Skip to main content
Log in

Willingness to Pay and Sensitivity to Time Framing: A Theoretical Analysis and an Application on Car Safety

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

An Erratum to this article was published on 19 October 2013

Abstract

Stated preference (SP) surveys attempt to obtain monetary values for non-market goods that reflect individuals’ “true” preferences. Numerous empirical studies suggest that monetary values from SP studies are sensitive to survey design and so may not reflect respondents’ true preferences. This study examines the effect of time framing on respondents’ willingness to pay (WTP) for car safety. We explore how WTP per unit risk reduction depends on the time period over which respondents pay and face reduced risk in a theoretical model and by using data from a Swedish contingent valuation survey. Our theoretical model predicts the effect to be nontrivial in many scenarios used in empirical applications. In our empirical analysis we examine the sensitivity of WTP to an annual and a monthly scenario. Our theoretical model predicts the effect from the time framing to be negligible, but the empirical estimates from the annual scenario are about 70 % higher than estimates from the monthly scenario.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The pilot, a postal questionnaire, was sent to 202 randomly chosen individuals, out of whom 91 returned completed questionnaires (44.1 % response rate). The sample for the pilot was split into two groups; one received questions on food and car safety, the other only on food safety. The objective was to test if the survey length had a negative effect on the response rate. We did not find any evidence of that, in fact, the response rate was slightly higher in the group who had to answer the longer questionnaire, 45.4 against 42.9 %. For a fuller description of the survey and the subgroups, see Sundström and Andersson (2009).

  2. The lottery ticket had the effect that some empty questionnaires were returned, 103 in the main survey and 8 in the pilot. (Empty questionnaire not included in response rates reported here.) All prices are in 2006 price level. USD 1 = SEK 7.38 (www.riksbank.se, 2/11/2008)

  3. Due to the postal format we could not control how the respondents answered the survey. It was, therefore, possible for respondents to answer the wrong follow-up questions (e.g. answering the follow-up question to an initial no answer, after stating that they were willing to pay the initial bid).

  4. Since we use standard and well known estimation techniques, this section has been kept to a minimum. For readers interested in more detailed descriptions of the models and techniques we recommend Bateman et al. (2002) or Haab and McConnell (2003).

  5. The Turnbull lower bound estimator is also known as the Kaplan–Meier estimator (Carson and Hanemann 2005).

  6. We used a conversion criterion equal to 0.005.

  7. The mixture model is discussed in the “Appendix”.

  8. Respondents’ perception on their mortality risk has been analyzed in Andersson (2011).

  9. Results from the DB format available upon request from the authors. With the exception of scale sensitivity, which is weaker and statistically insignificant in all three regressions with the DB format, qualitatively the results are identical between the two formats.

  10. In the lognormal model, the coefficient of \(\ln (\Delta p)\) is slightly smaller and not significant, and the coefficient of Year is significant at 10 % in one regression.

  11. A validity test of CVM studies with dichotomous choice questions is that the coefficient of the bid is negative and statistically significant, i.e. respondents should be less likely to accept the bid when the bid is higher. Regression with the bid and the same covariates as in Table 5 on the probability of accepting the bid showed that the bid coefficient was negative and highly significant (\(p<0.01\)) in all regressions.

  12. Johannesson et al. (1996) found that WTP was statistically significantly higher among females for a public good, but not for a private good.

  13. Household income per consumption unit is calculated by dividing total household income by the weighted sum of household members, where the weights are based on age and are from Statistics Sweden. The weights depend on the composition of the household and are smaller for younger than for older children.

  14. Respondents were asked in a follow-up question whether they found the scenario realistic. Close to 38 % of the respondents stated that they did not find the scenario realistic. We decided to include these respondents in our analysis since we have no information whether stating that the scenario was unrealistic suggests that they took the survey more or less seriously than those who stated that it was realistic. The distribution of respondents who found it realistic was nearly identical between the annual and monthly subsamples.

  15. All values in 2006 price level in this paragraph.

  16. Corresponding estimates for a public good risk reductions were SEK 20.46 and 36.64 million.

References

  • Alberini A (1995) Efficiency vs bias of willingness-to-pay estimates: bivaraite and interval-data models. J Environ Econ Manag 29:169–180

    Google Scholar 

  • Alberini A, Cropper M, Krupnick A, Simon NB (2004) Does the value of a statistical life vary with the age and health status? Evidence from the USA and Canada. J Environ Econ Manag 48(1):769–792

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alberini A, Cropper M, Krupnick A, Simon NB (2006a) Willingness to pay for mortality risk reductions: does latency matter? J Risk Uncertain 32(3):231–245

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alberini A, Hunt A, Markandya A (2006b) Willingness to pay to reduce mortality risks: evidence from a three-country contingent valuation study. Environ Resour Econ 33(2):251–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alberini A, Longo A (2009) Valuing the cultural monuments of Armenia: Bayesian updating of prior beliefs in contingent valuation. Environ Plan A 41:441–460

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • An Y, Ayala RA (1996) A mixture model of willingness to pay distributions. Mimeo, USA

  • Andersson H (2005) The value of safety as revealed in the Swedish car market: an application of the hedonic pricing approach. J Risk Uncertain 30(3):211–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersson H (2007) Willingness to pay for road safety and estimates of the risk of death: evidence from a Swedish contingent valuation study. Accid Anal Prev 39(4):853–865

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersson H (2008) Willingness to pay for car safety: evidence from Sweden. Environ Resour Econ 41:579–594

    Google Scholar 

  • Andersson H (2011) Perception of own death risk: an assessment of road-traffic mortality risk. Risk Anal 31(7):1069–1082

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersson H, Svensson M (2008) Cognitive ability and scale bias in the contingent valuation method. Environ Resour Econ 39(4):481–495

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersson H, Treich N (2011) The value of a statistical life. In: de Palma A, Lindsey R, Quinet E, Vickerman R (eds) A handbook of transport economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 396–424

  • Atkinson SE, Halvorsen R (1990) The valuation of risks to life: evidence from the market for automobiles. Rev Econ Stat 72(1):133–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ayer M, Brunk HD, Ewing GM, Reid WT, Silverman E (1955) An empirical distribution function for sampling with incomplete information. Ann Math Stat 26(4):641–647

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bateman IJ, Burgess D, Hutchinson WG, Matthews DI (2008) Learning design contingent valuation (LDCV): NOAA guidelines, preference learning and coherent arbitrariness. J Environ Econ Manag 55:127–141

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bateman IJ, Carson RT, Day B, Hanemann M, Hanley N, Hett T, Jones-Lee M, Loomes G, Mourato S, Özdemiro\({\bar{\text{ g }}}\)lu DW, Pearce R, Sugden Swanson J (2002) Economic valuation with stated preference techniques: a manual. Edward Elgar, UK

  • Beattie J, Covey J, Dolan P, Hopkins L, Jones-Lee MW, Loomes G, Pidgeon N, Robinson A, Spencer A (1998) On the contingent valuation of safety and the safety of contingent valuation: part 1—Caveat investigator. J Risk Uncertain 17(1):5–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blumenschein K, Blomquist GC, Johannesson M, Horn N, Freeman P (2008) Eliciting willingness to pay without bias: evidence from a field experiment. Econ J 118(525):114–137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bond KG, Cullen CA, Larson DM (2009) Joint estimation of discount rates and willingness to pay for public goods. Ecol Econ 68:2751–2759

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyle KJ, Johnson FR, McCollum DW (1997) Anchoring and adjustment in single-bounded, contingent valuation questions. Am J Agric Econ 79(5):1495–1500

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyle KJ, MacDonald HF, Cheng H, McCollum DW (1998) Bid design and yes saying in single-bounded, dichotomous-choice questions. Land Econ 74(1):49–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brooks RG, Jendteg S, Lindgren B, Persson U, Björk S (1991) EuroQol: health-related quality of life measurement. Results of the Swedish Questionnaire Exercise. Health Policy 18:37–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brouwer R, van Beukering P, Sultanian E (2008) The impact of the bird flu on public willingness to pay for the protection of migratory birds. Ecol Econ 64:575–585

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron TA (1988) A new paradigm for valuing non-market goods using referendum data: maximum likelihood estimation by censored logistic regression. J Environ Econ Manag 15:355–379

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carson RT, Conaway MB, Haneman WM, Krosnick JA, Presser S (2004) Valuing Oil spill prevention: a case study of California’s central coast. The economics of non-market goods and resources, vol 5. Kluwer, Dordrecht

  • Carson RT, Hanemann WM (2005) Contingent valuation. In: Mäler K-G, Vincent JR (eds) Handbook of environmental economics: valuing environmental changes. Handbook in economics, vol 2, 1st edn. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 821–936

  • Corso PS, Hammitt JK, Graham JD (2001) Valuing mortality-risk reduction: using visual aids to improve the validity of contingent valuation. J Risk Uncertain 23(2):165–184

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreyfus MK, Viscusi WK (1995) Rates of time preference and consumer valuations of automobile safety and fuel efficiency. J Law Econ 38(1):79–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fieller E (1940) The biological standardization of insulin. Suppl J R Stat Soc 7(1):1–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green D, Jacowitz KE, Kahneman D, McFadden D (1998) Referendum contingent valuation anchoring and willingness to pay for public goods. Resour Energy Econ 20(2):85–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haab TC (1999) Nonparticipation or misspecification? The impacts of nonparticipation on dichotomous choice contingent valuation. Environ Resour Econ 14:443–461

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haab TC, McConnell KE (2003) Valuing environmental and natural resources: the econometrics of non-market valuation. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Hammitt JK (2000) Evaluating contingent valuation of environmental health risks: the proportionality test. Assoc Environ Resour Econ (AERE) Newslett 20(1):14–19

    Google Scholar 

  • Hammitt JK (2002) QALYs versus WTP. Risk Anal 22(5):985–1001

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hammitt JK, Graham JD (1999) Willingness to pay for health protection: inadequate sensitivity to probability? J Risk Uncertain 18(1):33–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hammitt JK, Haninger K (2007) Willingness to pay for food safety: sensitivity to duration and severity of illness. Am J Agric Econ 89(5):1170–1175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanemann WM (1984) Welfare evaluations in contingent valuation experiments with discrete responses. Am J Agric Econ 66(3):332–341

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanemann MW, Loomis J, Kanninen B (1991) Statistical efficiency of double-bounded dichotomous choice contingent valuation. Am J Agric Econ 73(4):1255–1263

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herriges JA, Shogren JF (1996) Starting point bias in dichotomous choice valuation with follow-up questioning. J Environ Econ Manag 30:112–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hultkrantz L, Lindberg G, Andersson C (2006) The value of improved road safety. J Risk Uncertain 32(2): 151–170

    Google Scholar 

  • Irwin JR, Sloviv P, Lichtenstein S, McClelland GH (1993) Preference reversals and the measurement of environmental values. J Risk Uncertain 6:5–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johannesson M, Johansson P-O, O’Connor RM (1996) The value of private safety versus the value of public safety. J Risk Uncertain 13(3):263–275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johannesson M, Johansson P-O, Lövgren K-G (1997) On the value of changes in life expectancy: blips versus parametric changes. J Risk Uncertain 15(3):221–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansson P-O (2002) On the definition and age-dependency of the value of a statistical life. J Risk Uncertain 25(3):251–263

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones-Lee MW (1974) The value of changes in the probability of death or injury. J Polit Econ 82(4):835–849

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones-Lee MW, Hammerton M, Philips P (1985) The value of safety: results of a national sample survey. Econ J 95(377):49–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Knetsch JL (1992) Valuing public goods: the purchase of moral satisfaction. J Environ Econ Manag 22(1):57–70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47(2): 263–291

    Google Scholar 

  • Kanninen BJ (1995) Bias in discrete response contingent valuation. J Environ Econ Manag 28:114–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim S-I, Haab TC (2009) Temporal insensitivity of willingness to pay and implied discount rates. Resour Energy Econ 31:89–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koltowska-Häggström M, Jonsson B, Isacson D, Bingefors K (2007) Using EQ-5D to derive utilities for the quality of life—assessment of growth hormone deficiency in adults (QoL–AGHDA). Value Health 10(1):73–81

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kovacs KF, Larson DM (2008) Identifying individual discount rates and valuing public open space with stated-preference models. Land Econ 84(2):209–224

    Google Scholar 

  • Krupnick A (2007) Mortality risk valuation and age: stated preference evidence. Rev Environ Econ Policy 1(2):261–282

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krupnick A, Alberini A, Cropper M, Simon NB, O’Brian B, Goeree R, Heintselman M (2002) Age, health and the willingness to pay for mortality risk reductions: a contingent valuation survey of Ontario residents. J Risk Uncertain 24(2):161–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krupnick A, Hoffmann S, Larsen B, Peng X, Tao R, Yan C (2006) The willingness to pay for mortality risk reductions in Shanghai and Chongqing, China. Technical report. Resources for the Future, Washington, DC

  • NOAA (1993) Report of the NOAA panel on contingent valuation. Feder Regist 58:2478–2536

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson U, Norinder A, Hjalte K, Gralén K (2001) The value of a statistical life in transport: findings from a new contingent valuation study in Sweden. J Risk Uncertain 23(2):121–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pratt JW, Zeckhauser RJ (1996) Willingness to pay and the distribution of risk and wealth. J Polit Econ 104(4):747–763

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roach B, Boyle KJ, Welsh M (2002) Testing bid design effects in multiple-bounded, contingent-valuation questions. Land Econ 78(1):121–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosen S (1974) Hedonic prices and implicit markets: product differentiation in pure competition. J Polit Econ 82(1):34–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosen S (1988) The value of changes in life expectancy. J Risk Uncertain 1(3):285–304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rydenstam K (2008) Mer jämställt i Norden än i öriga Europa? SCB:s tidskrift Välfärd, Nr 1

  • Shepard DS, Zeckhauser RJ (1984) Survival versus consumption. Manag Sci 30(4):423–439

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • SIKA (2008) Samhällsekonomiska kalkylprinciper och kalkylvärden för transportsektorn. SIKA PM 2008:3. SIKA (Swedish Institute for Transport and Communications Analysis)

  • Stevens TH, DeCoteau NE, Willis CE (1997) Sensitivity of contingent valuation to alternative payment schedules. Land Econ 73(1):140–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stumborg BE, Baerenklau KA, Bishop RC (2001) Nonpoint source pollution and present values: a contingent valuation study of Lake Mendota. Rev Agric Econ 23(1):120–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sundström K, Andersson H (2009) Swedish consumers willingness to pay for food safety—a contingent valuation study on Salmonella risk. SLI—Working Paper 2009:1. Swedish Institute for Food and Agricultural Economics (SLI), Lund

  • Turnbull BW (1976) The empirical distribution function with arbitrarily grouped, censored, and truncated data. J R Statist Soc 38(B):290–295

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky A, Thale RH (1990) Anomalies: preference reversals. J Econ Perspect 4(2):201–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky A, Slovic P, Kahneman D (1990) The causes of preference reversal. Am Econ Rev 80(1):204–217

    Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi WK (1998) Ration Risk Policy. Oxford University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi WK, Aldy JE (2003) The value of a statistical life: a critical review of market estimates throughout the world. J Risk Uncertain 27(1):5–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weinstein MC, Shepard DS, Pliskin JS (1980) The economic value of changing mortality probabilities: a decision–theoretic approach. Q J Econ 94(2):373–396

    Google Scholar 

  • Werner M (1999) Allowing for zeros in dichotomous-choice contingent valuation models. J Bus Econ Statist 17(4):479–486

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Funding for this research was provided by VINNOVA. James Hammitt acknowledges financial support from INRA and the European Research Council under the European Community’s Seventh Framework Programme (FP7/2007-2013) Grant Agreement No. 230589. The authors are grateful to the editor and two reviewers for their helpful comments on earlier drafts. The usual disclaimers apply.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Henrik Andersson.

Appendix: The Mixture Model

Appendix: The Mixture Model

When assuming a log-normal distribution, WTP equal to zero is ruled out. Incorporating zero WTP can be done by employing the mixture model (An and Ayala 1996; Haab 1999; Werner 1999). This section briefly describes the difference between the DB conventional (WTP \(>\) 0) and mixture model. For a more detailed description of the mixture model see, e.g., An and Ayala (1996).

Let \(i=1,\ldots ,N\), \(b_{i},\;b^L_i\) and \(b^H_i\), denote the index for each respondent, the initial bid, and the follow-up bids, respectively, with the superscripts referring to lower (L) and higher (H) follow-up bids. The respondents’ answers in a DB CVM are represented by the following four indicator variables:

$$\begin{aligned} \left\{ \begin{array}{l@{\quad }l} D_{1i}=1\quad ~\text{ iff } \text{ WTP }_i<b^L_i&{}\quad \text{(``no-no'' } \text{ response) } \\ D_{2i}=1\quad ~\text{ iff }~b^L_i\le \text{ WTP }_i<b_i&{}\quad \text{(``no-yes'' } \text{ response) } \\ D_{3i}=1\quad ~\text{ iff }~b_i\le \text{ WTP }_i<b^H_i&{}\quad \text{(``yes-no'' } \text{ response) } \\ D_{4i}=1\quad ~\text{ iff }~b^H_i\le \text{ WTP }_i&{}\quad \text{(``yes-yes'' } \text{ response) } \\ \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(12)

Let \(F(x;\theta )\) denote the cumulative distribution function (CDF) for \(x\) with parameters \(\theta \), and our sample log-likelihood for the conventional model is then,

$$\begin{aligned} l(\theta )&= \sum _{i=1}^N\left\{ D_{1i}\ln \left[ F\left( b^L_i;\theta \right) \right] +D_{2i}\ln \left[ F\left( b_i;\theta \right) -F\left( b^L_i;\theta \right) \right] \right. \nonumber \\&\left. \quad +D_{3i}\ln \left[ F\left( b^H_i;\theta \right) -F\left( b_i;\theta \right) \right] +D_{4i}\ln \left[ 1-F\left( b^H_i;\theta \right) \right] \right\} . \end{aligned}$$
(13)

Now, assuming that \(x\ge 0\), the CDF of \(x\) in the mixture model will have the form,

$$\begin{aligned} G(x;\rho ,\theta )=\left\{ \begin{array}{l l l l} \rho &{} \quad ~\text{ if }~ &{} x=0 \\ \rho +(1-\rho )F(x;\theta ) &{}\quad ~\text{ if }~ &{} x>0 \\ \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(14)

i.e. \(G(x;\rho ,\theta )\) has a point mass \(\rho \) at \(x=0\).

The estimation of the mixture model depends on whether the analyst has information about which respondents have a WTP equal to zero, information that can be obtained by asking a follow-up question to the “no-no” respondents. When this information is not available, \(\rho \) needs to be estimated and the log-likelihood is specified as follows,

$$\begin{aligned} l_1(\rho ,\theta )&= \sum _{i=1}^N\left\{ D_{1i}\ln \left[ \rho \!+\!(1\!-\!\rho ) F\left( b^L_i;\theta \right) \right] \!+\!D_{2i}\ln \left[ (1\!-\!\rho )\left( F(b_i;\theta )\!-\!F(b^L_i;\theta )\right) \right] \right. \nonumber \\&\left. \quad +D_{3i}\ln \left[ (1-\rho )\left( F\left( b^H_i;\theta \right) -F(b_i;\theta )\right) \right] \right. \nonumber \\&\left. \quad + D_{4i}\ln \left[ (1-\rho )\left( 1-F\left( b^H_i;\theta \right) \right) \right] \right\} . \end{aligned}$$
(15)

When \(x_i=0\) is known to the analyst, \(\rho =N_0/N\), where \(N_0\) is the number of respondents with a WTP equal to zero. For the log-likelihood we then need to introduce a new indicator variable, \(D_{0i}\), which is equal to 1 if WTP is equal to zero. The log-likelihood with full information is then specified by

$$\begin{aligned} l_2(\rho ,\theta )&= \sum _{i=1}^N\left\{ D_{0i}\ln [\rho ]+(D_{1i}-D_{0i})\ln \left[ \left( 1-\rho \right) F\left( b^L_i;\theta \right) \right] \right. \nonumber \\&\left. \quad +D_{2i}\ln \left[ (1-\rho )\left( F(b_i;\theta )-F\left( b^L_i;\theta \right) \right) \right] \right. \nonumber \\&\left. \quad +D_{3i}\ln \left[ (1\!-\!\rho )\left( F(b^H_i;\theta )\!-\!F(b_i;\theta )\right) \right] \!+\!D_{4i}\ln \left[ (1\!-\!\rho )\left( 1\!-\!F\left( b^H_i;\theta \right) \right) \right] \right\} \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(16)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Andersson, H., Hammitt, J.K., Lindberg, G. et al. Willingness to Pay and Sensitivity to Time Framing: A Theoretical Analysis and an Application on Car Safety. Environ Resource Econ 56, 437–456 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-013-9644-0

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-013-9644-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation