Skip to main content
Log in

The Likelihood of the Consistency of Collective Rankings Under Preferences Aggregation with Four Alternatives Using Scoring Rules: A General Formula and the Optimal Decision Rule

  • Published:
Computational Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In most of the social choice literature dealing with the computation of the exact probability of voting events under the impartial culture assumption, authors deal with no more than four constraints to describe voting events. With more than four constraints, most of the authors rely on Monte-Carlo simulations. It is usually more tricky to estimate the probability of events described by five constraints. Gehrlein and Fishburn (Appl Math Optim 6:241–255, 1980) have tried, but their conclusions are based on conjectures. In this paper, we circumvent this conjecture by having recourse to the technique suggested by Saari and Tataru (Econ Theory 13: 345–363, 1999) in order to compute the limit probability of the consistency of collective rankings when there are four competing alternatives given that the decision rule is a scoring rule. We provide a general formula for the limiting probability of the consistency and we determine the optimal decision rules among the scoring rules that provide the best guarantee of consistency. Given the collective ranking on a set A, we have consistency if the collective ranking on B a proper subset of A is not altered after some alternatives are removed from A.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For more on the other assumptions, please refer to Berg and Lepelley (1994) and Gehrlein and Lepelley (2010).

  2. We give a formal definition of a voting situation in Sect. 2.

  3. Assume \((X_1, X_2,\cdots , X_n)\) a vector of n random variables with a nonsingular multivariate normal distribution. Plackett (1954) evaluated the probability \(P(X_1>x_1, X_2>x_2,\cdots , X_n >x_n)\); he ended with a reduction formula of this probability based on the numerical quadrature for \(n=3, 4\).

  4. A limiting probability is computed when the size of the electorate tends to infinity.

  5. We provide a supplement document in which the reader can see how our formulas look like.

  6. The methodology developed in this paper was recently used and applied by Kamwa and Merlin (2015) to perform probability computations for some voting events under some popular voting rules.

  7. A linear order is a binary relation that is transitive, complete and antisymmetric. The binary relation R on A is transitive if for \(a,b,c\in A\), if aRb and bRc then aRc. R is antisymmetric if for all for \(a\ne b\), \(aRb\Rightarrow \lnot bRa\); if we have aRb and bRa, then \(a=b\). R is complete if and only if for all \(a,b\in A\), we have aRb or bRa.

  8. We were not able to find a reduced form of this formula. This was also the case for all the other general formulas.

  9. Given a collective ranking over a set of four candidates, they determine under the impartial culture condition, the probability of each of the six possible rankings when one candidate is dropped.

  10. Thanks to the referee for bringing to our attention the works of D’Ambrosio and Heiser (2016) and Gormley and Murphy (2008).

References

  • Abrahamson, I. G. (1964). Orthant probabilities for the quadrivariate normal distribution. The Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 35(4), 1685–1703.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berg, S., & Lepelley, D. (1994). On probability models in voting theory. Statistica Neerlandica, 48, 133–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coxeter, H. S. M. (1935). The functions of Schläfli and Lobatschefsky. Quarterly Journal of Mathematics, 6, 13–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D’Ambrosio, A., & Heiser, W. J. (2016). A recursive partitioning method for the prediction of preference rankings based upon kemeny distances. Psychometrika, 81(3), 774–794.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felsenthal, D. S. (2012). Review of paradoxes afflicting procedures for electing a single candidate. In D. S. Felsenthal & M. Machover (Eds.), Electoral systems: Paradoxes, assumptions, and procedures, studies in choice and welfare. Berlin: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W. V. (1979). A representation for quadrivariate normal positive orthant probabilities. Journal Communications in Statistics-simulation and Computation, 8(4), 349–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W. V. (2006). Condorcet’s paradoxes. Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W. V., & Fishburn, P. C. (1976). The probability of the paradox of voting: A computable solution. Journal of Economic Theory, 13, 14–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W. V., & Fishburn, P. C. (1980). Robustness of positional scoring over subsets of alternatives. Applied Mathematics and Optimization, 6, 241–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W. V., & Fishburn, P. C. (1981). Scoring rules and majority agreements for large electorates with arbitrary preferences. Mathematical Social Sciences, 2, 23–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W. V., & Lepelley, D. (2010). Voting paradoxes and group coherence. Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W. V., & Lepelley, D. (2017). Elections, voting rules and paradoxical outcomes. Berlin: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gormley, I. C., & Murphy, T. B. (2008). A mixture of experts model for rank data with applications in election studies. The Annals of Applied Statistics, 2(4), 1452–1477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamwa, E., & Merlin, V. (2015). Scoring rules over subset of alternatives: Consistency and paradoxes. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 61, 130–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kellerhals, R. (1989). On the volume of hyperbolic polyedra. Mathematische Annalen, 285, 541–569.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kendall, M. G. (1938). A new measure of rank correlation. Biometrika, 30(1/2), 81–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mallows, C. L. (1957). Non-null ranking models. I. Biometrika, 44(1/2), 114–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merlin, V., Tataru, M., & Valognes, F. (2002). On the likelihood of condorcet’s profiles. Social Choice and Welfare, 19(1), 193–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merlin, V., Tataru, M., & Valognes, F. (2000). On the probability that all decision rules select the same winner. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 33, 183–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merlin, V., & Valognes, F. (2004). On the impact of indifferent voters on the likelihood of some voting paradoxes. Mathematical Social Sciences, 48, 343–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milnor, J. (1982). Hyperbolic geometry: The first 150 years. Bulletin of the American Mathematical Society, 6, 9–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nurmi, H. (1999). Voting paradoxes and how to deal with them. Berlin: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Plackett, R. L. (1954). A reduction formula for normal multivariate integrals. Biometrika, 41(3/4), 351–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saari, D. G., & Tataru, M. (1999). The likelihood of dubious election outcomes. Economic Theory, 13, 345–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schläfli, L. (1950). Theorie der Vielfachen Kontinuität. Gesammelte Mathematische Abhandlungen 1. Basel: Birkhäuser.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tataru, M., & Merlin, V. (1997). On the relationship of the Condorcet winner and positional voting rules. Mathematical Social Sciences, 34, 81–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful to two anonymous reviewers for their helpful comments. Thanks to two anonymous members of the Maple-group for their assistance. Eric Kamwa acknowledges the support of the Hitotsubashi Institute of Economic Research during his stay under the “JSPS Program for Advancing Strategic International Networks to Accelerate the Circulation of Talented Researchers”. Vincent Merlin acknowledges support from the project ANR-14-CE24-0007-01 CoCoRICo-CoDec.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Eric Kamwa.

Appendix

Appendix

For space constraints, here are the links to:

  • An external sheet where the reader can see how our formulas look.

https://www.dropbox.com/s/mkdbxuwfrsevmk3/general%20formula.pdf?dl=0

  • The MAPLE-sheet we used for all our computations.

https://www.dropbox.com/s/byyvtoex90h4je5/MapleSheet_generic.pdf?dl=0

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kamwa, E., Merlin, V. The Likelihood of the Consistency of Collective Rankings Under Preferences Aggregation with Four Alternatives Using Scoring Rules: A General Formula and the Optimal Decision Rule. Comput Econ 53, 1377–1395 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10614-018-9816-7

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10614-018-9816-7

Keywords

Mathematics Subject Classification

Navigation