Skip to main content
Log in

Why risk popular ratification failure? A comparative analysis of the choice of the ratification instrument in the 25 Member States of the EU

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Following the European integration history, referenda are a risky ratification strategy. Despite establishing a convention and intense treaty negotiations, an unprecedented number of eleven member states announced a referendum for the ratification of the constitutional treaty in 2004, two of them finally failed and stalled the ratification process. This study examines the choice of the ratification instrument by an empirical analysis of the strategic interaction between government, opposition parties and the electorate in the 25 ratification countries. Our analysis considers country-specific conditions and correctly predicts most of the ratification choices in countries which announced referenda (65%) and almost all parliamentary ratification cases (93%). The results reveal that governments choose referenda when they expect low gains from a treaty reform or are confronted with a Euro-sceptical parliamentary opposition. We also find that governments are eager to separate popular votes from domestic electoral campaigns.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. These are Belgium, Czech Republic, Denmark, Ireland, Luxemburg, the Netherlands, Poland, Portugal, Spain and the United Kingdom, and only France announced the referendum after the signing of the treaty.

  2. List of failed referenda: France (Constitution, 2006), Netherlands (Constitution, 2006), Denmark (Maastricht, 1992; EMU, 2000), Ireland (Nice, 2001), Norway (membership, 1972, 1994), Sweden (EMU, 2003). List of successful referenda: Ireland (membership, 1972; SEA, 1987; Maastricht, 1992; Amsterdam, 1998), Denmark (membership, 1972; SEA, 1986; Amsterdam, 1998), France (enlargement, 1972; Maastricht, 1992), Great Britain (continued membership, 1975), Austria, Sweden, Finland (membership, 1994), Luxemburg, Spain (constitution, 2006), Malta, Hungary, Slovenia, Lithuania, Slovakia, Poland, Czech R, Estonia, Latvia (membership, 2003).

  3. In case voters’ desire for participation is very strong a referendum might turn out “de facto mandatory” (Binzer Hobolt 2006, p. 159f.). This is more likely in member states which have a tradition of referenda with respect to certain issues.

  4. The Lithuanian government announced parliamentary ratification right after the general elections in 2004. In Spain the referendum has been announced by the Aznar government in June 2003, elections took place in March 2004 and the referendum has been conducted under the Zapatero government in May 2004. In January 2003 the Dutch elected a new government which announced referendum in September 2003.

  5. The project Domestic Structures and European Integration (DOSEI) has been funded under the 5th framework programme of the European Commission (for more information please consult: http://dosei.dhv-speyer.de).

  6. The gains of government i are defined by the following equation, where ip defines the ideal position of the government, sq defines the status quo (Treaty of Nice) and out defines the constitutional treaty: \( \mathop U\nolimits_{i} = \sqrt {\sum\nolimits_{j = 1}^{2} {\mathop {\mathop s\nolimits_{ij} \left( {\mathop {ip}\nolimits_{ij} - \mathop {sq}\nolimits_{j} } \right)}\nolimits^{2} } } - \sqrt {\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{2} {\mathop s\nolimits_{ij} \mathop {\left( {\mathop {ip}\nolimits_{ij} - \mathop o\nolimits_{j} } \right)}\nolimits^{2} } } \). The parameter s describes the relative salience the government attaches to one dimension as compared to the other. It has been operationalized as the relation of those summed item discrimination parameters which had been of vital interest for the respective government (König and Finke 2007; Hug and König 2002).

  7. The Chapel Hill 2002 dataset is based on 238 expert interviews conducted between September 2002 and April 2003. The dataset includes positions on European integration for 171 parties in 21 countries. The positions for Cyprus, Malta, Luxembourg and Estonia have been imputed with the means of the respective party families. Our operationalization uses the answers from question 1: “Overall orientation of the party leadership towards European integration in 2002” (Hooghe et al. 2002).

  8. Unfortunately, the CMP data does not include information on Cyprus and Malta. The respective party positions have been imputed on the basis of survey data provided by Benoit and Laver (2006) using AMELIA.

  9. The standard approach to cooperative game theory assumes that actors always chose the best option (best response). The Quantal Response approach breaks with this assumption and allows for decision errors (quantal response). These decision errors follow a logistic distribution. The degree of rationality follows the distribution parameter λ (McKelvey and Palfrey 1995). For reasons of model identification the lambda is equal for all actors and has been fixed beforehand.

  10. Note that the estimates are based on the assumption that referenda do not cause any other costs than implied by t r, t o, t v, p r, p o, p v and g. Furthermore, for the sake of model identification, the decision error is assumed to be identical and positive for all actors (λ = 25).

  11. Governments expected utility is the product of the anticipated probability for ratification success and its treaty gains (t g). The probability of successful parliamentary ratification has been taken from the results of our QR estimation (see Table 4). The probability of successful referendum has been set equal to 0.5 because our main indicator for voters’ treaty gains (t v) turns out entirely insignificant.

References

  • Altman, D. (2007). Myths and facts about the use of direct democracy worldwide, paper presented at the ECPR Joint Sessions of Workshops, Workshop 18: Referendums and Initiatives, Helsinki 7–12 May.

  • Binzer Hobolt, S. (2006). Direct democracy and European integration. Journal of European Public Policy, 13(1), 153–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjørklund, T. (1982). The demand for referendum: When does it arise and when does it succeed? Scandinavian Political Studies, 5, 237–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Closa, C. (2007). Why convene referendums? Explaining choices in EU constitutional politics. Journal of European Public Policy, 14(8), 1311–1332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crum, B. (2007). Party stances in the referendums on the EU constitution. European Union Politics, 8(1), 201–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Vreese, C., & Boomgaarden, H. G. (2006). Media effects on public opinion about the enlargement of the European union. Journal of Common Market Studies, 44(2), 419–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feld, L. P., & Kirchgässner, G. (1999). Direct democracy matters for economic performance: An empirical investigation. Kyklos, 50(4), 507–538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finke, D. (2009). Domestic politics and European treaty reform: Analysing the dynamics of governmental reform positions. European Union Politics, 10(3).

  • Franklin, M., van der Eijk, C., & Marsh, M. (1995). Referendum outcomes and trust in government: Public support for Europe in the wake of Maastricht. West European Politics, 18, 101–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S., & Stutzer, A. (2000). Happiness, economy and institutions. Economic Journal, 110(4), 918–938.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S., & Stutzer, A. (2002). Happiness and economics: How the economy and institutions affect well-being. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gallagher, M. (1988). The single European act referendum. Irish Political Studies, 3(1), 77–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garry, J., Marsh, M., & Sinnott, R. (2005). Second order vs. issue voting effects in EU referendums: Evidence from the Irish nice-treaty referendums. European Union Politics, 6(2), 201–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerber, E. R. (1996). Legislative response to the threat of popular initiatives. American Journal of Political Science, 40, 99–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerber, E. R. (1998). Pressuring legislatures through the use of the initiatives: Two forms of indirect influence. In S. Bowler, T. Donovan, & C. J. Tolbert (Eds.), Citizens as legislators: Direct democracy in the united states (pp. 191–208). Columbus: Ohio State University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerber, E. R. (1999). The populist paradox: Interest group influence and the promise of direct legislation. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hooghe, L., et al. (2002). Chapel hill data set: Positioning of political parties on European integration downloadable at http://www.unc.edu/%7Ehooghe/data.htm.

  • Hug, S. (1995). What causes referenda? Uncertainty? Preferences? Institutions? Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American political science association, Chicago.

  • Hug, S. (2002). Voices of Europe—Citizens, referendums and European integration, Rowman and Littlefield.

  • Hug, S. (2004). Occurrence and policy consequences of referendums. A theoretical model and empirical evidence. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 16(3), 321–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hug, S., & König, T. (2002). In view of ratification: Governmental preferences and domestic constraints at the Amsterdam intergovernmental conference. International Organization, 56(2), 447–476.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hug, S., & Schulz, T. (2005). Referendums in the EU’s constitution building process. Review of International Organizations, 2(2), 177–218.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hug, S., & Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players and referendums around the world. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 14(4), 465–515.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ilda, K. (1996). Involuntary defection in two-level games. Public Choice, 89, 283–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann, B., & Waters, M. D. (Eds.). (2004). Direct democracy in Europe. A comprehensive reference guide to the initiative and referendum process in Europe. Durham: Carolina Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirchgässner, G., Feld, L. P., & Savioz, M. R. (1999). Die direkte demokratie: Modern, erfolgreich, entwicklungs- und exportfähig. Basel: Helbing und Lichtenhahn.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klingemann, H.-D., Volkens, A., Bara, J., Budge, I., & McDonald, M. D. (2006). Mapping policy preferences II estimates for parties, electors and governments in central and Eastern Europe, European Union and OECD 1990–2003. Oxford University Press.

  • König, T., & Finke, D. (2007). Reforming the equilibrium? Veto players and policy change in the European constitution-building process. Review of International Organizations, 2(2), 153–176. http://www.springerlink.com/content/0713545168342405/.

  • König, T., & Hug, S. (2000). Ratifying maastricht: Parliamentary votes on international treaties and theoretical solution concepts. European Union Politics, 1(1), 93–124.

    Google Scholar 

  • LeDuc, L. (2003). The politics of direct democracy: Referendums in global perspective. Toronto: Broadview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lupia, A. (1992). Busy voters, agenda control and the power of information. American Political Science Review, 86, 390–403.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lupia, A., & Matsusaka, J. G. (2004). Direct democracy: New approaches to old questions. Annual Review of Political Science, 7, 463–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luthardt, W. (1994). Direkte demokratie. Ein Vergleich in Westeuropa. Baden-Baden: Nomos.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsusaka, J. G. (2004). For the many or the few: The initiative process, public policy and American democracy. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsusaka, J. G., & McCarty, N. M. (2001). Political resource allocation: Benefits and costs of voter initiatives. Journal of Law Economics & Organization, 17(2), 413–448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R. D., & Palfrey, T. R. (1995). Quantal response equilibria for normal form games. Games and Economic Behavior, 10(1), 6–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morel, L. (2001). The rise of government initiated referendums in consolidatedemocracies. In P. Mendelsohn (Ed.), Referendum democracy: Citizens, elites and deliberation in referendum campaigns (pp. 123–152). New York: Palgrave.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C. (2005). Constitutional political economy in the European Union. Public Choice, 124, 57–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pahre, R. (2006). Democratic foreign policy making: Problems of divided government and international cooperation. London: Palgrave.

  • Pierce, R., Valen, H., & Listhaug, O. (1983). Referendum voting behaviour: The Norwegian and British referendum on membership in the European community. American Journal of Political Science, 27, 43–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pommerehne, W. (1978). Institutional approaches to public expenditures: Empirical evidence from swiss municipalities. Journal of Public Economics, 9(2), 163–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qvortrup, M. (2002). A comparative study of referendums: Government by the people. Manchester: Manchester University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, T., & Rosenthal, H. (1979). Bureaucrats versus voters: On the political economy of resource allocation by direct democracy. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 93(4), 561–587.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Satz, D., & Ferejohn, J. (1994). Rational choice and social theory. Journal of Philosophy, 91(2), 1–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scarrow, S. (2003). Making elections more direct? reducing the role of parties in elections. In B. Cain, D. Russell, & S. Scarrow (Eds.), Democracy transformed? (pp. 44–58). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, G., & Weitsman, P. (1996). The punishment trap. Integration referendums as popularity contests. Comparative Political Studies, 28(4), 582–607.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schulz, T. (2006). The timing of referendum announcements on the EU constitution and what it might tell us about their underlying motivation, Konferenzbeitrag für Workshop, Efficiency versus Democracy, ECPR Joint Sessions of Workshops, Nicosia, 25–30 April.

  • Signorino, C. (1999). Strategic interaction and the statistical analysis of international conflict. American Political Science Review, 93(2), 279–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slapin, J. (2006). Who is powerful? European Union Politics, 7(1), 51–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steenbergen, M., Edwards, E., & de Vries, C. E. (2007). Who is cueing whom? mass-elite linkages and the future of European integration. European Union Politics, 8(1), 13–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suksi, M. (1993). Bringing in the people: A comparison of constitutional forms and practices of the referendum. Dordrecht: Martinus Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • Svensson, P. (2002). Five Danish referendums on the European community and European union: A critical assessment of the Franklin thesis. European Journal of Political Research, 41, 733–750.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Widtfeld, A. (2004). Elite collusion and public defiance: Sweden’s euro referendum in 2003. West European Politics, 27(3), 503–518.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Daniel Finke.

Appendices

Appendix 1

1.1 Adaptation 1: Government’s choice (applicable to 17 member states)

In this version, the last two stages of the game resemble those of the general model. The second stage is missing because the opposition has no choice to decide on a referendum. At stage 1, when government knows that it has to accept a popular vote, the choice will depend on the expected outcome of the popular and parliamentary vote. If both ratification actors will accept the proposal, the government votes for a referendum when the audience benefits plus gains in domestic party competition are positive (p g + g > 0). If, on the other hand, both will reject the proposal, the government only prefers a referendum if the audience benefits outweigh the losses in domestic party competition (p g  > g). In the event of voters’ support and parliamentary rejection, the government is in favour of a referendum whenever the sum of the audience benefits, treaty gains and gains from domestic party competition is positive (t g  + p g  + g > 0). Finally, when voters reject and parliament adopt the proposal, the government will only propose a referendum if the audience benefits outweigh the sum of unrealized treaty gains and damage in domestic party competition (p g  > t g  + g).

If the government knows that it will overrule a popular vote, the choice for the ratification instrument is independent from audience benefits (with the exception that p g is discounted). In case of both ratification actors will accept the proposal, the government prefers a referendum whenever the gains in domestic party competition are higher than the treaty gains (g > t g). If, however, both ratification actors will reject the proposal, the government only favors a referendum if the treaty gains are higher than the losses in domestic party competition (t g  > g). If voters will adopt but parliament reject the proposal, the government prefers a referendum if this promises gains in domestic party competition ( > 0). Finally, if voters will reject but parliament adopt the proposal, the government only prefers a referendum in the highly unrealistic event where it could benefit from a popular No-vote in domestic party competition (g < 0).

Overall, the likelhood for a referendum increases with p g if the referendum is either de facto or legally binding. The effects of g and t g depend on the government’s expectation about the parliamentary and popular vote. If t g is relatively large as compared to g and p g, the government will always choose a less risky ratification strategy. However, the model also suggests that a government will even accept treaty losses if this causes (or avoids) benefits (or costs) in domestic party competition.

1.2 Adaptation 2: Opposition can veto (applicable to Belgium, Germany, Poland)

Another class of institutional provisions applies to countries which require supermajorities in order to initiate a referendum. As a result, neither opposition nor government can initiate a referendum unilaterally. In this version, stages 4 and 3 are identical to the general model. Stage 2 is similar to the general model when the government prefers a referendum, while the opposition has no choice in the event of parliamentary ratification. At stage 1, when the opposition will veto a referendum, the government is indifferent between announcing a referendum and parliamentary ratification. But when the opposition agrees on initiating a referendum, the government is behaving as described in stage 1 of adaptation 1.

1.3 Adaptation 3: Opposition can initiate (applicable to Greece, Italy, Slovakia, Hungary)

In some countries, the opposition can unilaterally initiate a referendum. In these cases, stages 4 and 3 are identical to the complete model. This also holds true for stage 2 which, however, is only relevant when the government prefers parliamentary ratification; otherwise the opposition has no choice. At stage 1, when the opposition will prefer a referendum, the government has little choice. If the referendum is either de facto or legally binding, the government will announce a referendum whenever the audience benefits are positive (p g  > 0). If the government must overrule a popular vote, it is indifferent between popular and parliamentary ratification. However, if the opposition would agree on a parliamentary ratification, the government is confronted with the same choice between referendum and parliament as described in stage 1 of adaptation1.

Appendix 2

The Ratification progress (mean of explanatory variables for the cases observed at each decision stage in January 2007).

Appendix 3

Table 6 Predicted probabilities for each of the four stages

Appendix 4

Table 7 Results of Country-specific residuals

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Finke, D., König, T. Why risk popular ratification failure? A comparative analysis of the choice of the ratification instrument in the 25 Member States of the EU. Const Polit Econ 20, 341–365 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-008-9068-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-008-9068-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation