Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Political structure, legislative process, and corruption: comparing Taiwan and South Korea

  • Published:
Crime, Law and Social Change Aims and scope Submit manuscript

    We’re sorry, something doesn't seem to be working properly.

    Please try refreshing the page. If that doesn't work, please contact support so we can address the problem.

Abstract

Taiwan and South Korea have the same constitutional system, approximate economic scale, and similar cultural backgrounds, yet they differ in degree of corruption. What political structures and legislative processes cause this outcome is the major question posed in this paper. The political structure in South Korea is a centralization-of-power model, while that in Taiwan is a separation-of-powers model. This paper proposes that Taiwan and South Korea have different types of corruption and different political structures, and the legislative process in South Korea is more compromising than that in Taiwan. These factors contribute to greater corruption in South Korea than in Taiwan. This study clarifies how particular institutional dynamics reduce or enhance the prospects for democratic governance and help to better understand how political structure and legislative process channel different types of corruption into different degrees of corruption. Studies on the relationship between constitutional structure and corruption have concluded that parliamentarism can help reduce corruption more than presidentialism. This thesis argues that a country with centralized power tends to be less corrupt than a country with separation of powers. If this argument and the rationale behind it hold true for countries with both parliamentary and presidential systems, we can expect that semi-presidential countries with a centralized system are less corrupt than those with a decentralized system, all else being equal. However, by comparing these two semi-presidential countries, we find that South Korea, with its centralized model, was more corrupt than Taiwan, with its decentralized model. This comparative case study provides a counterargument to the conventional wisdom of constitutional structure and governance.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Both Taiwan and South Korea are semi-presidential countries. See Elgie [8].

  2. The most similar systems design has two theoretical implications: (1) the common factors in the cases are irrelevant in explaining different outcomes; (2) different factors in the cases are related to different outcomes. In terms of our concern here, this paper seeks to explain why different political structures and processes can affect different degrees of corruption by using the most similar systems design. Please see Przeworski and Teune [42].

  3. This classification is for the purpose of literature review.

  4. Supplier means that the person or organization dispenses corrupt benefits. Stake indicates corrupt benefits.

  5. The DPP attacked the KMT over the corruption issue and made significant strides in electoral competition before the transfer of power. It forced the KMT to fight corruption, but in the meantime had to depend on corruption in order to survive in the electoral competition. See Fell [9, 10] and Göbel [13].

  6. From 1995 to 2003 there were only two cases of bill reconsideration. Please see Statistics Yearbook of the Legislative Yuan of Taiwan (Taiwan: The Accounting Agency of the Legislative Yuan Press, 2003).

  7. See Statistics Yearbook of the Legislative Yuan of Taiwan (Taiwan: The Accounting Agency of the Legislative Yuan Press, 2003).

  8. See Statistics Yearbook of the Legislative Yuan of Taiwan (Taiwan: The Accounting Agency of the Legislative Yuan Press, 2003).

  9. Regarding the powers of the National Assembly, they are enumerated in the constitution of South Korea and can also be found on the website of the National Assembly of South Korea: http://www.eng.assembly.go.kr.

  10. According to the National Assembly Act (Article 127), the standing committees of the National Assembly shall perform an annual inspection of the state administration for 20 days from the day after the commencement of the regular session; however, the date may be changed by a resolution of the plenary session.

  11. Universalism states that reelected officials’ incentive and uncertainty over being included in minimum-winning coalitions have contributed to legislators’ distributing benefits universally in Congress. Please see Weingast [53]. Distributing benefits for local electoral districts is called pork-barrel legislation.

  12. In Taiwan, there are four major parties: the Kuomintang (KMT), the Democratic Progressive Party (DPP), the People First Party (PFP), and the Taiwan Solidarity Union (TSU). The opposition parties are the KMT and the PFP. The DPP is the ruling party and TSU is its ally.

  13. The DPP opposed the KMT, the PFP, and the NP 47.5% of the time; it opposed the KMT and the PFP 5.1% of the time; it opposed the PFP and the NP 11.1% of the time, and it opposed the NP 7.1% of the time. Thus, total party polarization mode was 60.8%. Related discussions see Lee [28, 29].

  14. Before 1995, Kim Young-sam’s party was the Democratic Liberal Party (DLP). In order to push the policy of generation change, he changed the party name to the New Korea Party (NKP). It caused some leaders to leave the DLP, such as Kim Jong-pil.

  15. The percentage of office-holders sharing their birthplace with the incumbent president relative to the total number of office-holders during each regime was 23.4 (Kyoung-nam) under Kim Young-sam (1993–1997) and 15.8% (Jeon-nam (Kwang-ju) under Kim Dae-jung (1998–2000)). See Jang [16].

References

  1. Abe, M., & Kawakami, M. (1997). A distribute comparison of enterprise size in Korea and Taiwan. The Developing Economies, 35(4), 382–400. doi:10.1111/j.1746-1049.1997.tb00853.x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Aldrich, J. H. (1995). Why parties? The origin and transformation of party politics in America. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Cheng, H. (2004). Party interaction on the record of roll-call voting in Taiwan’s parliament: From the first session of the third term to the second session of the fifth term. Taiepi: Soochow University, Political Science Department, Master Thesis (Written in Chinese).

  4. Chu, Y. (1994). The realignment of business-government relations and regime transition in Taiwan. In A. MacIntyre (Ed.), Business and government in industrializing Asia. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Collie, M. P. (1988). Universalism and the parties in the U.S. house of representatives, 1921–80. American Journal of Politics, 32(4), 865–883. doi:10.2307/2111192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Cox, G. W., & Morgenstern, S. (2001). Latin America’s reactive assemblies and proactive presidents. Comparative Politics, 33(2), 171–189. doi:10.2307/422377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Croissant, A. (2002). Strong presidents, weak democracy? Presidents, parliaments and political parties in South Korea. Korean Observer, 33(1), 1–45.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Elgie, R. (2007). What is semi-presidentialism and where is it found. In R. Elgie, & S. Moestrup (Eds.), Semi-presidentialism outside Europe (pp. 1–13). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Fell, D. (2004). Party politics in Taiwan: Party change and the democratic evolution of Taiwan, 1991–2004. London and New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Fell, D. (2005). Political and media liberalization and political corruption in Taiwan. The China Quarterly, 184, 875–893. doi:10.1017/S0305741005000548.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Ferguson, T. (1995). Golden rule: The investment theory of party competition and the logic of money-driven political systems. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Gerring, J., & Thacker, S. (2004). Political institutions and corruption: The role of unitarianism and parliamentarism. British Journal of Political Science, 34(2), 295–330. doi:10.1017/S0007123404000067.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Göbel, C. (2004). Beheading the hydra: Combating political corruption and organized crime. China Perspectives, 56, 14–25.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Haggard, S., & Kang, D. (1999). The Kim Young Sam presidency in comparative perspective. In C. Moon, & J. Mo (Eds.), Democratization and globalization in Korea: Assessments and prospects (pp. 111–131). Seoul: Yonsei University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Huang, S. (2003). The predicament of minority government in the legislative Yuan. Taiwanese Political Science Review, 7(2), 3–49 (written in Chinese).

    Google Scholar 

  16. Jang, S. (2000). Driving engine or rent-seeking super-cartel. Ph.D. Dissertation submitted to Michigan University, East Lansing, Michigan.

  17. Johnston, M. (1986). The political consequence of corruption: A reassessment. Comparative Politics, 18(4), 459–477. doi:10.2307/421694.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Kang, D. C. (2002). Crony capitalism: Corruption and development in South Korea and the Philippines. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Kim, S.-h. (1999). Patronage Politics as an Obstacle to Democracy in South Korea: Regional Networks and Democratic Consolidation. In H. Handelman, & M. Tessler (Eds.), Democracy and its Limits: Lessons from Asia, Latin America, and the Middle East (pp. 115–29). University of Notre Dame Press.

  20. Kim, S. (2000). The politics of reform in South Korea: The first year of the Kim Dae Jung government, 1998–1999. Asian Perspective, 24(1), 163–185.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Kim, C., & Yong-gwan, K. (1995). The evolution of obedience norms in the national assembly: A study of the repeated carrot-and-the stick game. Asian Perspective, 19(2), 243–269.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Koh, B. C. (1997). South Korea in 1996: Internal strains and external challenges. Asian Survey, 37(1), 1–9. doi:10.1525/as.1997.37.1.01p01954.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Kong, T. (1996). Corruption and its institutional foundations: The experience of South Korea. IDS Bulletin, 27(2), 48–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Kong, T. (2000). Power alternation in South Korea. Government and Opposition, 35(3), 370–391. doi:10.1111/1477-7053.00033.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Kong, T. (2004). Corruption and the effect of regime type: The case of Taiwan. New Political Economy, 9(3), 341–364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Kuo, C. (2000). Taiwan’s distorted democracy in comparative perspective. Journal of Asian and African Studies, 35(6), 86–111.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Kwon, H. (2005). Targeting public spending in a new democracy: Evidence from South Korea. British Journal of Political Science, 35(2), 321–341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Lee, H. (2004). South Korea in 2003: A question of leadership. Asian Survey, 44(1), 130–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Lee, I. (2004). Denial of agenda access and deliberation of bills: The fourth term of the legislative Yuan. National Taiwan University, Political Science Department, Master Thesis (written in Chinese).

  30. Levitt, S. D., & Snyder Jr., J. M. (1995). Political parties and the distribution of federal outlays. American Journal of Political Science, 39(4), 958–980. doi:10.2307/2111665.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Lijphart, A. (1971). Comparative politics and the comparative method. The American Political Science Review, 65(3), 682–693. doi:10.2307/1955513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Lin, Y. (2001). Kickbacks in small local construction projects. Wealth Magazine, 231, 171–176, Taiwan (written in Chinese).

    Google Scholar 

  33. Mebane Jr., W. R. (1994). Fiscal constraints and electoral manipulation in American social welfare. The American Political Science Review, 88(1), 77–94. doi:10.2307/2944883.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. Morris, P. (1996). Electoral politics in South Korea. Electoral Studies, 15, 550–562. doi:10.1016/S0261-3794(96)80473-2.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Nye, J. S. (1967). Corruption and political development: A cost–benefit analysis. The American Political Science Review, 61(2), 417–427. doi:10.2307/1953254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Oh, J. K. (1999). Korean politics: The quest for democratization and economic development. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  37. Park, C. (1998). The national assembly of the Republic of Korea. Journal of Legislative Studies, 4(4), 66–82.

    Google Scholar 

  38. Park, C. (2000). Legislative–executive relations and legislative reform. In L. Diamond, & D. Chull Chin (Eds.), Institutional reform and democratic consolidation in Korea (pp. 73–96). Stanford: Hoover Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Park, C. (2002). Change is short but continuity is long: Policy influence of the national assembly in newly democratized Korea. In G. Loewenberg, P. Squire, & D. R. Kiewiet (Eds.), Legislatures: Comparative perspectives on representative assemblies (pp. 329–351). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  40. Park, C. (2003). Budget review in the national assembly of democratic Korea. Journal of East Asian Studies, 3, 493–521.

    Google Scholar 

  41. Persson, T., Roland, G., & Tabellini, G. (1997). Separation of powers and political accountability. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4), 1163–1202. doi:10.1162/003355300555457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Przeworski, A., & Teune, H. (1970). The logic of comparative social inquiry. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  43. Rose-Ackerman, S. (1999). Corruption and government. London: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  44. Rose-Ackerman, S. (2001). Political corruption and democratic structures. In A. K. Jian (Ed.), The political economy of corruption (pp. 35–62). New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  45. Samuels, D. J., & Shugart, M. S. (2003). Presidentialism, elections and representation. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 15(1), 33–60. doi:10.1177/0951692803151002.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  46. Saxer, C. J. (2002). From transition to power alternation: Democracy in South Korea, 1987–1997. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  47. Sheng, S. (2003). The influences of the legislative branch and executive branch in the law-making process. Taiwanese Political Science Review, 7(2), 51–105, (written in Chinese).

    Google Scholar 

  48. Sheplse, K. A., & Weingast, B. R. (1981). Political preferences for the pork barrel? A generalization. American Journal of Political Science, 25(1), 96–111. doi:10.2307/2110914.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  49. Shiau, C. (1996). Elections and the changing state–business relationship. In T. Hung-mao (Ed.), Taiwan’s electoral politics and democratic transition: Riding the third wave (pp. 213–225). New York: M. E. Sharp.

    Google Scholar 

  50. Stein, R. M., & Bickers, K. N. (1994). Congressional elections and the pork barrel. The Journal of Politics, 56(2), 377–399. doi:10.2307/2132144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  51. Wedeman, A. (1997). Looters, rent-scrapers, and dividend-collectors: Corruption and growth in Zaire, South Korea, and the Philippines. Journal of Developing Areas, 31(4), 457–478.

    Google Scholar 

  52. Wedeman, A. (2002). Development and corruption. In E. T. Gomez (Ed.), Political business in East Asia (pp. 34–61). New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  53. Weingast, B. R. (1979). A rational choice perspective on congressional norms. American Journal of Political Science, 23(2), 245–263. doi:10.2307/2111001.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  54. Yang, S. (1995). An analysis of South Korea’s political process and party politics. In J. Cotton (Ed.),Politics and policy in the New Korean State: From Roh Tae-woo to Kim Young-sam (pp. 6–34). New York: St. Martin’s.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jung-hsiang Tsai.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Tsai, Jh. Political structure, legislative process, and corruption: comparing Taiwan and South Korea. Crime Law Soc Change 52, 365–383 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10611-009-9188-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10611-009-9188-y

Keywords

Navigation