Skip to main content
Log in

Comparing Regulations to Protect the Commons: An Experimental Investigation

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In a laboratory experiment we test three regulations imposed on a common-pool resource game with heterogeneous users: an access fee and subsidy scheme, transferable quotas and non-transferable quotas. We calibrate the game so that all regulations improve users’ profits compared to free-access extraction. We compare the regulations according to five criteria: resource preservation, individual profits, profit difference, Pareto-improvement from free-access and sorting of the most efficient users. One of the main findings is that, even though it performs better in sorting out the most efficient subjects, the fee and subsidy scheme is not more profitable than tradable quotas.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Ellerman et al. (2010) for evidence of price volatility on the CO2 emission allowances system in Europe and Grafton et al. (2011) on water price variability among users.

  2. Apesteguia (2006) studied behavioral consequences of two degrees of information on CPR (complete vs. incomplete information) and found that information does not alter behaviors, i.e., both levels of information lead to the convergence of the aggregate effort towards the Nash equilibrium.

  3. This repeated “Partners” design is more realistic as agents share common pool resources repeatedly. Moreover, with two groups per session, we double the number of independent observations compared to a “Strangers” design.

  4. A special feature of CPRs is that by investing \(x\) units of extracting effort, an individual obtains a share \(\frac{x}{X}\) of total extraction (or harvest) \(X\phi (X)\). The linear form \(a-bX\) is standard in CPR experiments (Janssen and Ostrom 2006).

  5. As pointed out above, our intension is not to test behaviors in the FA regime but rather to assess the performance of regulations in improving welfare from a non-cooperative equilibrium of the FA benchmark. That is why we set up quite a straightforward benchmark game.

  6. Since the average product \(\phi (X)\) is decreasing with CPR extraction \(X\), the return on the CPR \(\phi (X)\) is always lower than on the outside option \(c_i\) for player of type \(i=A,B\) for any \(X \le 32\).

  7. Note that the first best CPR extraction level is \(X=12\). Implementing the first-best would require one to assign \(1.5\) quota units to each subject and, therefore, to divide the quotas.

  8. Due to the lump-sum nature of \((\tau ,\sigma )\), all other incentive-compatibility constraints can be ignored. By the other incentive-compatible constraints, we mean those that prevent any player from investing only part of his or her endowment in the CPR, rather than all (for types \(A\)) or nothing (for types \(B\)).

  9. Recall that the TQ game is dynamic since it involves two decisions in turn: a strategy in the quota market and an investment decision. Given the market equilibrium outcome, the investment strategy described is a Nash equilibrium of the investment subgame. In the previous market stage, given the selling and buying strategy of the other players, a type \(A\) (resp. type B) player’s best response is to buy (resp. to sell) 2 quotas.

  10. Ambec and Sebi (2011) provide a more complete theoretical comparison of all three instruments, including the Pareto-improvement criteria and fairness considerations.

  11. When the number of bids differs from the number of asks, the bidders or sellers not supplied are determined randomly.

  12. Based on the estimated coefficients for model (1), the predicted Nash deviation in absolute value for period 5 is 0.5 compared to 0.42 for period 7. At the first period it is equal to 0.9.

  13. We have also considered some other specifications of the model including higher lags (\(T=2, 3\)) and the strategy used each player in the previous period. Results are consistent with the ones presented in Table 2.

  14. Subjects do not seek the social optimum which is obtained in our setup when the four players \(A\) extract at their maximum capacity and when the four players \(B\) extract one unit each: only 3 % of players \(B\) extract fewer than 2 units.

  15. Consequent to the results of the learning equation estimates in the previous section, we performed the Wilcoxon signed rank tests without taking into account the first three periods. The results stress the ones that we report with 7 periods: \(p \ge 0.1439\) for NTQ and FS, \(p \ge 0.6246\) for NTQ and TQ and \(p \ge 0.1214\) for FS and TQ.

  16. We get a pseudo \(\mathrm{R}^2\) equal to 0.2 which corresponds to a relatively poor predictive power of the logit model. However, at a probability cutoff equal to 0.50, 74 % of the subjects are well classified by the model.

  17. These results are robust even if we exclude the first periods for which the learning effect has been shown to be strong. For instance, if we restrict the sample to periods 3–7, we obtain some estimated coefficients for \(TYPE_B\) and \(TREAT_{FS}\) significant at 1 % and respectively equal to 0.244 and 1.661.

References

  • Ambec S, Sebi C (2011) The distributional impact of common-pool resource regulations. Indian Growth Dev Rev 4:123–141

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Apesteguia J (2006) Does information matter in the commons? Experimental evidence. J Econ Behav Organ 60:55–69

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burtraw D (2000) Innovation under the tradable sulfur dioxide emission permits program in the U.S. electricity sector. Discussion Paper 00–38, Resources for the Future (RFF), Washington

  • Camerer CF (2003) Behavioral game theory-experiments in strategic interaction. New York/Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey

    Google Scholar 

  • Casari M, Plott CR (2003) Decentralized management of common property resources: an experiment with a centuries-old institution. J Econ Behav Organ 51:217–247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cason T, Plott CR (1996) EPA’s new emissions trading mechanism: a laboratory evaluation. J Environ Econ Manag 30:133–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cason TN, Gangadharan L, Duke C (2003) A laboratory study of auctions for reducing non-point source pollution. J Environ Econ Manag 46:446–471

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cochard F, Willinger M, Xepapadeas A (2005) Efficiency of nonpoint source pollution instruments: an experimental study. Environ Resour Econ 30:393–422

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz H (1967) Toward a theory of property rights. Am Econ Rev 57:347–359

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellerman AD, Convery FJ, de Perthuis C (2010) Pricing carbon: the European emissions trading scheme. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman D, Sunder S (1994) Experimental economics: a primer for economists. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg D, Levine D (1998) The theory of learning in games. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Giordana G, Willinger M (2013) Fixed instruments to cope with stock externalities: an experimental evaluation. In: List JA Price MK (eds) Handbook on experimental economics and the environment. Edward Elgar, pp 367–403

  • Gordon HS (1954) The econominc theory of a common property resource: the fishery. J Political Econ 62:124–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grafton RQ, Landry C, Libecap GD, McGlennon S, Ó Brien B (2011) An integrated assessment of water markets: a cross-country comparison. Rev Environ Econ Policy 5:219–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grafton RQ, Nelson HW (2005) The effects of buy-back programs in the British Columbia salmon fishery. Austrial National University, Working Paper

  • Grafton RQ, Ward MB (2008) Prices versus rationing: Marshallian surplus and mandatory water restrictions. Econ Rec 84:57–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hannesson R (2004a) Buy-back Program for fishing vessels in Norway. Working Paper, Center for Fisheries Economics, Bergen

  • Hannesson R (2004b) The privatization of the oceans. The MIT Press, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardin G (1968) The tragedy of the commons. Science 162:1243–1248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herr A, Gardner R, Walker JM (1997) An experimental study of time-independant and time-dependant externalities in the commons. Games Econ Behav 19:77–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Janssen MA, Ostrom E (2006) Governing social ecological systems. Handb Comput Econ 30:1465–1509

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson LT, Rutstrom EE, George JG (2006) Income distributrion preferences and regulatory change in social dilemmas. J Econ Behav Organ 61:181–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mason CF, Phillips OR (1997) Mitigating the tragedy of the commons through cooperation: an experimental evaluation. J Environ Econ Manag 34:148–172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mookherjee D, Sopher B (1994) Learning behavior in an experimental matching pennies game. Games Econ Behav 7:62–91

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oses-Eraso N, Udina F, Viladrich-Grau M (2008) Environemental versus human-induced scarcity in the commons: is our response the same? Environ Resour Econ 40:529–550

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E (1990) Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E (2006) The value-added of laboratory experiments for the study of institutions and common-pool resources. J Econ Behav Organ 2:149–163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plott CR (1983) Externalities and corrective policies in experimental markets. Econ J 93:106–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schott S, Buckley N, Mestelman S, Muller RA (2007) Output sharing in partnerships as a common pool resource management instrument. Environ Resour Econ 37:697–711

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walker JM, Gardner R, Herr A, Ostrom E (2000) Collective choice in the commons: experimental result on proposed allocation rules and votes. Econ J 110:212–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Stefan Ambec.

Additional information

We wish to thank Jean-Loup Dupuis for technical assistance with the computer laboratory and Liz Libbrecht for editorial assistance. We thank the Editor and two anonymous referees for useful suggestions that improved the paper. We also acknowledge the participants in various conferences (including EAERE 2008) and seminars for comments. This research received financial support from the French National Research Agency through the project ANR-08-JCJC-0111-01.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 150 KB)

Appendices

Appendix 1: Experimental Design

See Tables 7, 8 and 9.

Table 7 Treatment order

Appendix 2: General Data

Table 8 Average CPR extraction, profit and profit improvement frequency

Appendix 3: Tables in the Instructions

Table 9 Payoff matrix of player

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ambec, S., Garapin, A., Muller, L. et al. Comparing Regulations to Protect the Commons: An Experimental Investigation. Environ Resource Econ 58, 219–244 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-013-9700-9

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-013-9700-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation