}^{*}-R_{p}^{*}\right) +\left( 1-\alpha \right) \tau \left( E_{pp}^{*}-R_{pp}^{*}\right) +\theta \left( \tau E_{pz}^{*}-E_{z}^{*}\right) \alpha R_{tp}\right] }{\left( 1-\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}\right) } \\ +\left[ \begin{array}{c} \theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) \left( E_{z}^{*}-\tau E_{pz}^{*}\right) c_{A}^{g}-\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zz}^{*} \\ -R_{gg}-\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zz}^{*}R_{tg} \\ +\frac{\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) ^{2}gc_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*}\left( E_{z}^{*}-\tau E_{pz}^{*}\right) }{\left( 1-\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}\right) } \end{array} \right] \frac{\alpha \left( tR_{tp}+gc_{p}^{g}\right) }{c^{g}+tR_{tg}} \end{array} \right] d\tau =0\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(19)

Given that \(R_{t}+tR_{tt}+gc_{t}^{g}=0\) and \(tR_{tp}+gc_{p}^{g}=0\) from (1), and after some simplifications, (20) is also equivalent to

$$\begin{aligned}&\left[ \begin{array}{c} c_{A}^{g}-\frac{\theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*}}{\left( 1-\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}\right) } \nonumber \\ -\left[ \begin{array}{c} \theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) \left( E_{z}^{*}-\tau E_{pz}^{*}\right) c_{A}^{g}-\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) ^{2}gc_{A}^{g}E_{zz}^{*} \\ -R_{gg}+\frac{\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) ^{2}gc_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*}\left( E_{z}^{*}-\tau E_{pz}^{*}\right) }{\left( 1-\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}\right) } \end{array} \right] \frac{gc_{A}^{g}}{c^{g}+tR_{tg}} \end{array} \right] dA \nonumber \\&\quad +\left[ \begin{array}{c} \theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zp}^{*}-R_{gp}-\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zz}^{*}R_{tp} \\ -\frac{\theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*}\left[ E_{p}^{*}-R_{p}^{*}-\tau \left( E_{pp}^{*}-R_{pp}^{*}\right) +\theta \left( \tau E_{pz}^{*}-E_{z}^{*}\right) R_{tp}\right] }{ \left( 1-\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}\right) } \end{array} \right] dp \nonumber \\&\quad +\left[ \begin{array}{c} \theta \left( 1-\alpha \right) \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zp}^{*}+\alpha R_{gp}-\theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{pz}^{*} \\ +\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zz}^{*}\alpha R_{tp} \\ +\frac{\theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*}\left[ \alpha \left( E_{p}^{*}-R_{p}^{*}\right) +\left( 1-\alpha \right) \tau \left( E_{pp}^{*}-R_{pp}^{*}\right) +\theta \left( \tau E_{pz}^{*}-E_{z}^{*}\right) \alpha R_{tp}\right] }{\left( 1-\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}\right) } \end{array} \right] d\tau \nonumber \\&\quad +\left[ \begin{array}{c} R_{tg}-R_{gt} \\ -\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zz}^{*}R_{tt} \\ +\frac{\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*}\left( E_{z}^{*}-\tau E_{pz}^{*}\right) R_{tt}}{\left( 1-\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}\right) } \end{array} \right] dt=0 \end{aligned}$$
(20)

From (20) and given that \(t\) and \(p\) are independent on \(\tau \), we can derive the following expression of the effect of a change in \(\tau \) on \(A\):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dA}{d\tau }&= \frac{N^{A}}{D^{A}}\nonumber \\&= \frac{\left[ \begin{array}{c} -\alpha \theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zp}^{*}+\alpha R_{gp} \\ +\frac{\theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*}\left[ \alpha \left( E_{p}^{*}-R_{p}^{*}\right) +\left( 1-\alpha \right) \tau \left( E_{pp}^{*}-R_{pp}^{*}\right) +\theta \left( \tau E_{pz}^{*}-E_{z}^{*}\right) \alpha R_{tp}\right] }{\left( 1-\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}\right) } \\ +\alpha \theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zz}^{*}R_{tp} \end{array} \right] }{\left[ \begin{array}{c} -c_{A}^{g}+\frac{\theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*}}{\left( 1-\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}\right) } \\ +\left[ \begin{array}{c} \theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) \left( E_{z}^{*}-\tau E_{pz}^{*}\right) c_{A}^{g}-\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) ^{2}gc_{A}^{g}E_{zz}^{*} \\ -R_{gg}+\frac{\theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) ^{2}gc_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*}\left( E_{z}^{*}-\tau E_{pz}^{*}\right) }{\left( 1-\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}\right) } \end{array} \right] \frac{gc_{A}^{g}}{c^{g}+tR_{tg}} \end{array} \right] }\qquad \quad \end{aligned}$$
(21)

Substituting (11) in the numerator (\(N^{A}\)) and denominator (\(D^{A}\)) of the above expression, and given that \(c^{g}+tR_{tg}-gR_{gg}=0\) from (1), we get expression (12) after factoring \(N^{A}\) for \(\alpha \).

Appendix 3

Proof of Proposition 1

To appraise the effect of the BTA on \(A\), it is necessary to determine the signs of the numerator and the denominator, i.e. the signs of \(N^A\) and \(D^A\). From (13), we can show that \(N^A=\) \(\alpha -\overline{\alpha ^A }\), with

$$\begin{aligned} \overline{\alpha ^A }=\frac{\theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*}\tau \left( E_{pp}^{*}-R_{pp}^{*}\right) }{\left( \tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}-1\right) \left[ \begin{array}{c} \theta ^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zz}^{*}R_{tp}-\theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zp}^{*} +tR_{tp}\left( \frac{1}{g}+\frac{\theta E_{zu^{*}}^{*}R_{tg}}{1-\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}}\right) \\ +\frac{\theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) gc_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*}}{ \left( 1-\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}\right) }\left[ \left( E_{p}^{*}-R_{p}^{*}\right) -\tau \left( E_{pp}^{*}-R_{pp}^{*}\right) + \frac{R_{tp}c^{g}}{gc_{A}^{g}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) }\right] \end{array} \right] }. \end{aligned}$$

From our assumptions, we know that \(R_{tg}>0,\, c_{A}<0\), \(E_{zu^{*}}>0,\, R_{tp}<0,\, E_{p}^{*}-R_{p}^{*}>0\), \(E_{pp}^{*}<0\), \(R_{pp}^{*}>0\), \(E_{zz}^{*}>0\), and \(E_{zp}^{*}\geqslant 0\). When \(\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}>1\) and \( \theta >\overline{\theta }\) with \(\overline{\theta }=\frac{\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}-1}{gE_{zu^{*}}^{*}R_{tg}}\), it directly follows that \(\overline{\alpha ^A }>0\). Therefore, it is straightforward to show that \(N^A\gtrless 0\) when \(\alpha \gtrless \overline{\alpha ^A }\). It also follows from our assumptions that \(D^A\gtrless 0\) if \(\left| c_{A}^{g}\right| \lessgtr \overline{c}\), with \(\overline{c}=\frac{ 3\left( c^{g}+tR_{tg}\right) }{\theta ^{2}g^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) ^{2}E_{zz}^{*}}\).

\(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 1

From (15), we can show that \(N^{e}=\) \(\alpha -\overline{\alpha ^{e}}\), with

$$\begin{aligned} \overline{\alpha ^{e}}\!=\!\frac{\theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) ^{2}g^{2}c_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*}\tau \left( E_{pp}^{*}-R_{pp}^{*}\right) }{\left( \tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}\!-\!1\right) \left[ \! \begin{array}{c} -3R_{tp}\left( c^{g}+tR_{tg}\right) -\theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) ^{2}g^{2}c_{A}^{g}E_{zp}^{*} +tR_{tp}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) \left( 1+\frac{\theta E_{zu^{*}}^{*}R_{tg}g}{1-\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}}\right) \\ +\frac{\theta \left( R_{tg}+1\right) ^{2}g^{2}c_{A}^{g}E_{zu^{*}}^{*} }{\left( 1-\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}\right) }\left[ \left( E_{p}^{*}-R_{p}^{*}\right) -\tau \left( E_{pp}^{*}-R_{pp}^{*}\right) + \frac{R_{tp}c^{g}}{gc_{A}^{g}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) }\right] \end{array} \!\right] } \end{aligned}$$

Under the assumptions highlighted in Lemma 1, it straightforward to see that \(\overline{\alpha ^{e}}>0\) when \(\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}>1\) and \(\theta >\overline{\theta }\), with \(\overline{\theta }=\frac{\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}-1}{gE_{zu^{*}}^{*}R_{tg}}\). Therefore, we have \(N^{e}\gtrless 0\) when \(\alpha \gtrless \overline{\alpha ^{e}}\). Under the same assumptions as in the proof of Proposition 1, it also directly follows that \( D^{e}\gtrless 0\) if \(\left| c_{A}^{g}\right| \gtrless \overline{c}\) with \(\overline{c}= \frac{ 3\left( c^{g}+tR_{tg}\right) }{\theta ^{2}g^{2}\left( R_{tg}+1\right) ^{2}E_{zz}^{*}}\).\(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 2

From (14), it is straightforward to see that we always have \(\frac{de}{d\tau }<0\) if \(\frac{dA}{d\tau }>0\). The table below combines the conditions that determine the signs of \(\frac{de}{d\tau }\), \(\frac{dA}{d\tau }\) and \(\frac{dg}{d\tau }\) when \(\frac{dA}{d\tau }<0\) and \(\frac{dg}{d\tau }<0\), as summarized in Proposition 1 and Lemma 1 respectively.

\(\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}>1;\, \theta >\overline{\theta };\, \alpha >\overline{\alpha }\); and \(\left| c_{A}^{g}\right| >\overline{c}\)

\(\tau E_{pu^{*}}^{*}>1;\, \theta >\overline{\theta };\, \alpha <\overline{\alpha }\); and \(\left| c_{A}^{g}\right| <\overline{c}\)

\(\frac{dA}{d\tau }<0\) and \(\frac{dg}{d\tau }<0\)

\(\frac{dA}{d\tau }<0\) and \(\frac{dg}{d\tau }<0\)

\(\overline{\alpha ^{e}}>\overline{\alpha }\)

\(\overline{\alpha ^{e}}< \overline{\alpha }\)

\(\overline{\alpha ^{e}}>\alpha >\overline{\alpha }\) or \(\alpha >\overline{ \alpha ^{e}}>\overline{\alpha }\)

\(\alpha <\overline{\alpha ^{e}}<\overline{ \alpha }\) or \(\overline{\alpha ^{e}}<\alpha <\overline{\alpha }\)

\(\overline{\alpha ^{e}}>\alpha \) or \(\alpha >\overline{\alpha ^{e}}\)

\( \alpha <\overline{\alpha ^{e}}\) or \(\overline{\alpha ^{e}}<\alpha \)

\(\frac{de}{d\tau }<0\) or \(\frac{de}{d\tau }>0\)

\(\frac{de}{d\tau }>0\) or \( \frac{de}{d\tau }<0\)

From this table, we can directly show that \(\frac{de}{d\tau }> 0\) if \(\alpha >\overline{\alpha ^{e}}>\overline{\alpha }\) or \(\alpha <\overline{\alpha ^{e}}<\overline{\alpha }\), and that \(\frac{de}{d\tau }< 0\) if \(\overline{\alpha ^{e}}>\alpha >\overline{\alpha }\) or \(\overline{\alpha ^{e}}<\alpha <\overline{\alpha }\). \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Nimubona, AD., Rus, H.A. Green Technology Transfers and Border Tax Adjustments. Environ Resource Econ 62, 189–206 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-014-9821-9

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-014-9821-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation