Skip to main content
Log in

Digital showroom strategies for dual-channel supply chains in the presence of consumer webrooming behavior

  • S.I. : Information- Transparent Supply Chains
  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Online sellers are increasingly adopting the digital showroom service to reduce consumer valuation uncertainty and boost sales. However, such service also facilitates consumer webrooming behavior, which may reduce the online demand and intensify channel competition. In this study, we develop a theoretical supply chain model consisting of a manufacturer and a retailer to investigate the optimal digital showroom strategy for dual-channel supply chains in the presence of consumer webrooming behavior. The findings show that when the online shopping cost is relatively high, the digital showroom service can increase the profits of both players under two typical supply chain structures. However, when the online shopping cost is relatively low, the digital showroom service may decrease each player’s profit since it increases the selling prices in both channels and aggravates the double marginalization problem under the wholesale price contract. In this case, a new contract that combines a quantity discount component and a webrooming profit sharing component (abbreviated as QD-WPS) is proposed, which can perfectly coordinate the dual-channel supply chain with digital showrooms.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. https://www.shopify.com//retail/digital-virtual-showroom.

  2. https://wwd.com/business-news/technology/diesel-opens-doors-on-digital-showroom-1203660949/.

  3. http://finance.sina.com.cn/roll/2018-10-26/doc-ifxeuwws8240057.shtml.

  4. Note that, there will be also online-only consumers in the market, especially when the products are exclusively sold through online channels or the physical store is extremely far away from consumers. Since our study focuses on consumer webrooming behavior, and online-only consumers will not exhibit this behavior, to maintain mathematical tractability, we classify consumers in the market into dual-channel consumers and store-only consumers.

  5. https://www.shopify.com//retail/digital-virtual-showroom.

References

  • Balakrishnan, A., Sundaresan, S., & Zhang, B. (2014). Browse-and-switch: Retail-online competition under value uncertainty. Production and Operations Management, 23(7), 1129–1145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basak, S., Basu, P., Avittathur, B., & Sikdar, S. (2017). A game theoretic analysis of multichannel retail in the context of showrooming. Decision Support Systems, 103, 34–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basak, S., Basu, P., Avittathur, B., & Sikar, S. (2020). Manufacturer driven strategic coordination as a response to “showrooming.” Decision Support Systems, 133, 113–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cachon, G. P. (2001). Stock wars: Inventory competition in a two-echelon supply chain with multiple retailers. Operations Research, 49(5), 629–805.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cao, J., So, K. C., & Yin, S. (2016). Impact of an “online-to-store” channel on demand allocation, pricing and profitability. European Journal of Operational Research, 248(1), 234–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, T. M., & Guo, S. (2020). Is a ‘free lunch’ a good lunch? The performance of zero wholesale price-based supply-chain contracts. European Journal of Operational Research, 285(1), 237–246.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Digiday. (2015). The North Face brings virtual reality to retail. Retrieved January, 2021, from https://digiday.com/marketing/north-face-brings-virtual-reality-retail/.

  • Eliot, L. (2015). Retail’s new reality: Invisible shopping centers and virtual assistants. Retrieved January, 2021, from http://www.cnbc.com/2015/04/24/retails-new-reality-four-ways-technology-can-boost-sales-commentary.html.

  • E-Marketer. (2019). Here’s Why Stores Still Matter in the Digital Age. Retrieved January, 2021, from https://www.emarketer.com/content/here-s-why-stores-still-matter-in-the-digital-age.

  • Gao, F., & Su, X. (2017). Online and offline information for omnichannel retailing. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 19(1), 84–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gu, Z., & Tayi, G. K. (2017). Consumer pseudo-showrooming and omni-channel product placement strategies. MIS Quarterly, 41(2), 583–606.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guan, X., Mantrala, M., & Bian, Y. W. (2019). Strategic information management in a distribution channel. Journal of Retailing, 95(1), 42–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hua, Z. S., Hou, H., & Bian, Y. W. (2017). Optimal shipping strategy and return service charge under no-reason return policy in online retailing. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man and Cybernetics: Systems, 47(12), 3189–3206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jing, B. (2018). Showrooming and webrooming: Information externalities between online and offline sellers. Marketing Science, 37(3), 469–483.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson. (2020). How to Make Money Live Streaming in 2020. Retrieved January, 2021, from https://www.uscreen.tv/blog/make-money-live-streaming/.

  • He, L. F., Xue, M., & Gu, B. (2020). Internet-of-things enabled supply chain planning and coordination with big data services: Certain theoretic implications. Journal of Management Science and Engineering, 5(1), 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hu, W., & Li, Y. (2012). Retail service for mixed retail and E-tail channels. Annals Operations Research, 192, 151–171.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konur, D. (2021). Keep your enemy close? Competitive online brands’ expansion with individual and shared showrooms. OMEGA-the International Journal of Management Science, 99, 102–206.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuksov, D., & Liao, C. (2018). When showrooming increases retailer profit. Journal of Marketing Research, 55(4), 459–473.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kwark, Y., Chen, J., & Raghunathan, S. (2014). Online product reviews: Implications for retailers and competing manufacturers. Information Systems Research, 25(1), 93–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, G., Tao, Z., & Giri, K. T. (2020). Inroad into omni-channel retailing: Physical showroom deployment of an online retailer. European Journal of Operational Research, 283(2), 676–691.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, M. L., Zhang, X. M., & Dan, B. (2020). Competition and cooperation in a supply chain with an offline showroom under asymmetric information. International Journal of Production Research, 58(19), 5964–5979.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, Y. Y., Li, B., Zheng, W., & Chen, X. (2021). Reveal or hide? Impact of demonstration on pricing decisions considering showrooming behavior. OMEGA-the International Journal of Management Science, 102, 102–329.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, Y., Cooper, W. L., & Wang, Z. (2019). Information provision and pricing in the presence of consumer search costs. Production and Operations Management, 28(7), 1603–1620.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehra, A., Kumar, S., & Raju, J. S. (2018). Competitive strategies for brick-and-mortar stores to counter “showrooming.” Management Science, 64(7), 3076–3090.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miklos-Thal, J., & Shaffer, G. (2015). Resale price maintenance in the age of showrooming. Working paper, University of Rochester.

  • Ofek, E., Katona, Z., & Sarvary, M. (2011). “Bricks and clicks”: The impact of product returns on the strategies of multichannel retailers. Marketing Science, 30(1), 42–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pulga, A. (2015). Daily dose of iq wayfairs get it near me ad program encourages webrooming. Retrieved January, 2021, from www.iqmetrix.com/blog/daily-dose-of-iq-wayfairs-get-it-near-me-ad-program-encourages-webrooming/.

  • Pun, H., Chen, J., & Li, W. (2020). Channel strategy for manufacturers in the presence of service freeriders. European Journal and Operational Research, 287(2), 460–479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shi, H. Y., Liu, Y. C., & Petruzzi, N. C. (2019). Informative advertising in a distribution channel. European Journal and Operational Research, 274(2), 773–787.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sun, M., & Tyagi, R. K. (2020). Product fit uncertainty and information provision in a distribution channel. Production and Operations Management, 29(10), 2381–2402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sun, Y. H., Wang, Z. H., & Han, X. H. (2020). Supply chain channel strategies for online retailers: Whether to introduce web showrooms? Transportation Research Part e: Logistics and Transportation Review, 144, 102–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu, D., Ray, G., Geng, X., & Whinston, A. (2004). Implications of reduced search cost and free riding in e-commerce. Marketing Science, 2(23), 255–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xia, Y., Xiao, T., & Zhang, G. P. (2017). The impact of product returns and retailer’s service investment on manufacturer’s channel strategies. Decision Sciences, 48(5), 918–955.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xing, D., & Liu, T. (2012). Sales effort free riding and coordination with price match and channel rebate. European Journal and Operational Research, 219(2), 264–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, G., Ji, G., & Tan, K. H. (2020). Impact of artificial intelligence adoption on online returns policies. Annals Operations Research. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-020-03602-y

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yoo, W. S., & Lee, E. (2011). Internet channel entry: A strategic analysis of mixed channel structures. Marketing Science, 30(1), 29–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, T., & Choi, T. M. (2021). Optimal consumer sales tax policies for online-offline retail operations with consumer returns. Naval Research Logistics, 68(6), 701–720.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, S., & Zhang, J. (2020). Agency selling or reselling: e-tailer information sharing with supplier offline entry. European Journal of Operational Research, 280(1), 134–151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, T., Li, G., Cheng, T. C. E., & Shum, S. (2020). Consumer inter-product showrooming and information service provision in an omni-channel supply chain. Decision Sciences, 51(5), 1232–1264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, X. (2009). Retailers’ multichannel and price advertising strategies. Marketing Science, 28(6), 1080–1094.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This research was partly supported by programs granted by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (NSFC) (Nos: 71671108, 72002121, 71871068 and 72031004), and the Natural Science Foundation of Guangdong Province (No. 2021A1515011655). This work was also supported by the University Innovation Team Project of Guangdong Province in 2021 (2021WCXTD013).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Shuai Yan.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A: Proofs of main results under the base model

Proof of Lemma 1

  1. (1)

    Structure A:

    We apply the backward induction to solve for the optimal price strategies of the manufacturer and the independently offline retailer. First, given wholesale price \(\hat{w}^{A}\), we can derive the optimal retail prices \(\hat{p}_{o}^{A}\) and \(\hat{p}_{r}^{A}\). Second, we determine the optimal wholesale price \(\hat{w}^{A}\).

    The manufacturer and the retailer’s profit can be written as:

    $$ \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A} = \alpha \left( {1 - \frac{{\hat{p}_{o}^{A} - \theta \hat{p}_{r}^{A} + h}}{t}} \right)\hat{p}_{o}^{A} + \left( {\alpha \theta \frac{{\hat{p}_{o}^{A} - \theta \hat{p}_{r}^{A} + h}}{t} + \theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\frac{{\theta \left( {v - \hat{p}_{r}^{A} } \right)}}{t}} \right)\hat{w}^{A} , $$

    \(\hat{\pi }_{r}^{A} = \left( {\alpha \theta \frac{{\hat{p}_{o}^{A} - \theta \hat{p}_{r}^{A} + h}}{t} + \theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\frac{{\theta \left( {v - \hat{p}_{r}^{A} } \right)}}{t}} \right)\left( {\hat{p}_{r}^{A} - \hat{w}^{A} - c_{r} } \right)\), respectively.

    Since \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \hat{\pi }_{r}^{A} }}{{\left( {\partial \hat{p}_{r}^{A} } \right)^{2} }} = - \frac{{2\theta^{2} }}{t} < 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A} }}{{\left( {\partial \hat{p}_{o}^{A} } \right)^{2} }} = - \frac{2\alpha }{t} < 0\), by solving \(\frac{{\partial \hat{\pi }_{r}^{A} }}{{\partial \hat{p}_{r}^{A} }} = 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A} }}{{\partial \hat{p}_{o}^{A} }} = 0\), we can derive the equilibrium prices are:

    $$ \hat{p}_{r}^{A} = \frac{{2\left( {c_{r} + v + \hat{w}^{A} } \right)\theta + \alpha \left( {h + t - \left( {2v - \hat{w}^{A} } \right)\theta } \right)}}{{\left( {4 - \alpha } \right)\theta }}, $$
    (A1)
    $$ \hat{p}_{o}^{A} = \frac{{2t - h\left( {2 - \alpha } \right) + \left( {c_{r} + v + 3\hat{w}^{A} - v\alpha } \right)\theta }}{4 - \alpha }. $$
    (A2)

    Then, the manufacturer’s profit can be written as follow:

    $$ \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A} = \frac{{\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)}}{{t\left( {4 - \alpha } \right)^{2} }}\left( \begin{gathered} \left( {2t - h\left( {2 - \alpha } \right)} \right)^{2} \gamma + 2c_{r} \theta \gamma \left( {2t - h\left( {2 - \alpha } \right)} \right) + \theta^{2} c_{r}^{2} \gamma - 2\theta^{2} c_{r} \left( {4\hat{w}^{A} - v\alpha } \right) \hfill \\ - \theta \gamma h\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {2v\left( {2 - \alpha } \right) + \hat{w}^{A} \alpha } \right) + \theta^{2} \left( {v - \hat{w}^{A} } \right)\left( {v\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\alpha + \hat{w}^{A} \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)} \right) \hfill \\ + t\theta \gamma \left( {4v\left( {1 - \alpha } \right) + \hat{w}^{A} \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)} \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right) $$

    Since \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A} }}{{\left( {\partial \hat{w}^{A} } \right)^{2} }} = - \frac{{2\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\theta^{2} }}{{t\left( {4 - \alpha } \right)^{2} }} < 0\), by solving \(\frac{{\partial \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A} }}{{\partial \hat{w}^{A} }} = 0\), we can derive the best response functions as follows: \(\hat{w}^{A*} = \frac{{t\alpha \left( {8 + \alpha } \right) - \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {h\alpha^{2} + \left( {8c_{r} - v\left( {8 + \alpha^{2} } \right)} \right)\theta } \right)}}{{2\left( {8 - 7\alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right)\theta }}\).

    Substituting the equilibrium prices \(\hat{w}^{A*}\) into (A1) and (A2), we can obtain the table of lemma 1 under structure A. Note that, to ensure the optimal decisions satisfy the assumptions (a), (b) and (c) in N scenario in Sect. 3.1, all the following calculations are conducted under such constraints: \(\hat{p}_{o}^{A*} + h \le \theta v\), \(\hat{p}_{r}^{A*} \le v\) and \(\min \left\{ {\frac{\theta v - t}{\theta },\frac{{\hat{p}_{o}^{A*} + h - t}}{\theta }} \right\} \le \hat{p}_{r}^{A*} \le \frac{{\hat{p}_{o}^{A*} + h}}{\theta }\).

  2. (2)

    Structure B:

    We take the same procedure as Structure A to solve the problem. First, given wholesale price \(\hat{w}^{B}\), we derive the optimal retail prices \(\hat{p}_{o}^{B}\) and \(\hat{p}_{r}^{B}\). Second, we determine the optimal wholesale price \(\hat{w}^{B}\). The manufacturer and the retailer’s profit can be written as:

    $$ \hat{\pi }_{m}^{B} = \alpha \left( {1 - \frac{{\hat{p}_{o}^{B} - \theta \hat{p}_{r}^{B} + h}}{t}} \right)\hat{w}^{B} + \left( {\alpha \theta \frac{{\hat{p}_{o}^{B} - \theta \hat{p}_{r}^{B} + h}}{t} + \theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\frac{{\theta \left( {v - \hat{p}_{r}^{B} } \right)}}{t}} \right)\left( {\hat{p}_{r}^{B} - c_{r} } \right), $$

    \(\hat{\pi }_{o}^{B} = \alpha \left( {1 - \frac{{\hat{p}_{o}^{B} - \theta \hat{p}_{r}^{B} + h}}{t}} \right)\left( {\hat{p}_{o}^{B} - \hat{w}^{B} } \right)\), respectively.

    Since \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \hat{\pi }_{o}^{B} }}{{\left( {\partial \hat{p}_{o}^{B} } \right)^{2} }} = - \frac{2\alpha }{t} < 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \hat{\pi }_{m}^{B} }}{{\left( {\partial \hat{p}_{r}^{B} } \right)^{2} }} = - \frac{{2\theta^{2} }}{t} < 0\), by solving \(\frac{{\partial \hat{\pi }_{o}^{B} }}{{\partial \hat{p}_{o}^{B} }} = 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial \hat{\pi }_{m}^{B} }}{{\partial \hat{p}_{r}^{B} }} = 0\), we can derive the equilibrium prices are:

    $$ \hat{p}_{r}^{B} = \frac{{\left( {h + t + 3\hat{w}^{B} } \right)\alpha + 2\left( {c_{r} + v - v\alpha } \right)\theta }}{{\left( {4 - \alpha } \right)\theta }}, $$
    (A3)
    $$ \hat{p}_{o}^{B} = \frac{{2t - h\left( {2 - \alpha } \right) + \hat{w}^{B} \left( {2 + \alpha } \right) + \left( {c_{r} + v - v\alpha } \right)\theta }}{4 - \alpha }. $$
    (A4)

    Then, the manufacturer’s profit can be written as follow:

    $$ \hat{\pi }_{m}^{B} = \frac{1}{{t\left( {4 - \alpha } \right)^{2} }}\left( \begin{gathered} \left( {\left( {h + t} \right)^{2} + 8h\hat{w}^{B} + 7\left( {\hat{w}^{B} } \right)^{2} } \right)\alpha^{2} + \hat{w}^{B} \left( {t + \hat{w}^{B} } \right)\alpha^{3} - 8\alpha \hat{w}^{B} \left( {h - t + \hat{w}^{B} } \right) \hfill \\ - \alpha \theta c_{r} \left( {2\left( {h + t} \right)\left( {2 - \alpha } \right) + \hat{w}^{B} \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\alpha } \right) + \left( {c_{r} \left( {2 - \alpha } \right) - 2v\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)^{2} \theta^{2} \hfill \\ + \alpha \theta v\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {4h + 4t + \hat{w}^{B} \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)} \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right). $$

    Since \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \hat{\pi }_{m}^{B} }}{{\left( {\partial \hat{w}^{B} } \right)^{2} }} = - \frac{{2\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\alpha }}{{t\left( {4 - \alpha } \right)^{2} }} < 0\), by solving \(\frac{{\partial \hat{\pi }_{m}^{B} }}{{\partial \hat{w}^{B} }} = 0\), we can derive the best response functions as follows:\(\hat{w}^{B*} = \frac{{8h\left( {1 - \alpha } \right) - t\left( {8 + \alpha^{2} } \right) + \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {c_{r} \alpha - v\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)} \right)\theta }}{{2\left( {7\alpha + \alpha^{2} - 8} \right)}}\).

    Substituting the equilibrium prices \(\hat{w}^{B*}\) into (A3) and (A4), we can obtain the table of lemma 1 under structure B. Note that, all the subsequent calculations are conducted under such constraints: \(\hat{p}_{o}^{B*} + h \le \theta v\), \(\hat{p}_{r}^{B*} \le v\) and \(\min \left\{ {\frac{\theta v - t}{\theta },\frac{{\hat{p}_{o}^{B*} + h - t}}{\theta }} \right\} \le \hat{p}_{r}^{B*} \le \frac{{\hat{p}_{o}^{B*} + h}}{\theta }\). □

Proof of Theorem 1

  1. (1)

    Structure A

    We apply the backward induction to solve for the optimal price strategies of the manufacturer and the independently offline retailer. First, given wholesale price \(w^{A}\), we derive the optimal retail prices \(p_{o}^{A}\) and \(p_{r}^{A}\). Second, we determine the optimal wholesale price \(w^{A}\). The manufacturer and the retailer’s profit can be written as:

    $$ \pi_{m}^{A} = \alpha \theta \left( {1 - \frac{{p_{o}^{A} - p_{r}^{A} + h}}{t}} \right)\left( {p_{o}^{A} - c} \right) + \left( {\alpha \theta \frac{{p_{o}^{A} - p_{r}^{A} + h}}{t} + \theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\frac{{\theta \left( {v - p_{r}^{A} } \right)}}{t}} \right)w^{A} , $$

    \(\pi_{r}^{A} = \left( {\alpha \theta \frac{{p_{o}^{A} - p_{r}^{A} + h}}{t} + \theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\frac{{\theta \left( {v - p_{r}^{A} } \right)}}{t}} \right)\left( {p_{r}^{A} - w^{A} - c_{r} } \right)\), respectively.

    Since \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \pi_{r}^{A} }}{{\left( {\partial p_{r}^{A} } \right)^{2} }} = - \frac{{2\left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\theta }}{t} < 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \pi_{m}^{A} }}{{\left( {\partial p_{o}^{A} } \right)^{2} }} = - \frac{2\alpha \theta }{t} < 0\), by solving \(\frac{{\partial \pi_{r}^{A} }}{{\partial p_{r}^{A} }} = 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial \pi_{m}^{A} }}{{\partial p_{o}^{A} }} = 0\), we can derive the equilibrium prices are:

    $$ p_{r}^{A} = \frac{{2\theta \left( {1 + c_{r} + w^{A} } \right) + \alpha \left( {h + t - \theta \left( {2 - w^{A} } \right)} \right)}}{{\theta \left( {4 - \alpha } \right)}}, $$
    (A5)
    $$ p_{o}^{A} = \frac{{\left( {c_{r} + 2c - h + 2t + 3w^{A} } \right)\alpha + \left( {c_{r} + 2c - 2h + 2t + v + 3w^{A} } \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta }}{{3\alpha + 4\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta }}. $$
    (A6)

    Then, the manufacturer’s profit can be written as follow:

    \(\pi_{m}^{A} = \frac{{\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{3} \theta }}{{t\left( {\alpha \left( {3 - 4\theta } \right) + 4\theta } \right)^{2} }}\left( \begin{gathered} w^{A} \left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {3\gamma + 4\theta } \right)\left( {\left( {c - c_{r} + h + t} \right)\gamma - 2\left( {c_{r} - v + w^{A} } \right)\theta } \right) + \hfill \\ \gamma \left( \begin{gathered} \left( {c_{r} - c - h + 2t} \right)\left( {\gamma + \theta } \right) \hfill \\ + \left( {v - c - h - w^{A} } \right)\theta \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)\left( \begin{gathered} \left( {c_{r} - c - h + 2t + 3w^{A} } \right)\left( {\gamma + \theta } \right) \hfill \\ + \left( {v - c - h} \right)\theta \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)\). Since \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \pi_{m}^{A} }}{{\left( {\partial w^{A} } \right)^{2} }} = - \frac{{2\theta^{2} \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\left( {9\alpha + 8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta } \right)}}{{t\left( {\alpha \left( {3 - 4\theta } \right) + 4\theta } \right)^{2} }} < 0\), by solving \(\frac{{\partial \pi_{m}^{A} }}{{\partial w^{A} }} = 0\), we can derive the best response functions as follows:

    $$ w^{A*} = \frac{1}{2}\left( {v - c_{r} + \frac{{\left( {c_{r} + 8\left( {c + h} \right) - 9v} \right)\alpha }}{{9\alpha + 8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta }} + \frac{t\alpha }{{\theta - \alpha \theta }} - \frac{{\left( {c + h - v} \right)\alpha }}{\alpha + \theta - \alpha \theta }} \right). $$

    Substituting the equilibrium prices \(w^{A*}\) into (A5) and (A6), we can obtain the table of theorem 1 under structure A. Note that, to ensure the optimal decisions satisfy the assumptions (a), (b) and (c) in S scenario in subsection 3.1, all the following results are calculated under such constraints: \(p_{o}^{A*} + h \le v\), \(p_{r}^{A*} \le v\) and \(\min \left\{ {\frac{\theta v - t}{\theta },p_{o}^{A*} + h - t} \right\} \le p_{r}^{A*} \le p_{o}^{A*} + h\).

  2. (2)

    Structure B

    We take the same procedure as Structure A to solve this problem. First, given wholesale price \(w^{B}\), we derive the optimal retail prices \(p_{o}^{B}\) and \(p_{r}^{B}\). Second, we determine the optimal wholesale price \(w^{B}\). The manufacturer and the retailer’s profit can be written as:

    $$ \pi_{m}^{B} = \alpha \left( {1 - \frac{{p_{o}^{B} - p_{r}^{B} + h}}{t}} \right)w^{B} + \left( {\alpha \theta \frac{{p_{o}^{B} - p_{r}^{B} + h}}{t} + \theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\frac{{\theta \left( {v - p_{r}^{B} } \right)}}{t}} \right)\left( {p_{r}^{B} - c_{r} } \right), $$

    \(\pi_{o}^{B} = \alpha \left( {1 - \frac{{p_{o}^{B} - p_{r}^{B} + h}}{t}} \right)\left( {p_{o}^{B} - w^{B} - c} \right)\), respectively. Since \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \pi_{o}^{B} }}{{\left( {\partial p_{o}^{B} } \right)^{2} }} = - \frac{2\alpha \theta }{t} < 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \pi_{m}^{B} }}{{\left( {\partial p_{r}^{B} } \right)^{2} }} = - \frac{{2\left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\theta }}{t} < 0\), by solving \(\frac{{\partial \pi_{o}^{B} }}{{\partial p_{o}^{B} }} = 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial \pi_{m}^{B} }}{{\partial p_{r}^{B} }} = 0\), we can derive the equilibrium prices are:

    $$ p_{r}^{B} = \frac{{\left( {2c_{r} + c + h + t + 3w^{B} } \right)\alpha + 2\theta \left( {v + c_{r} } \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)}}{{3\alpha + 4\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)}}, $$
    (A7)
    $$ p_{o}^{B} = \frac{{\left( {c_{r} + 2c - h + 2t + 3w^{B} } \right)\alpha + \left( {c_{r} + 2c - 2h + 2t + v + 2w^{B} } \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta }}{{3\alpha + 4\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)}}. $$
    (A8)

    Let \(\gamma = \frac{\alpha }{1 - \alpha }\). Then the manufacturer’s profit can be written as follows

    $$ \pi_{m}^{B} = \frac{{\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{3} }}{{t\left( {\alpha \left( {3 - 4\theta } \right) + 4\theta } \right)^{2} }}\left( \begin{gathered} w^{B} \theta \gamma \left( {3\gamma + 4\theta } \right)\left( {\left( {c_{r} - c - h + 2t} \right)\left( {\gamma + \theta } \right) + \left( {v - c - h - 2w^{B} } \right)\theta } \right) + \hfill \\ \theta \left( {\left( {c_{r} - c - h - t - 3w^{B} } \right)\gamma + 2\left( {c_{r} - v} \right)\theta } \right)\left( \begin{gathered} \gamma \left( {c_{r} - c - h - t} \right)\left( {\gamma + \theta } \right) \hfill \\ + \left( {2c_{r} - 2v + w^{B} } \right)\gamma \theta + 2\left( {c_{r} - v} \right)\theta^{2} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right) $$

    Since \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \pi_{m}^{B} }}{{\left( {\partial w^{B} } \right)^{2} }} = - \frac{{2\alpha \theta^{2} \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {9\alpha + 8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta } \right)}}{{t\left( {\alpha \left( {3 - 4\theta } \right) + 4\theta } \right)^{2} }} < 0\), by solving \(\frac{{\partial \pi_{m}^{B} }}{{\partial w^{B} }} = 0\), we can derive the best response functions as follows:

    $$ w^{B*} = \frac{{9t\alpha^{2} - \left( {c_{r} + 8\left( {c + h - 2t} \right) - 9v} \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\alpha \theta - 8\left( {c + h - t - v} \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{2} \theta^{2} }}{{2\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {9\alpha + 8\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)}}. $$

    Substituting the equilibrium prices \(w^{B*}\) into (B7) and (B8), we can obtain the table of theorem 1 under structure B. Note that, all the following results are calculated under such constraints: \(p_{o}^{B*} + h \le v\), \(p_{r}^{B*} \le v\) and \(\min \left\{ {\frac{\theta v - t}{\theta },p_{o}^{B*} + h - t} \right\} \le p_{r}^{B*} \le p_{o}^{B*} + h\). □

Proof of Corollary 1

  1. (1)

    According to the equilibrium decisions of Structure A in Table 4, we have

    $$ \frac{{\partial p_{o}^{A*} }}{\partial h} = \frac{{ - 7\alpha - 8\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)}}{{2\left( {9\alpha + 8\theta - 8\alpha \theta } \right)}} < 0,\;\frac{{\partial p_{r}^{A*} }}{\partial h} = \frac{1}{2}\alpha \left( {\frac{{5\alpha + 4\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta }}{{\left( {\alpha + \theta - \alpha \theta } \right)\left( {9\alpha + 8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta } \right)}}} \right) > 0, $$
    $$ \frac{{\partial w^{A*} }}{\partial h} = - \frac{{\alpha^{2} }}{{2\left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\left( {9\alpha + 8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta } \right)}} < 0; $$
  2. (2)

    According to the equilibrium decisions of Structure B in Table 4, we have.

    $$ \frac{{\partial p_{o}^{B*} }}{\partial h} = - \frac{{\alpha \left( {7 - 6\theta } \right) + 6\theta }}{{8\theta + \alpha \left( {9 - 8\theta } \right)}} < 0,\frac{{\partial p_{r}^{B*} }}{\partial h} = - \frac{\alpha }{{9\alpha + 8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta }} < 0,\frac{{\partial w^{B*} }}{\partial h} = - \frac{{4\left( {\alpha + \theta - \alpha \theta } \right)}}{{9\alpha + 8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta }} < 0. $$

Proof of Proposition 1

  1. (1)

    Structure A.

    Taking the difference of the online selling price with and without digital showrooms, we have \(p_{o}^{A*} - \hat{p}_{o}^{A*} = \frac{\begin{gathered} \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {t\gamma \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right) + \theta c\left( {11\gamma + 8\theta } \right)} \right) \hfill \\ - \theta \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {2c_{r} \left( {\gamma \left( {8 + \alpha } \right) + 8\theta } \right) - 16h\alpha - 9v\gamma \left( {8 + \alpha } \right) - 8v\left( {10 - \alpha } \right)\theta } \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} }{{2\theta \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right)}}\).

    Since \(\frac{{\partial \left( {p_{o}^{A*} - \hat{p}_{o}^{A*} } \right)}}{\partial h} = \frac{{8\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)}}{{\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {9\alpha + 8\theta - 8\alpha \theta } \right)}} > 0\), by setting \(p_{o}^{A*} - \hat{p}_{o}^{A*} = 0\), we can derive.

    $$ \begin{aligned} h_{1} & = \frac{1}{16\alpha }\left( {8\left( {2c_{r} - v\left( {10 - \alpha } \right)} \right)\theta - \frac{{\alpha \left( {8t + 9v - 2c_{r} } \right)\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)}}{1 - \alpha } - \frac{{9t\alpha^{2} \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)}}{{\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{2} \theta }} - \frac{{c\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {11\alpha + 8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta } \right)}}{{\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {1 - \theta } \right)}}} \right) \\ & < \left( \begin{gathered} \theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {2c_{r} \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {\alpha^{2} + 8\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + 8\theta } \right) - v\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {\alpha \left( {72 - 88\theta } \right) + 80\theta + \alpha^{2} \left( {9 + 8\theta } \right)} \right)} \right) \hfill \\ - \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {t\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {8\theta + \alpha \left( {9 - 8\theta } \right)} \right) + c\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {8\theta + \alpha \left( {11 - 8\theta } \right)} \right)} \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right) \\ & < - \frac{{\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta }}{{\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta }}\left( \begin{gathered} v\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\theta \left( {3\left( {8 - 5\alpha } \right)\alpha + 16\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{2} \theta } \right) + \theta c\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {19\alpha + 8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta } \right) \hfill \\ + 2c_{r} \left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {3\alpha \left( {8 + \alpha } \right) + 4\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {6 + \alpha } \right)\theta } \right) + \alpha^{2} c\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {12 - \theta } \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right) \\ & < 0. \\ \end{aligned} $$

    To guarantee \(w^{A*} \ge 0\), that is,\(0 < h \le 9v - 8c_{r} - c + 17t - \frac{{8\left( {2c_{r} - t - 2v} \right)\theta }}{\gamma } - \frac{{8\left( {c_{r} - v} \right)\theta^{2} }}{{\gamma^{2} }} + \frac{9t\gamma }{\theta }\). Hence, we have \(p_{o}^{A*} > \hat{p}_{o}^{A*}\).

    Taking the difference of the offline selling price with and without digital showrooms, we have.

    $$ p_{r}^{A*} - \hat{p}_{r}^{A*} = \frac{\alpha }{4}\left( {\frac{{7v + c_{r} + 2v\alpha }}{8 + \alpha } - \frac{{2h\left( {4 + \alpha } \right)}}{{\theta \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)}} + \frac{{9v - c_{r} - 8c - 8h}}{{9\alpha + 8\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)}} - \frac{{2\left( {v - c - h} \right)}}{\alpha + \theta - \alpha \theta }} \right). $$

    Since \(\frac{{\partial \left( {p_{r}^{A*} - \hat{p}_{r}^{A*} } \right)}}{\partial h} = - \frac{{\alpha^{2} \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {28\theta + 4\alpha \left( {9 - 5\theta } \right) + \alpha^{2} \left( {9 - 8\theta } \right)} \right)}}{{2\theta \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\left( {8\theta + \alpha \left( {9 - 8\theta } \right)} \right)}} < 0\), by setting \(p_{r}^{A*} - \hat{p}_{r}^{A*} = 0\), we can derive.

    $$ h_{1}^{A} = \frac{{\theta \left( {c\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {5\gamma + 4\theta } \right) - 4c_{r} \left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\left( {1 - \theta } \right) - v\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {9\gamma \left( {4 + \alpha } \right) + 4\left( {7 + 2\alpha } \right)\theta } \right)} \right)}}{{\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {9\gamma \left( {4 + \alpha } \right) + 4\left( {7 + 2\alpha } \right)\theta } \right)}}. $$

    Hence, if \(h \le h_{1}^{A}\), we have \(p_{r}^{A*} - \hat{p}_{r}^{A*} \ge 0\); otherwise, \(p_{r}^{A*} - \hat{p}_{r}^{A*} < 0\).

    Taking the difference of the wholesale price with and without digital showrooms, we have:

    \(w^{A*} - \hat{w}^{A*} = \frac{\alpha }{2}\left( {\frac{{v - c_{r} - v\alpha }}{8 + \alpha } + \frac{h\alpha }{{\theta \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)}} - \frac{{9v - c_{r} - 8c - 8h}}{{9\alpha + 8\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)}} + \frac{v - c - h}{{\alpha + \theta - \alpha \theta }}} \right)\) and \(\frac{{\partial \left( {w^{A*} - \hat{w}^{A*} } \right)}}{\partial h} = - \frac{{\alpha^{2} \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{2} - 9\alpha^{2} } \right)}}{{2\theta \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\left( {8\theta + \alpha \left( {9 - 8\theta } \right)} \right)}}\).

    If \(\theta \le \frac{{9\alpha^{2} }}{{8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{2} }}\), then \(\frac{{\partial \left( {w^{A*} - \hat{w}^{A*} } \right)}}{\partial h} > 0\). By setting \(w^{A*} - \hat{w}^{A*} = 0\), we can derive.

    $$ h_{2}^{A} = \frac{{\theta \left( {c\gamma \left( {8 + \alpha } \right) - 8c_{r} \left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\left( {1 - \theta } \right) - v\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{2} \left( {9\gamma^{2} - 8\theta } \right)} \right)}}{{\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {9\gamma^{2} - 8\theta } \right)}}. $$

    Hence, when \(h \le h_{2}^{A}\), we have \(w^{A*} - \hat{w}^{A*} \le 0\); otherwise, \(w^{A*} - \hat{w}^{A*} > 0\).

    If \(\theta > \frac{{9\alpha^{2} }}{{8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{2} }}\), then \(\frac{{\partial \left( {w^{A*} - \hat{w}^{A*} } \right)}}{\partial h} < 0\). Hence, when \(h \le h_{2}^{A}\), we have \(w^{A*} - \hat{w}^{A*} \ge 0\); otherwise, \(w^{A*} - \hat{w}^{A*} < 0\).

    In summary, when \(\theta \le \frac{{9\gamma^{2} }}{8} \wedge h \ge h_{2}^{A}\) or \(\theta \ge \frac{{9\gamma^{2} }}{8} \wedge h \ge h_{2}^{A}\), \(w^{A*} - \hat{w}^{A*} \le 0\); otherwise, \(w^{A*} - \hat{w}^{A*} > 0\).

  2. (2)

    Structure B.

    Taking the difference of the online selling price with and without digital showrooms, we have the following derivations.

    $$ \begin{aligned} p_{o}^{B*} - \hat{p}_{o}^{B*} & = \frac{{\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {2h\left( {6 + \alpha } \right) - \theta c_{r} \left( {4 + \alpha } \right) - v\theta \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)} \right) - t\left( {12 - \alpha \left( {2 + \alpha } \right)} \right)}}{{2\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)}} \\ & \; + \frac{{9t\gamma^{2} + \left( {5c_{r} + 4c - 14h + 22t + 9v} \right)\gamma \theta + 4\left( {c_{r} + c - 3h + 3t + 2v} \right)\theta^{2} }}{{2\theta \left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right)}}. \\ \end{aligned} $$

    Since \(\frac{{\partial \left( {p_{o}^{B*} - \hat{p}_{o}^{B*} } \right)}}{\partial h} = - \frac{{2\alpha \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {1 - \theta } \right)}}{{\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {9\alpha + 8\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)}} < 0\), by setting \(p_{o}^{B*} - \hat{p}_{o}^{B*} = 0\), we can derive \(h_{2} = \frac{1}{4\alpha }\left( \begin{gathered} \left( {\left( {5c_{r} + 9v} \right)\left( {8 + \alpha } \right) + 4t\left( {17 + \alpha } \right)} \right)\gamma + 4c\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\frac{\gamma + \theta }{{\left( {1 - \theta } \right)}} \hfill \\ + \frac{{9t\gamma^{2} \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)}}{\theta } + 8\left( {c_{r} \left( {4 + \alpha } \right) + v\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)} \right)\theta \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)\).

    To guarantee \(w^{B*} \ge 0\), that is \(h \le \frac{{9t\alpha^{2} - \left( {c_{r} + 8c - 16t - 9v} \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\alpha \theta + 8\left( {v - c + t} \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{2} \theta^{2} }}{{8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\theta }} = \widehat{h}\).

    Then we have.

    $$ \widehat{h} - h_{2} = \frac{{ - \left( {9\alpha + 8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta } \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{2} }}{{8\alpha \theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{2} \left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\left( {1 - \theta } \right)}}\left( \begin{gathered} \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {t\gamma + v\theta } \right)\left( {3\gamma \left( {5 + \alpha } \right) + 2\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\theta } \right) \hfill \\ + c_{r} \theta \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {\gamma \left( {9 + \alpha } \right) + 2\left( {4 + \alpha } \right)\theta } \right) + 8c\theta \left( {\gamma + \theta } \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right) < 0. $$

    Hence, \(p_{o}^{B*} - \hat{p}_{o}^{B*} > 0\) can always be satisfied.

    Taking the difference of the offline selling price with and without digital showrooms, we have the following derivations.

    $$ p_{r}^{B*} - \hat{p}_{r}^{B*} = \frac{{\alpha \left( {\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {9\alpha \left( {h - t} \right) + 8\theta c_{r} \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right) - \theta c\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)} \right)}}{{\theta \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {9\alpha + 8\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)}}. $$

    Since \(\frac{{\partial \left( {p_{r}^{B*} - \hat{p}_{r}^{B*} } \right)}}{\partial h} = \frac{{9\alpha^{2} \left( {1 - \theta } \right)}}{{\theta \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {9\alpha + 8\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)}} > 0\), by setting \(p_{r}^{B*} - \hat{p}_{r}^{B*} = 0\), we can derive \(h_{1}^{B} = t + \frac{{\theta \left( {c\left( {8 + \alpha } \right) - 8c_{r} \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {1 - \theta } \right)} \right)}}{{9\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right)}}\). Hence, when \(h \le h_{1}^{B}\), we have \(p_{r}^{B*} - \hat{p}_{r}^{B*} \le 0\); otherwise, \(p_{r}^{B*} - \hat{p}_{r}^{B*} > 0\).

    Taking the difference of the wholesale price with and without digital showrooms, we have the following derivations:

    $$ w^{B*} - \hat{w}^{B*} = \frac{1}{2}\left( \begin{gathered} \frac{{t\left( {8 + \alpha^{2} } \right) - \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {8h + c_{r} \alpha \theta - v\theta \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)} \right)}}{{7\alpha + \alpha^{2} - 8}} \hfill \\ + \frac{{9t\gamma^{2} - \left( {c_{r} + 8\left( {c + h - 2t} \right) - 9v} \right)\gamma \theta - 8\left( {c + h - t - v} \right)\theta^{2} }}{{\theta \left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right)}} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right). $$

    Since \(\frac{{\partial \left( {w^{B*} - \hat{w}^{B*} } \right)}}{\partial h} = \frac{{4\alpha \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {1 - \theta } \right)}}{{\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {9\alpha + 8\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)}} > 0\), by setting \(w^{B*} - \hat{w}^{B*} = 0\), we can derive.

    $$ h_{2}^{B} = \frac{\begin{gathered} \gamma \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {\theta c_{r} \left( {8 + \alpha + 8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta } \right) - 9t\gamma \left( {8 + \alpha } \right) - 8t\left( {7 + 2\alpha } \right)\theta } \right) \hfill \\ + \theta \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {8c\gamma + 8c\theta - v\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right)} \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} }{{8\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\theta }}. $$

    Hence, when \(h_{2}^{B} \le 0\), \(w^{B*} - \hat{w}^{B*} \le 0\); otherwise, \(w^{B*} - \hat{w}^{B*} > 0\). □

Proof of Proposition 2

  1. (1)

    Structure A.

    Taking the difference of the online demand with and without digital showrooms, we have the following derivations.

    $$ D_{o}^{A*} - \hat{D}_{o}^{A*} = \frac{\alpha }{2t}\left( \begin{gathered} \frac{{h\left( {8 - \alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right) - t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right) - \left( {6c_{r} + v\left( {2 - \alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right)} \right)\theta }}{8 + \alpha } \hfill \\ + \frac{{\theta \left( \begin{gathered} 3\left( {2c_{r} - 2\left( {c + h} \right) + 3t} \right)\gamma^{2} \hfill \\ + \left( {12c_{r} - 15\left( {c + h} \right) + 17t + 3v} \right)\gamma \theta + 2\left( {3c_{r} - 4\left( {c + h - t} \right) + v} \right)\theta^{2} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{\left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right)}} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right). $$

    Since.

    $$ \begin{aligned} \frac{{\partial \left( {D_{o}^{A*} - \hat{D}_{o}^{A*} } \right)}}{\partial h} & = - \frac{{\alpha \left( \begin{gathered} 9\alpha^{2} \left( { - 8 + \alpha + \alpha^{2} } \right) - \alpha \left( {136 - \alpha \left( {201 + \left( {6 - 17\alpha } \right)\alpha } \right)} \right)\theta \hfill \\ - \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {64 - \alpha \left( {192 + \alpha \left( {15 - 8\alpha } \right)} \right)} \right)\theta^{2} + 8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{2} \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\theta^{3} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{2t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\left( {8\theta + \alpha \left( {9 - 8\theta } \right)} \right)}} \\ & > \frac{{\alpha^{2} \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {9\alpha \left( {8 - \alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right) + \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {136 + \alpha \left( {7 - 8\alpha } \right)} \right)\theta } \right)}}{{2t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\left( {8\theta + \alpha \left( {9 - 8\theta } \right)} \right)}} > 0, \\ \end{aligned} $$

    by setting \(D_{o}^{A*} - \hat{D}_{o}^{A*} = 0\), we can derive.

    $$ h_{o}^{A} = \frac{{\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( \begin{gathered} \left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right) + 6\theta \alpha c_{r} } \right) \hfill \\ + \theta \alpha v\left( {9\gamma \left( {2 + \alpha } \right) + 2\left( {5 + 4\alpha } \right)\theta } \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right) + \theta c\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {6\gamma^{2} + 15\gamma \theta + 8\theta^{2} } \right)}}{{\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {9\gamma^{2} \left( {8 - \alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right) + \gamma \left( {136 + \alpha \left( {7 - 8\alpha } \right)} \right)\theta + 8\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\theta^{2} } \right)}}. $$

    Hence, when \(h \le h_{o}^{A}\), \(D_{o}^{A*} - \hat{D}_{o}^{A*} \le 0\); otherwise, \(D_{o}^{A*} - \hat{D}_{o}^{A*} > 0\).

    Taking the difference of the offline demand with and without digital showrooms, we have the following derivations.

    $$ D_{r}^{A*} - \hat{D}_{r}^{A*} = \frac{{\theta \left( {2 + \alpha } \right)\left( {\theta c_{r} - h\alpha - v\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)}}{{t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)}} + \frac{{\theta \left( {3\gamma + 2\theta } \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {\left( {c - c_{r} + h} \right)\gamma - \left( {c_{r} - v} \right)\theta } \right)}}{9t\gamma + 8t\theta }. $$

    Since \(\frac{{\partial \left( {D_{r}^{A*} - \hat{D}_{r}^{A*} } \right)}}{\partial h} = \frac{{6\alpha^{2} \theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {1 - \theta } \right)}}{{t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {9\alpha + 8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta } \right)}} > 0\), by setting \(D_{r}^{A*} - \hat{D}_{r}^{A*} = 0\), we can derive.

    $$ h_{r}^{A} = \frac{{c_{r} \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {3\gamma \left( {8 + \alpha } \right) + 2\left( {11 + \alpha } \right)\theta } \right) - 6v\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\theta - c\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {3\gamma + 2\theta } \right)}}{{6\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right)}}. $$

    Hence, when \(h \le h_{r}^{A}\), we have \(D_{r}^{A*} - \hat{D}_{r}^{A*} \le 0\); otherwise, \(D_{r}^{A*} - \hat{D}_{r}^{A*} > 0\).

    Taking the difference of the total market demand with and without digital showrooms, we have the following derivations.

    $$ D_{m}^{A*} - \hat{D}_{m}^{A*} = \frac{1}{2t}\left( \begin{gathered} \frac{{\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( \begin{gathered} 9t\gamma^{3} - \left( {4c_{r} + 5c + 5h - 17t - 9v} \right)\gamma^{2} \theta \hfill \\ - 4\left( {2c_{r} + c + h - 2t - 3v} \right)\gamma \theta^{2} - 4\left( {c_{r} - v} \right)\theta^{3} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{\left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right)\left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)}} \hfill \\ - \frac{{t\alpha \left( {8 + \alpha } \right) + 6c_{r} \alpha \theta - h\alpha \left( {8 - \alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right) + \theta \left( {2 + \alpha } \right)\left( {2h\alpha - 2c_{r} \theta + v\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {\alpha + 2\theta } \right)} \right)}}{8 + \alpha } \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right). $$

    Since\(\frac{{\partial \left( {D_{m}^{A*} - \hat{D}_{m}^{A*} } \right)}}{\partial h} = \frac{{\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( \begin{gathered} 9\alpha^{2} \left( {8 - \alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right) \hfill \\ + \alpha \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {136 + \alpha \left( {19 - 8\alpha } \right)} \right)\theta + 4\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{2} \left( {16 + 5\alpha } \right)\theta^{2} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{2t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\left( {9\alpha + 8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta } \right)}} > 0\), by setting \(D_{m}^{A*} - \hat{D}_{m}^{A*} = 0\), we can derive

    $$ h_{3}^{A} = \frac{{\left( \begin{gathered} \left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right) + 2\theta c_{r} \left( {27\gamma + 2\left( {11 + \alpha } \right)\theta } \right)} \right) + + \theta^{2} c\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {5\gamma + 4\theta } \right) \hfill \\ + \theta v\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {9\gamma^{2} \left( {2 + \alpha } \right) - 2\gamma \left( {1 - 4\alpha } \right)\theta - 12\theta^{2} } \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {9\gamma^{2} \left( {8 - \alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right) + \gamma \left( {136 + \alpha \left( {19 - 8\alpha } \right)} \right)\theta + 4\left( {16 + 5\alpha } \right)\theta^{2} } \right)}} $$

    Hence, when \(h \le h_{3}^{A}\), we have \(D_{m}^{A*} - \hat{D}_{m}^{A*} \le 0\); otherwise, \(D_{m}^{A*} - \hat{D}_{m}^{A*} > 0\).

  2. (2)

    Structure B.

    Taking the difference of the online demand with and without digital showrooms, we have the following derivations:

    $$ D_{o}^{B*} - \hat{D}_{o}^{B*} = \frac{{\alpha \left( {2 + \alpha } \right)\left( {h - t - \theta c_{r} } \right)}}{{t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)}} + \frac{{\alpha \theta \left( {c_{r} - c - h + t} \right)\left( {3\alpha + 2\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)}}{{9t\alpha + 8t\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)}}. $$

    Since \(\frac{{\partial \left( {D_{o}^{B*} - \hat{D}_{o}^{B*} } \right)}}{\partial h} = \frac{{\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {9\alpha \left( {2 + \alpha } \right) + 2\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\theta } \right)}}{{t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {9\alpha + 8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta } \right)}} > 0\), by setting \(D_{o}^{B*} - \hat{D}_{o}^{B*} = 0\), we can derive \(h_{o}^{B} = t - \frac{{\theta \left( {6c_{r} \alpha \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {1 - \theta } \right) - c\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {3\alpha + 2\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)} \right)}}{{\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {9\alpha \left( {2 + \alpha } \right) + 2\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)} \right)}}\). Hence, when \(h \le h_{o}^{B}\), we have \(D_{o}^{B*} - \hat{D}_{o}^{B*} \le 0\); otherwise, \(D_{o}^{B*} - \hat{D}_{o}^{B*} > 0\).

    Taking the difference of the offline demand with and without digital showrooms, we have the following derivations.

    $$ D_{r}^{B*} - \hat{D}_{r}^{B*} = \frac{{3\alpha \theta \left( {\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {\alpha c - \alpha c_{r} \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta c\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right) - \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {\alpha \left( {h - t} \right) + 8\theta c_{r} } \right)} \right)}}{{t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {9\alpha + 8\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)}}. $$

    Since \(\frac{{\partial \left( {D_{r}^{B*} - \hat{D}_{r}^{B*} } \right)}}{\partial h} = - \frac{{3\alpha^{2} \theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {1 - \theta } \right)}}{{t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {9\alpha + 8\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)}} < 0\), by setting \(D_{r}^{B*} - \hat{D}_{r}^{B*} = 0\), we can derive \(h_{r}^{B} = \frac{{t\alpha - 8\theta c_{r} }}{\alpha } - \frac{{\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {\alpha c_{r} \left( {1 - \theta } \right) - c\left( {\alpha + \theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)} \right)}}{{\alpha \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {1 - \theta } \right)}}\). Hence, when \(h \le h_{r}^{B}\), we have \(D_{r}^{B*} - \hat{D}_{r}^{B*} \ge 0\); otherwise, \(D_{r}^{B*} - \hat{D}_{r}^{B*} < 0\).

    Taking the difference of the total market demand with and without digital showrooms, we have the following derivations:

    $$ D_{m}^{B*} - \hat{D}_{m}^{B*} = \frac{{\alpha \left( {\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( \begin{gathered} \left( {h - t} \right)\left( {9\alpha \left( {2 + \alpha } \right) + \theta \left( {16 - \alpha } \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right) \hfill \\ - 3\theta c_{r} \left( {3\alpha \left( {2 + \alpha } \right) + 8\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right) + \theta^{2} c\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)} \right)}}{{t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {9\alpha + 8\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)}}. $$

    Since \(\frac{{\partial \left( {D_{m}^{B*} - \hat{D}_{m}^{B*} } \right)}}{\partial h} = \frac{{\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {9\alpha \left( {2 + \alpha } \right) + \theta \left( {16 - \alpha } \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)}}{{t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {9\alpha + 8\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)}} > 0\), by setting \(D_{m}^{B*} - \hat{D}_{m}^{B*} = 0\), we can derive.

    $$ h_{3}^{B} = t - \frac{{\theta \left( {c\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {8 + \alpha } \right) - 3c_{r} \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {3\alpha \left( {2 + \alpha } \right) + 8\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)} \right)}}{{\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {9\alpha \left( {2 + \alpha } \right) + \theta \left( {16 - \alpha } \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)}}. $$

    Hence, when \(h_{3}^{B} \le 0\), we have \(D_{m}^{B*} - \hat{D}_{m}^{B*} \le 0\); otherwise, \(D_{m}^{B*} - \hat{D}_{m}^{B*} > 0\). □

Proof of Corollary 2

  1. (1)

    Structure A.

    $$ \frac{{\partial \omega_{{}}^{A} }}{\partial h} = \frac{{\alpha \theta \left( {6\alpha^{2} + 15\alpha \theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right) + 8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{2} \theta^{2} } \right)}}{{2t\left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\left( {9\alpha + 8\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)}} > 0. $$
    $$ \frac{{\partial \omega_{{}}^{A} }}{\partial t} = \frac{{\alpha \theta \left( {6\left( {c_{r} - c - h} \right)\alpha^{2} + 3\left( {4c_{r} - 5\left( {c + h} \right) + v} \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\alpha \theta + 2\left( {3c_{r} - 4\left( {c + h} \right) + v} \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{2} \theta^{2} } \right)}}{{2t^{2} \left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\left( {9\alpha - 8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta } \right)}} $$

    and \(\frac{{\partial \left( {\frac{{\partial \omega_{{}}^{A} }}{\partial t}} \right)}}{\partial h} = - \frac{{\alpha \theta \left( {6\alpha^{2} + 15\alpha \theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right) + 8\theta^{2} \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{2} } \right)}}{{2t^{2} \left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\left( {9\alpha + 8\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)}} < 0\). By solving \(\frac{{\partial \omega_{{}}^{A} }}{\partial t} = 0\), we can obtain \(\overline{h}_{{}}^{A} = \frac{{6\left( {c_{r} - c} \right)\alpha^{2} + 3\left( {v + 4c_{r} - 5c} \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\alpha \theta + 2\left( {v + 3c_{r} - 4c} \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{2} \theta^{2} }}{{6\alpha^{2} + 15\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\alpha \theta + 8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{2} \theta^{2} }}\).

    Hence, when \(h \le \overline{h}_{{}}^{A}\), we have \(\frac{{\partial \omega_{{}}^{A} }}{\partial t} \ge 0\); otherwise, \(\frac{{\partial \omega_{{}}^{A} }}{\partial t} < 0\).

  2. (2)

    Structure B

    $$ \frac{{\partial \omega_{{}}^{B} }}{\partial h} = \frac{{\alpha \theta \left( {3\alpha + 2\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)}}{{t\left( {9\alpha + 8\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)}} > 0. $$

    \(\frac{{\partial \omega_{{}}^{B} }}{\partial t} = \frac{{\alpha \theta \left( {c_{r} - c - h} \right)\left( {3\alpha + 2\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)}}{{t^{2} \left( {9\alpha + 8\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)}}\). Hence when \(h \le \overline{h}^{B} = c_{r} - c\), we have \(\frac{{\partial \omega_{{}}^{B} }}{\partial t} \ge 0\); otherwise, \(\frac{{\partial \omega_{{}}^{B} }}{\partial t} < 0\). □

Proof of Proposition 3

  1. (1)

    Structure A.

    Taking the difference of the retailer’s profit between with and without digital showrooms, we have the following derivations.

    $$ \pi_{r}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{r}^{A*} = \frac{{\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)}}{t}\left( {\frac{{\theta \left( {3\gamma + 2\theta } \right)^{2} \left( {c\gamma + h\gamma + v\theta - c_{r} \left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)} \right)^{2} }}{{\left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right)^{2} }} - \frac{{\left( {2 + 3\gamma } \right)^{2} \left( {h\gamma - \left( {c_{r} - v + c_{r} \gamma } \right)\theta } \right)^{2} }}{{\left( {1 + \gamma } \right)\left( {8 + 9\gamma } \right)^{2} }}} \right). $$

    Since \(\begin{gathered} \frac{{\partial^{2} \left( {\pi_{r}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{r}^{A*} } \right)}}{{\partial h^{2} }} = - \frac{{2\alpha^{3} \left( \begin{gathered} 81\alpha^{2} \left( {2 + \alpha } \right)^{2} + 9\alpha \left( {36 - \alpha \left( {16 + \alpha \left( {76 + 25\alpha } \right)} \right)} \right)\theta \hfill \\ + 4\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {16 - \alpha \left( {48 + \alpha \left( {159 + 52\alpha } \right)} \right)} \right)\theta^{2} \hfill \\ - 4\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{2} \left( {16 + \alpha \left( {49 + 16\alpha } \right)} \right)\theta^{3} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)^{2} \left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\left( {\alpha \left( {9 - 8\theta } \right) + 8\theta } \right)^{2} }} \\ < - \frac{{18\alpha^{4} \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {9\alpha \left( {2 + \alpha } \right)^{2} + 4\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {9 + 2\alpha \left( {7 + 2\alpha } \right)} \right)\theta } \right)}}{{t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)^{2} \left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\left( {\alpha \left( {9 - 8\theta } \right) + 8\theta } \right)^{2} }} < 0 \\ \end{gathered}\), by setting \(\pi_{r}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{r}^{A*} = 0\), we can derive.

    $$ h_{4}^{A} = \frac{{M + \theta \left( {1 + \gamma } \right)\left( {c\left( {8 + 9\gamma } \right)^{2} \left( {3\gamma + 2\theta } \right)^{2} - 12c_{r} \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {16\theta + 3\gamma \left( {7 + 9\gamma + 7\theta } \right)} \right)} \right)}}{{\gamma \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {81\gamma^{2} \left( {2 + 3\gamma } \right)^{2} + 36\gamma \left( {9 + \gamma \left( {32 + 27\gamma } \right)} \right)\theta + 4\left( {16 + 81\gamma \left( {1 + \gamma } \right)} \right)\theta^{2} } \right)}} - \frac{v\theta }{\gamma }, $$

    wherein \(M = \left( {2 + 3\gamma } \right)\left( {8 + 9\gamma } \right)\left( {3\gamma + 2\theta } \right)\left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right)\sqrt {\left( {1 + \gamma } \right)\left( {c - c_{r} \left( {1 - \theta } \right)} \right)^{2} \theta \left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)}\). Thus, when \(h \le h_{4}^{A}\), we have \(\pi_{r}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{r}^{A*} \ge 0\); otherwise, \(\pi_{r}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{r}^{A*} < 0\).

    Taking the difference of the manufacturer’s profit between with and without digital showrooms, we have \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \left( {\pi_{m}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A*} } \right)}}{{\partial h^{2} }} = - \frac{{\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( \begin{gathered} 9\alpha^{2} \left( {8 - \alpha \left( {3 + \alpha } \right)} \right) \hfill \\ + \alpha \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {136 - \alpha \left( {11 + 8\alpha } \right)} \right)\theta + 8\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{2} \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\theta^{2} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{2t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\left( {8\theta + \alpha \left( {9 - 8\theta } \right)} \right)}} < 0\), by setting \(\pi_{m}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A*} = 0\), we can derive.

    $$ h_{5}^{A} = C - \sqrt {\begin{gathered} C + 2\left( {1 + \gamma } \right)\left( {8 + 9\gamma } \right)\left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right)\left( {t^{2} \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + 2\theta c_{r} } \right) \hfill \\ - 2v^{2} \theta^{2} \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {28\theta + 9\gamma \left( {4 + 5\gamma + 4\theta } \right)} \right) - 16v\theta^{2} c_{r} \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {1 + \gamma } \right) \hfill \\ - 2c\theta \left( {1 + \gamma } \right)\left( {8 + 9\gamma } \right)\left( {c\left( {4\gamma^{2} + 13\gamma \theta + 8\theta^{2} } \right) - 8c_{r} \left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)^{2} - 2v\theta \left( {5\gamma + 4\theta } \right)} \right) \hfill \\ - 8c_{r}^{2} \theta \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {1 + \gamma } \right)\left( {7\theta + 8\gamma + 9\gamma^{2} + 8\theta \gamma } \right). \hfill \\ \end{gathered} }$$

    where \(C = \frac{{\left( \begin{gathered} \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {1 + \gamma } \right)\left( {t\left( {8 + 9\gamma } \right)\left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right) + 4\theta \gamma c_{r} } \right) \hfill \\ + \theta c\left( {1 + \gamma } \right)\left( {8 + 9\gamma } \right)\left( {4\gamma^{2} + 13\gamma \theta + 8\theta^{2} } \right) + \theta v\gamma \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {28\theta + 9\gamma \left( {4 + 5\gamma + 4\theta } \right)} \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {9\gamma^{2} \left( {8 + \gamma \left( {13 + 4\gamma } \right)} \right) + \gamma \left( {136 + 9\gamma \left( {29 + 13\gamma } \right)} \right)\theta + 8\left( {1 + \gamma } \right)\left( {8 + 9\gamma } \right)\theta^{2} } \right)}}\).

    Hence, if \(h \le h_{5}^{A}\), we have \(\pi_{m}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A*} \le 0\); otherwise, \(\pi_{m}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A*} > 0\).

    Since \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \left( {\pi_{r}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{r}^{A*} } \right)}}{{\partial h^{2} }}{ + }\frac{{\partial^{2} \left( {\pi_{m}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A*} } \right)}}{{\partial h^{2} }} < 0\), by setting \(\left( {\pi_{r}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{r}^{A*} } \right) + \left( {\pi_{m}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A*} } \right) = 0\), we can derive the threshold.

    $$ h_{6}^{A} = E - \sqrt {E - F\left( \begin{gathered} \left( {t^{2} - \theta t^{2} + 2c_{r} \theta } \right)\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)^{2} \left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right)^{2} - 12\theta^{4} \left( {128 - \alpha \left( {384 - 15\alpha - 52\alpha^{2} } \right)} \right) \hfill \\ + 48\theta^{5} \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {32 - \alpha - 4\alpha^{2} } \right) - 27\gamma \theta^{3} \left( {2 - \alpha } \right)\left( {56 - 58\alpha - 25\alpha^{2} } \right) \hfill \\ - \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)^{2} \left( {72\theta c^{2} \gamma^{3} + \gamma^{2} \theta^{2} c\left( {197c - 18} \right) + 4\gamma \theta^{3} c\left( {43c - 14} \right) + 32\theta^{4} c\left( {2c - 1} \right)} \right) \hfill \\ - 8\theta c_{r} \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)^{2} \left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {9c_{r} \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\gamma^{2} - c\left( {18\gamma^{2} + 29\gamma \theta + 12\theta^{2} } \right)} \right) + 81\theta^{2} \gamma^{2} \alpha \left( {20 - \alpha - 3\alpha^{2} } \right) \hfill \\ - 4c_{r}^{2} \theta^{2} \left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {\gamma \left( {2036 + \alpha \left( {527 + 29\alpha } \right)} \right) + 4\left( {224 + \alpha \left( {61 + 3\alpha } \right)} \right)\theta } \right) \hfill \\ + 8c_{r} \theta^{2} \left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {9\gamma \left( {20 + 7\alpha } \right) + 4\left( {32 + 13\alpha } \right)\theta } \right) - 1296\theta^{2} \gamma^{2} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)} , $$

    where

    $$ E = F\left( \begin{gathered} t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)^{2} \left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right)^{2} + 16\left( {4c\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)^{2} - 32\left( {3 - c_{r} } \right)\alpha + \alpha^{2} \left( {3 + 13c_{r} + 12\alpha } \right)} \right)\theta^{4} \hfill \\ + 9\theta \gamma^{3} \left( {8c\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)^{2} - 4c_{r} \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {20 + 7\alpha } \right) + 9\left( {16 - \alpha \left( {20 - \alpha - 3\alpha^{2} } \right)} \right)} \right) \hfill \\ + \gamma^{2} \left( {197c\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)^{2} + 27\left( {2 - \alpha } \right)\left( {56 - \alpha \left( {58 + 25\alpha } \right)} \right) - 4c_{r} \left( {308 - \alpha \left( {373 + 178\alpha } \right)} \right)} \right)\theta^{2} \hfill \\ + 4\gamma \left( {384 + 48c\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)^{2} - 3\alpha \left( {384 - \alpha \left( {15 + 52\alpha } \right)} \right) - c_{r} \left( {128 - \alpha \left( {384 + 167\alpha } \right)} \right)} \right)\theta^{3} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right), $$
    $$ F = \frac{{\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)}}{\begin{gathered} \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {81\gamma^{3} \left( {64 + \alpha^{2} \left( {5 + 3\alpha } \right)} \right) - 64\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)^{2} \theta^{4} } \right) + 9\theta \gamma^{2} \left( {1600 - \alpha \left( {2112 + \alpha \left( {3 + \alpha \left( {58 + 75\alpha } \right)} \right)} \right)} \right) \hfill \\ + \theta^{2} \gamma \left( {13312 - \alpha \left( {25920 + \alpha \left( {2112 + \alpha \left( {613 + 624\alpha } \right)} \right)} \right)} \right) + 64\left( {64 - \alpha \left( {256 + \alpha \left( {43 + \alpha \left( {5 + 3\alpha } \right)} \right)} \right)} \right)\theta^{3} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} }. $$

    Hence, if \(h \le h_{6}^{A}\), we have \(\left( {\pi_{r}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{r}^{A*} } \right) + \left( {\pi_{m}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A*} } \right) \ge 0\); otherwise, \(\left( {\pi_{r}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{r}^{A*} } \right) + \left( {\pi_{m}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A*} } \right) < 0\).

  2. (2)

    Structure B.

    Taking the difference of the retailer’s profit between with and without digital showrooms, we have \(\pi_{o}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{o}^{B*} = \frac{\alpha }{t}\left( {\frac{{\left( {c_{r} - c - h + t} \right)^{2} \theta \left( {3\gamma + 2\theta } \right)^{2} }}{{\left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right)^{2} }} - \frac{{\left( {2 + 3\gamma } \right)^{2} \left( {h - t - \theta c_{r} } \right)^{2} }}{{\left( {8 + 9\gamma } \right)^{2} }}} \right)\).

    Since \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \left( {\pi_{o}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{o}^{B*} } \right)}}{{\partial h^{2} }} = \frac{{2\gamma \left( \begin{gathered} 4\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)^{2} \theta^{3} - 81\alpha \gamma \left( {2 + \alpha } \right)^{2} \hfill \\ - 9\gamma \theta \left( {64\left( {1 - \alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right) - 17\alpha^{3} } \right) \hfill \\ - 4\theta^{2} \left( {64 - \alpha \left( {192 + \alpha \left( {96 + 19\alpha } \right)} \right)} \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)^{2} \left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right)^{2} }} < 0\), by setting \(\pi_{o}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{o}^{B*} = 0\), we can derive.

    $$ h_{o}^{B} = \frac{{\left( \begin{gathered} t\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {729\gamma^{4} + 256\theta^{2} - 32\gamma \left( {29\gamma^{2} + 18\theta } \right)\left( {1 + \theta } \right) + 36\gamma^{2} \left( {9 + \theta \left( {41 + 9\theta } \right)} \right)} \right) \hfill \\ + \left( {8 + 9\gamma } \right)\left( {3\gamma + 2\theta } \right)\left( {\theta c\left( {8 + 9\gamma } \right)\left( {3\gamma + 2\theta } \right) - \left( {2 + 3\gamma } \right)\left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right)\sqrt {\left( {c - c_{r} \left( {1 - \theta } \right)} \right)^{2} \theta } } \right) \hfill \\ - 12\theta c_{r} \gamma \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {16\theta + 3\gamma \left( {7 + 9\gamma + 7\theta } \right)} \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {729\gamma^{4} + 256\theta^{2} - 32\gamma \left( {29\gamma^{2} + 18\theta } \right)\left( {1 + \theta } \right) + 36\gamma^{2} \left( {9 + \theta \left( {41 + 9\theta } \right)} \right)} \right)}}. $$

    Hence, when \(h \le h_{o}^{B}\), we have \(\pi_{o}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{o}^{B*} \le 0\); otherwise, \(\pi_{o}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{o}^{B*} > 0\).

    Taking the difference of the manufacturer’s profit between with and without digital showrooms, we have: \(\pi_{m}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{B*} = \frac{{\alpha \left( \begin{gathered} \left( {9\theta \gamma^{2} - 9\gamma \left( {1 + \gamma } \right) - 8\theta } \right)\left( {h - t} \right)^{2} + \theta^{2} c_{r}^{2} \left( {8 - 9\gamma^{2} } \right) - 8c_{r}^{2} \left( {1 + \gamma } \right)\theta^{3} \hfill \\ + 2\theta \gamma \left( {c_{r} + 8c + 9\gamma c - \theta c_{r} } \right)\left( {h - t} \right) + \theta \left( {8 + 9\gamma } \right)\left( {\left( {c + h - t} \right)^{2} \theta - 2c_{r} c\theta + \mu^{2} \gamma } \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{t\left( {8 + 9\gamma } \right)\left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right)}}\). Since \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \left( {\pi_{m}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{B*} } \right)}}{{\partial h^{2} }} = - \frac{{2\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {8\theta + 9\gamma \left( {1 + \gamma + \theta } \right)} \right)}}{{t\left( {8 + 9\gamma } \right)\left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right)}} < 0\), by setting \(\pi_{m}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{B*} = 0\), we can derive:

    $$ h_{m}^{B} = t + \frac{{c_{r} \theta \gamma \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta c\left( {8 + 9\gamma } \right)\left( {\gamma + \theta } \right) - \sqrt {\theta \left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right)\left( {1 + \gamma } \right)\left( {8 + 9\gamma } \right)\left( {c - c_{r} \left( {1 - \theta } \right)} \right)^{2} } }}{{\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {8\theta + 9\gamma \left( {1 + \gamma + \theta } \right)} \right)}}. $$

    Hence, when \(h \le h_{m}^{B}\), we have \(\pi_{m}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{B*} \le 0\); otherwise, \(\pi_{m}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{B*} > 0\).

    Since \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \left( {\pi_{o}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{o}^{B*} } \right)}}{{\partial h^{2} }} + \frac{{\partial^{2} \left( {\pi_{m}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{B*} } \right)}}{{\partial h^{2} }} < 0\), by setting \(\left( {\pi_{o}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{o}^{B*} } \right) + \left( {\pi_{m}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{B*} } \right) = 0\), we can derive.

    $$ h_{4}^{B} = t + \frac{{\left( \begin{gathered} \theta c\left( {8 + 9\gamma } \right)^{2} \left( {18\gamma^{2} + 29\gamma \theta + 12\theta^{2} } \right) - \theta \gamma c_{r} \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {128\theta + 9\gamma \left( {27\gamma + 20\left( {1 + \theta } \right)} \right)} \right) \hfill \\ - \left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right)\left( {8 + 9\gamma } \right)\sqrt {\theta \left( {12 + \gamma \left( {29 + 18\gamma } \right)} \right)\left( {c - c_{r} \left( {1 - \theta } \right)} \right)^{2} \left( {18\gamma^{2} + 29\gamma \theta + 12\theta^{2} } \right)} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{3\left( {1 - \theta } \right)\left( {27\gamma^{2} \left( {12 + \gamma \left( {29 + 18\gamma } \right)} \right) + 9\gamma \left( {64 + \gamma \left( {148 + 87\gamma } \right)} \right)\theta + 4\left( {8 + 9\gamma } \right)^{2} \theta^{2} } \right)}}. $$

    Hence, when \(h \le h_{4}^{B}\), we have \(\left( {\pi_{o}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{o}^{B*} } \right) + \left( {\pi_{m}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{B*} } \right) \le 0\); otherwise,\(\left( {\pi_{o}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{o}^{B*} } \right) + \left( {\pi_{m}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{B*} } \right) > 0\).

Proof of Lemma 2

The profit of centralized dual-channel supply chain can be written as.

$$ \begin{aligned} \pi_{{}}^{C} & = D_{o} \left( {p_{o}^{C} - c} \right) + D_{r} \left( {p_{r}^{C} - c_{r} } \right) \\ & = \left( {1 - \frac{{p_{o}^{C} - p_{r}^{C} + h}}{t}} \right)\left( {p_{o}^{C} - c} \right) + \left( {\alpha \theta \frac{{p_{o}^{C} - p_{r}^{C} + h}}{t} + \theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\frac{{\theta \left( {v - p_{r}^{C} } \right)}}{t}} \right)\left( {p_{r}^{C} - c_{r} } \right). \\ \end{aligned} $$

Since \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \pi^{C} }}{{\left( {\partial p_{r}^{C} } \right)^{2} }} = - \frac{{2\left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\theta }}{t} < 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \pi^{C} }}{{\left( {\partial p_{o}^{C} } \right)^{2} }} = - \frac{2\alpha \theta }{t} < 0\), by solving \(\frac{{\partial \pi^{C} }}{{\partial p_{r}^{C} }} = 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial \pi^{C} }}{{\partial p_{o}^{C} }} = 0\), we can derive the equilibrium prices as follows: \(p_{o}^{C*} = \frac{1}{2}\left( {c - h + t + v + \frac{t\gamma }{\theta }} \right)\) and \(p_{r}^{C*} = \frac{1}{2}\left( {c_{r} + v + \frac{t\gamma }{\theta }} \right)\). □

Proof of Theorem 2

  1. (1)

    Under structure A, a dual-channel supply chain can achieve coordination when both the online selling price and the offline selling price are equal to those in the centralized supply chain system. Based on Lemma 2, let \(p_{fr}^{A*} = p_{r}^{C*}\) and \(p_{fo}^{A*} = p_{o}^{C*}\). Then we have \(w_{f}^{A*} = \frac{{\gamma \left( {t\gamma - \left( {c + h - t - v} \right)\theta } \right)}}{{2\theta \left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)}}\).

    To guarantee that the manufacturer is willing to provide digital showrooms to consumers and achieve both “win–win coordination” and “supply chain system coordination”, we have two conditions: \(\pi_{fm}^{A*} - \pi_{m}^{A*} \ge 0\) and \(\pi_{fm}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A*} \ge 0\). Thus, the fixed compensation needs to satisfy: \(F \ge \underline {F} = \max \left\{ {F_{1} ,F_{2} } \right\}\), where \(F_{1} = \frac{{\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {\left( {c_{r} - c - h} \right)\gamma + \left( {c_{r} - v} \right)\theta } \right)^{2} }}{9t\gamma + 8t\theta }\) and.

    $$ F_{2} = \frac{1}{{4t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)}}\left( \begin{gathered} \left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {t\gamma + 2v\alpha \theta - 2h\alpha } \right) + 8\alpha h^{2} + \alpha \left( {3 + \alpha } \right)\left( {v\theta - h^{2} \alpha } \right)} \right) \hfill \\ + 4c_{r}^{2} \theta^{2} \left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)^{2} - 4\theta \left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {c_{r} + v} \right) + v\theta^{2} \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {v\left( {2 + \alpha } \right)^{2} - 8c_{r} } \right) \hfill \\ - \alpha \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {t\gamma - \left( {c + h - t - v} \right)\theta } \right)^{2} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right). $$

    Similarly, we also need to guarantee that the retailer is willing to accept such contract, thus, we have two conditions: \(\pi_{fr}^{A*} - \pi_{r}^{A*} \ge 0\) and \(\pi_{fr}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{r}^{A*} \ge 0\). Thus, the fixed compensation needs to satisfy \(F \le \overline{F} = \min \left\{ {F_{3} ,F_{4} } \right\}\), where.

    $$ F_{3} = \frac{{3\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {5\gamma + 4\theta } \right)\left( {3\gamma + 4\theta } \right)\left( {\left( {c_{r} - c - h} \right)\gamma + \left( {c_{r} - v} \right)\theta } \right)^{2} }}{{4t\left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {9\gamma + 8\theta } \right)^{2} }}, $$
    $$ F_{4} = \frac{1}{4t}\left( {\frac{{\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {\left( {c_{r} - c - h} \right)\gamma + \left( {c_{r} - v} \right)\theta } \right)^{2} }}{\gamma + \theta } - \frac{{4\left( {2 + \alpha } \right)^{2} \left( {h\alpha - \theta c_{r} + \theta v\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)^{2} }}{{\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)^{2} }}} \right). $$

    Hence, the two-part tariff contract \(\left( {w_{f}^{A*} ,F^{A} } \right)\) with \(w_{f}^{A*} = \frac{{\gamma \left( {t\gamma - \left( {c + h - t - v} \right)\theta } \right)}}{{2\theta \left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)}}\) and \(\underline {F} \le F^{A} \le \overline{F}\) can achieve both “win–win coordination” and “supply chain system coordination”.

  2. (2)

    (2) Under structure B, let \(p_{fr}^{B*} = p_{r}^{C*}\) and \(p_{fo}^{B*} = p_{o}^{C*}\), then we have \(w_{f}^{B*} = \frac{1}{2}\left( {v - c_{r} + \frac{t\gamma }{\theta }} \right)\).

    To guarantee that the manufacturer is willing to provide digital showrooms to consumers and achieve both “win–win coordination” and “supply chain system coordination”, we have two conditions \(\pi_{fm}^{B*} - \pi_{m}^{B*} \ge 0\) and \(\pi_{fm}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{B*} \ge 0\).

    Since \(\pi_{fm}^{B*} - \pi_{m}^{B*} = - F^{B} - \frac{{\alpha \left( {c_{r} - c - h + t} \right)^{2} \left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\theta }}{9t\gamma + 8t\theta } < 0\) and \(\pi_{fm}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{B*} = - F^{B} - \frac{{\alpha \left( {h - t - c_{r} \theta } \right)^{2} }}{{t\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)}} < 0\). Thus, under structure B, the two-part tariff contract cannot achieve either supply chain coordination. □

Proof of Theorem 3

  1. (1)

    Under structure A, according to the Eqs. (10) and (11), we have

    \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \pi_{qr}^{A} }}{{\left( {\partial p_{qr}^{A} } \right)^{2} }} = - \frac{{2\theta \left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\left( {t - \delta_{q}^{A} \left( {\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + \theta } \right)\theta } \right)}}{{t^{2} }} < 0\) and.

    \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \pi_{qm}^{A} }}{{\left( {\partial p_{qo}^{A} } \right)^{2} }} = - \frac{{2\alpha \theta \left( {t + \delta_{q}^{A} \alpha \theta } \right)}}{{t^{2} }} < 0\), by solving \(\frac{{\partial \pi_{qr}^{A} }}{{\partial p_{qr}^{A} }} = 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial \pi_{qm}^{A} }}{{\partial p_{qo}^{A} }} = 0\), we can derive the equilibrium prices as follows:

    $$ p_{qr}^{A} = \frac{{t\left( \begin{gathered} \left( {2ct + \left( {1 - \lambda^{A} } \right)\left( {c + h + t} \right) + \left( {3 - \lambda^{A} } \right)w_{q}^{A} } \right)\gamma + 2\theta t\left( {c_{r} + v + w_{q}^{A} } \right) \hfill \\ + 2\theta \delta_{q}^{A} \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {\gamma \left( {\gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {c_{r} - c - h - t} \right) - v\gamma \theta \left( {2 - \lambda^{A} } \right) - 2v\theta^{2} } \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{\left( {3 - \lambda^{A} } \right)\left( {1 - \lambda^{A} } \right)t\gamma + 4t\theta - 4\delta_{q}^{A} \theta^{2} \left( {\theta + \alpha \left( {1 - \lambda^{A} - \theta } \right)} \right)}}, $$
    $$ p_{qo}^{A} = \frac{{\left( \begin{gathered} t\left( {ct\left( {1 + F} \right) + \left( {1 - F} \right)\left( {2c - \left( {1 - F} \right)h + 2t} \right) + \left( {3 - F} \right)w_{q}^{A} } \right)\gamma + \hfill \\ \theta t\left( {c_{r} + 2c + Fc_{r} - 2h + 2t + v + Fv + \left( {3 + F} \right)w_{q}^{A} } \right) + 2\theta \delta_{q}^{A} \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {c_{r} - c - h - t} \right)\gamma^{2} \hfill \\ + 2\theta \delta_{q}^{A} \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {\left( {2\left( {c_{r} - c - Fh - t} \right) - \left( {2 - F} \right)v} \right)\gamma \theta + \left( {c_{r} - c + h - t - \left( {2 + F} \right)v} \right)\theta^{2} } \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{\left( {3 - F} \right)\left( {1 - F} \right)t\gamma + 4t\theta - 4\delta_{q}^{A} \theta^{2} \left( {\theta + \alpha \left( {1 - F - \theta } \right)} \right)}}. $$

    To coordinate the supply chain, the manufacturer needs to let \(w_{q}^{A}\) and \(\delta_{q}^{A}\) satisfy \(p_{qo}^{A*} = p_{o}^{C*}\) and \(p_{qr}^{A*} = p_{r}^{C*}\). Thus, we have.

    \(w_{q}^{A*} = \frac{{\gamma \left( {1 - \lambda^{A} } \right)\left( {\left( {2 - \lambda^{A} } \right)\theta v - \left( {c_{r} - c - h - t} \right)\gamma } \right) - c_{r} \gamma \theta \left( {3 - \lambda^{A} } \right) + \gamma \theta \left( {1 + \lambda^{A} } \right)\left( {c + h + t} \right) - 2\left( {c_{r} - v} \right)\theta^{2} }}{{2\theta \left( {\theta + \gamma \left( {1 - \lambda^{A} } \right)} \right)}}\) and \(\delta_{q}^{A*} = \frac{{t\left( {\gamma \left( {1 - \lambda^{A} } \right)\left( {3 - \lambda^{A} } \right) + 4\theta } \right)}}{{4\theta^{2} \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {\theta + \gamma \left( {1 - \lambda^{A} } \right)} \right)}}\).

    To guarantee that the manufacturer is willing to provide digital showrooms to consumers and achieve both “win–win coordination” and “supply chain system coordination”, two conditions should be satisfied: \(\pi_{qm}^{A*} - \pi_{m}^{A*} \ge 0\) and \(\pi_{qm}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A*} \ge 0\). Since \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \left( {\pi_{qm}^{A*} - \pi_{m}^{A*} } \right)}}{{\partial \lambda^{2} }} > 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \left( {\pi_{qm}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A*} } \right)}}{{\partial \lambda^{2} }} > 0\), thus by solving \(\pi_{qm}^{A*} - \pi_{m}^{A*} = 0\), we can obtain \(\hat{\lambda }_{1}\) and \(\hat{\lambda }_{2}\); by solving \(\pi_{qm}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A*} = 0\), we can obtain \(\hat{\lambda }_{3}\) and \(\hat{\lambda }_{4}\). Thus, it needs to satisfy \(\lambda^{A} \le \lambda_{1}^{A}\) or \(\lambda^{A} \ge \lambda_{3}^{A}\), where \(\lambda_{1}^{A} = \max \left\{ {\hat{\lambda }_{1} ,\hat{\lambda }_{3} } \right\}\) and \(\lambda_{3}^{A} = \min \left\{ {\hat{\lambda }_{2} ,\hat{\lambda }_{4} } \right\}\).

    Similarly, we also need to guarantee that the retailer is willing to accept such contract, thus two conditions should be satisfied:\(\pi_{qr}^{A*} - \pi_{r}^{A*} \ge 0\) and \(\pi_{qr}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{r}^{A*} \ge 0\). Since \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \left( {\pi_{qr}^{A*} - \pi_{r}^{A*} } \right)}}{{\partial \lambda^{2} }} < 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \left( {\pi_{qr}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{r}^{A*} } \right)}}{{\partial \lambda^{2} }} < 0\), then by solving \(\pi_{qr}^{A*} - \pi_{r}^{A*} = 0\), we can obtain \(\tilde{\lambda }_{1}\) and \(\tilde{\lambda }_{2}\); by solving \(\pi_{qr}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{r}^{A*} = 0\), we can obtain \(\tilde{\lambda }_{3}\) and \(\tilde{\lambda }_{4}\). Thus, it needs to satisfy \(\tilde{\lambda }_{1} \le \lambda^{A} \le \tilde{\lambda }_{2}\) or \(\tilde{\lambda }_{3} \le \lambda^{A} \le \tilde{\lambda }_{4}\), where \(\lambda_{2}^{A} = \max \left\{ {\tilde{\lambda }_{1} ,\tilde{\lambda }_{3} } \right\}\) and \(\lambda_{4}^{A} = \min \left\{ {\tilde{\lambda }_{2} ,\tilde{\lambda }_{4} } \right\}\).

    In summary, if \(\left\{ {\lambda_{1}^{A} \le \lambda^{A} \le \lambda_{2}^{A} } \right\} \cup \left\{ {\lambda_{3}^{A} \le \lambda^{A} \le \lambda_{4}^{A} } \right\}\), the QD-WPS contract can achieve both “win–win coordination” and “supply chain system coordination”.

  2. (2)

    Under structure B, according to the Eqs. (10) and (11), we have \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \pi_{qm}^{B} }}{{\left( {\partial p_{qr}^{B} } \right)^{2} }} = \frac{{2\alpha \theta \left( { - \lambda^{B} t + \delta_{{}}^{B} \alpha \theta } \right)}}{{t^{2} }} < 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \pi_{qo}^{B} }}{{\left( {\partial p_{qo}^{B} } \right)^{2} }} = - \frac{2\alpha \theta }{t} < 0\).

    By solving \(\frac{{\partial \pi_{qo}^{B} }}{{\partial p_{qo}^{B} }} = 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial \pi_{qm}^{B} }}{{\partial p_{qr}^{B} }} = 0\), we can derive the equilibrium prices as follows:

    $$ p_{qr}^{B} = \frac{{\left( \begin{gathered} t\left( {2c_{r} + \left( {1 - \lambda^{B} } \right)\left( {c + h + t} \right) + \left( {3 - \lambda^{B} } \right)w_{q}^{B} + 2\theta \delta^{B} \alpha \left( {2 - \lambda^{B} } \right)} \right)\gamma - 2\theta \delta^{B} \left( {c_{r} - c - h} \right)\alpha \gamma \hfill \\ + 2\theta \left( {c_{r} + v} \right)\left( {t - \delta^{B} \alpha \theta } \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{\left( {3 - \lambda^{B} } \right)\left( {1 - \lambda^{B} } \right)t\gamma + 4t\theta - 4\delta^{B} \alpha \theta^{2} }} $$

    and

    $$ p_{qo}^{B} = \frac{{\left( \begin{gathered} t\left( {c_{r} \left( {1 + \lambda^{B} } \right) + \left( {1 - \lambda^{B} } \right)\left( {2c - \left( {1 - \lambda^{B} } \right)h + 2t} \right) + \left( {3 - \lambda^{B} } \right)w_{q}^{B} } \right)\gamma - 2\delta^{B} \left( {c_{r} - 2h + 2t + v} \right)\alpha \theta^{2} + \hfill \\ \left( {t\left( {\left( {c_{r} + v} \right)\left( {1 + \lambda^{B} } \right) + 2c - 2h + 2t + 2w_{q}^{B} } \right) - 2\delta^{B} \left( {c_{r} - c - h + \left( {2 - \lambda^{B} } \right)t} \right)\alpha \gamma } \right)\theta \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{\left( {3 - \lambda^{B} } \right)\left( {1 - \lambda^{B} } \right)t\gamma + 4t\theta - 4\delta^{B} \alpha \theta^{2} }}. $$

    In order to coordinate the supply chain, the manufacturer needs to let \(w_{q}^{B}\) and \(\delta^{B}\) satisfy \(p_{qo}^{B*} = p_{o}^{C*}\) and \(p_{qr}^{B*} = p_{r}^{C*}\). Thus, we have.

    $$ w_{q}^{B*} { = }\frac{1}{2}\left( {1 - \lambda^{B} } \right)(c_{r} + v - \frac{{\left( {c - c_{r} + h - \left( {2 - \lambda^{B} } \right)t} \right)\gamma }}{\theta }) - \left( {c + h - t} \right), $$

    and \(\delta^{B*} = \frac{{t\left( {\gamma \left( {1 - \lambda^{B} } \right)\left( {3 - \lambda^{B} } \right) + 4\theta } \right)}}{{4\alpha \theta^{2} }}\).

    To guarantee that the manufacturer is willing to provide digital showrooms to consumers and achieve both “win–win coordination” and “supply chain system coordination”, two conditions should be satisfied:\(\pi_{qm}^{B*} - \pi_{m}^{B*} \ge 0\) and \(\pi_{qm}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{B*} \ge 0\). Since \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \left( {\pi_{qm}^{B*} - \pi_{m}^{B*} } \right)}}{{\partial \lambda^{2} }} > 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \left( {\pi_{qm}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{B*} } \right)}}{{\partial \lambda^{2} }} > 0\), then we can obtain \(\underset{\raise0.3em\hbox{$\smash{\scriptscriptstyle\thicksim}$}}{\lambda }_{1}\) and \(\underset{\raise0.3em\hbox{$\smash{\scriptscriptstyle\thicksim}$}}{\lambda }_{2}\) by solving \(\pi_{qm}^{B*} - \pi_{m}^{B*} = 0\) and \(\pi_{qm}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{B*} = 0\). Thus, it needs to satisfy \(\lambda^{B} \le \lambda_{2}^{B}\), where \(\lambda_{2}^{B} = \min \left\{ {\underset{\raise0.3em\hbox{$\smash{\scriptscriptstyle\thicksim}$}}{\lambda }_{1} ,\underset{\raise0.3em\hbox{$\smash{\scriptscriptstyle\thicksim}$}}{\lambda }_{2} } \right\}\).

    Similarly, we also need to guarantee that the retailer is willing to accept such contract, thus, two conditions should be satisfied: \(\pi_{qo}^{B*} - \pi_{o}^{B*} \ge 0\) and \(\pi_{qo}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{o}^{B*} \ge 0\). Since \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \left( {\pi_{qo}^{B*} - \pi_{o}^{B*} } \right)}}{{\partial \lambda^{2} }} < 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \left( {\pi_{qo}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{o}^{B*} } \right)}}{{\partial \lambda^{2} }} < 0\), then we can obtain \(\underset{\raise0.3em\hbox{$\smash{\scriptscriptstyle\thicksim}$}}{\lambda }_{3}\) and \(\underset{\raise0.3em\hbox{$\smash{\scriptscriptstyle\thicksim}$}}{\lambda }_{4}\) by solving \(\pi_{qo}^{B*} - \pi_{o}^{B*} = 0\) and \(\pi_{qo}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{o}^{B*} = 0\). Thus, it needs to satisfy \(\lambda^{B} \ge \lambda_{1}^{B}\), where \(\lambda_{1}^{B} = \min \left\{ {\underset{\raise0.3em\hbox{$\smash{\scriptscriptstyle\thicksim}$}}{\lambda }_{3} ,\underset{\raise0.3em\hbox{$\smash{\scriptscriptstyle\thicksim}$}}{\lambda }_{4} } \right\}\).

    In summary, if \(\lambda_{1}^{B} \le \lambda^{B} \le \lambda_{2}^{B}\), the QD-WPS contract can achieve both “win–win coordination” and “supply chain system coordination”. □

Appendix B: channel structure D

2.1 The benchmark without digital showrooms

The profit functions of the online channel, the offline retailer, and the manufacturer under structure D can be expressed as.

$$ \hat{\pi }_{o}^{D} = \hat{D}_{o}^{D} \left( {\hat{p}_{o}^{D} - \hat{w}^{D} } \right), $$
(B1)
$$ \hat{\pi }_{r}^{D} = \hat{D}_{r}^{D} \left( {\hat{p}_{r}^{D} - \hat{w}^{D} - c_{r} } \right), $$
(B2)
$$ \hat{\pi }_{m}^{D} = \left( {\hat{D}_{o}^{D} + \hat{D}_{r}^{D} } \right)\hat{w}^{D} . $$
(B3)

By substituting \(\hat{D}_{o}\) and \(\hat{D}_{r}\) into Eqs. (B1) and (B2) and using the first-order conditions, \(\frac{{\partial \hat{\pi }_{r}^{D} }}{{\partial \hat{p}_{r}^{D} }} = 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial \hat{\pi }_{o}^{D} }}{{\partial \hat{p}_{o}^{D} }} = 0\), we can derive the best response functions as follows:

$$ \hat{p}_{r}^{D} = \frac{{\left( {h + \hat{p}_{o}^{D} } \right)\alpha + \left( {c_{r} + v + \hat{w}^{D} - v\alpha } \right)\theta }}{2\theta }, $$
(B4)
$$ \hat{p}_{o}^{D} = \frac{1}{2}\left( { - h + t + \hat{w}^{D} + \hat{p}_{r}^{D} \theta } \right). $$
(B5)

We can verify that the second-order derivatives of the profit functions are negative. Solving these two equations yields the equilibrium prices:

$$ \hat{p}_{r}^{D} = \frac{{\left( {h + t + \hat{w}^{D} } \right)\alpha + 2\left( {c_{r} + v + \hat{w}^{D} - v\alpha } \right)\theta }}{{\left( {4 - \alpha } \right)\theta }}, $$
(B6)
$$ \hat{p}_{o}^{D} = - \frac{{2\left( {t + \hat{w}^{D} } \right) + h\left( { - 2 + \alpha } \right) + \left( {c_{r} + v + \hat{w}^{D} - v\alpha } \right)\theta }}{ - 4 + \alpha }. $$
(B7)

Substituting the equilibrium prices into Eq. (B3) and using the first-order conditions, \(\frac{{\partial \hat{\pi }_{m}^{D} }}{{\partial \hat{w}^{D} }} = 0\), we can derive the best response functions as follows:

$$ \hat{w}^{D*} = \frac{{t\alpha \left( {2 + \theta } \right) - h\alpha \left( {2 - \alpha - \theta } \right) + \theta \left( {v\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {\alpha + 2\theta } \right) + c_{r} \left( {\alpha - \left( {2 - \alpha } \right)\theta } \right)} \right)}}{{2\left( {\left( {2 - \alpha } \right)\alpha - 2\alpha \theta + \left( {2 - \alpha } \right)\theta^{2} } \right)}}. $$
(B8)

Substituting the equilibrium prices \(\hat{w}^{D*}\) into (B6), (B7) and Eqs. (B1)-(B3) yields the equilibrium retail prices and profits:

Structure

Optimal decisions

Structure D

\(\hat{w}^{D*} = \frac{{t\alpha \left( {2 + \theta } \right) - h\alpha \left( {2 - \alpha - \theta } \right) + \theta \left( {v\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {\alpha + 2\theta } \right) + c_{r} \left( {\alpha - \left( {2 - \alpha } \right)\theta } \right)} \right)}}{{2\left( {\left( {2 - \alpha } \right)\alpha - 2\alpha \theta + \left( {2 - \alpha } \right)\theta^{2} } \right)}}\)

 

\(\hat{p}_{o}^{D*} = \frac{{\left( \begin{gathered} 2\left( {3 - \alpha } \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {2t\gamma - h\gamma \left( {2 - \alpha } \right) + \gamma \theta \left( {c_{r} + v - v\alpha } \right) + v\theta^{3} } \right) + \alpha \theta \left( {8h - 3h\alpha - 4t} \right) \hfill \\ - \left( {8h - 4\left( {2t + v} \right) + c_{r} \left( {4 + \alpha } \right) + \alpha \left( {3t + v\left( {7 - 3\alpha } \right) - h\left( {9 - 2\alpha } \right)} \right)} \right)\theta^{2} + \theta^{3} c_{r} \left( {2 - \alpha } \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{2\left( {4 - \alpha } \right)\left( {\alpha \left( {2 - \alpha } \right) - 2\alpha \theta + \left( {2 - \alpha } \right)\theta^{2} } \right)}}\)

 

\(\hat{p}_{r}^{D*} = \frac{{\left( \begin{gathered} 2\left( {3 - \alpha } \right)\left( {t\alpha^{2} + t\alpha \theta^{2} + h\alpha \theta^{2} + 2v\left( {3 - \alpha } \right)\theta^{3} } \right) + \alpha \theta v\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {8 - 3\alpha - 4\theta } \right) \hfill \\ + h\alpha \left( {2\alpha - \alpha^{2} - 4\theta - \alpha \theta } \right) + t\alpha \theta \left( {4 - 3\alpha } \right) \hfill \\ + \theta c_{r} \left( {\left( {8 - 3\alpha } \right)\alpha - \left( {8 - \alpha } \right)\alpha \theta + 2\left( {2 - \alpha } \right)\theta^{2} } \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{2\theta \left( {4 - \alpha } \right)\left( {\left( {2 - \alpha } \right)\alpha - 2\alpha \theta + \left( {2 - \alpha } \right)\theta^{2} } \right)}}\)

2.2 Optimal decisions in the presence of digital showrooms

The profit functions of the online channel, the offline retailer, and the manufacturer can be expressed as.

$$ \pi_{o}^{D} = D_{o}^{D} \left( {p_{o}^{D} - w^{D} - c} \right), $$
(B9)
$$ \pi_{r}^{D} = D_{r}^{D} \left( {p_{r}^{D} - w^{D} - c_{r} } \right), $$
(B10)
$$ \pi_{m}^{D} = \left( {D_{o}^{D} + D_{r}^{D} } \right)w^{D} . $$
(B11)

By substituting \(D_{o}^{D}\) and \(D_{r}^{D}\) into Eqs. (B9) and (B10) and using the first-order conditions, \(\frac{{\partial \pi_{r}^{D} }}{{\partial p_{r}^{D} }} = 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial \pi_{m}^{D} }}{{\partial p_{o}^{D} }} = 0\), we can derive the best response functions as follows:

$$ p_{r}^{D} = \frac{{\left( {c_{r} + h + p_{o}^{D} + w^{D} } \right)\alpha + \left( {c_{r} + v + w^{D} } \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta }}{{2\alpha \left( {1 - \theta } \right) + 2\theta }}, $$
(B12)
$$ p_{o}^{D} = \frac{1}{2}\left( {c - h + p_{r}^{D} + t + w^{D} } \right). $$
(B13)

We can verify that the second-order derivatives of the profit functions are negative. Solving these two equations yields the equilibrium prices:

$$ p_{r}^{D} = \frac{{\left( {2c_{r} + c + h + t + 3w^{D} } \right)\alpha + 2\left( {c_{r} + v + w^{D} } \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta }}{{3\alpha + 4\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta }}, $$
(B14)
$$ p_{o}^{D} = \frac{{\left( {c_{r} + 2c - h + 2t + 3w^{D} } \right)\alpha + \left( {c_{r} + 2c - 2h + 2t + v + 3w^{D} } \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta }}{{3\alpha + 4\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta }}. $$
(B15)

Substituting the equilibrium prices into Eq. (B11) and using the first-order conditions, \(\frac{{\partial \pi_{m}^{D} }}{{\partial w^{D} }} = 0\), we can derive the best response functions as follows:

$$ w^{D*} = \frac{{3t\alpha^{2} - \left( {2c_{r} + c + h - 3\left( {t + v} \right)} \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\alpha \theta - 2\left( {c_{r} - v} \right)\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)^{2} \theta^{2} }}{{2\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {3\alpha + 2\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\theta } \right)}}. $$
(B16)

Substituting the equilibrium prices \(w^{ND*}\) into (B14), (B15) and Eqs. (B9-B11) yields the equilibrium retail prices and profits:

Structure

Optimal decisions

Structure D

\(w^{D*} = \frac{{3t\gamma^{2} - \left( {2c_{r} + c + h - 3\left( {t + v} \right)} \right)\gamma \theta - 2\left( {c_{r} - v} \right)\theta^{2} }}{{2\theta \left( {3\gamma + 2\theta } \right)}}\)

 

\(p_{o}^{D*} = \frac{{4\left( {c - h + t} \right) - c_{r} + 5v}}{8} + \frac{\gamma }{8}\left( {\frac{{2\left( {c_{r} - c - h + t} \right)}}{3\gamma + 2\theta } + \frac{{c_{r} + 2\left( {c + h + t} \right) - 3v}}{3\gamma + 4\theta } + \frac{4t}{\theta }} \right)\)

 

\(p_{r}^{D*} = \frac{{3t\gamma^{2} + \left( {2c_{r} + c + h + 5t + 3v} \right)\gamma \theta + 2\left( {c_{r} + 3v} \right)\theta^{2} }}{{2\theta \left( {3\gamma + 4\theta } \right)}}\)

Appendix C: Digital showrooms partially resolve match uncertainty

In this section, we first introduce the extension part base on the main model. Then, we derive the equilibrium price decisions in this case. Last, we compare the equilibrium profits of supply chain members with/without digital showrooms to check the robustness of our main results.

When digital showrooms can only partially solve consumers’ valuation uncertainty. Following Gao and Su (2017) and Sun et al. (2020), we assume that consumer will receive a signal \(S\) if they view digital showrooms, where \(S\) is binary, i.e., \(s = \{ 0,1\}\). Specifically, some consumers believe that the product fits them well and remain interested in the product (i.e., \(s = 1\)), while remaining consumers discover that the product does not fit them and leave the market (i.e., \(s = 0\)). Moreover, we also assume that a fraction \(\rho\) (\(\rho \in \left[ {0,1} \right]\)) of misfit-type consumers learn their true types, where the parameter \(\rho\) can be interpreted as the degree of informativeness of digital showrooms. Note that if \(\rho = 1\), digital showrooms offer a perfect signal to consumer, which is the assumption of our main model. Then, the probabilities that fit-type and misfit-type consumers receive the signal \(s = 1\) are \(P\left( {s \, = \, 1|Y} \right) \, = \, 1\) and \(P\left( {s \, = \, 1|F} \right){ = }1 - \rho\), respectively, where \(Y\) and \(F\) denote fit-type and misfit-type consumers, respectively, with \(P\left( Y \right) = \theta\) and \(P\left( F \right) = 1 - \theta\). Following the Bayesian updating process, the posterior belief of a remaining consumer on the probability of fitness (i.e., \(\theta^{P}\)) can be computed as

$$ \theta^{P} = P\left( {Y|s = 1} \right) = \frac{{P\left( {s = 1|Y} \right)P\left( Y \right)}}{{P\left( {s = 1|Y} \right)P\left( Y \right) + P\left( {s = 1|F} \right)P\left( F \right)}} = \frac{\theta }{{1 - \rho \left( {1 - \theta } \right)}}. $$
(C1)

Note, we use superscript “P” to denote the case when the digital showrooms can only partly resolve consumer match uncertainty.

Then the net utility of a dual-channel consumer purchasing the product from the online and offline channels can be characterized as \(EU_{o}^{P} = \theta^{P} v - p_{o}^{P} - h\) and \(EU_{r}^{P} = \theta^{p} \left( {v - p_{o}^{P} } \right) - tx\), respectively. To avoid trivial situations, we make several assumptions in this model: (1)\(p_{o}^{P} + h \le \theta^{P} v\), to avoid negative customer online utility for any online selling price; (2) \(p_{r}^{P} \le v\), to avoid negative customer offline utility for any offline selling price; and (3) \(\min \left\{ {\frac{\theta v - t}{\theta },\frac{{p_{o}^{P} + h - t}}{{\theta^{P} }}} \right\} \le p_{r}^{P} \le \frac{{p_{o}^{P} + h}}{{\theta^{P} }}\), in case of one of the shopping channel always dominate other channel. To maximize their respective utilities, dual-channel consumers with \(EU_{o}^{P} \ge EU_{r}^{P}\) will purchase the product from the online channel, and those with \(EU_{o}^{P} < EU_{r}^{P}\) will choose to visit the physical store. In this case, the amount of dual-channel consumers that purchase the product from the online and offline channels can be formulated as.

$$ D_{o}^{P} = \alpha \left( {1 - \rho \left( {1 - \theta } \right)} \right)\left( {1 - \frac{{p_{o}^{P} - \theta^{P} p_{r}^{P} + h}}{t}} \right), $$
(C2)
$$ D_{r}^{P} = \alpha \theta^{P} \left( {1 - \rho \left( {1 - \theta } \right)} \right)\left( {\frac{{p_{o}^{P} - \theta^{P} p_{r}^{P} + h}}{t}} \right) + \theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\frac{{\theta \left( {v - p_{r}^{P} } \right)}}{t}. $$
(C3)

Under structure A, the profit functions of the manufacturer and the offline retailer can be expressed as.

$$ \pi_{pm}^{A} = \left( {p_{po}^{A} - c} \right)D_{po}^{A} + w_{p}^{A} D_{pr}^{A} , $$
(C4)
$$ \pi_{pr}^{A} = \left( {p_{pr}^{A} - w_{p}^{A} - c_{r} } \right)D_{pr}^{A} . $$
(C5)

Under structure B, the profit functions of the manufacturer and the online retailer can be expressed as.

$$ \pi_{pm}^{B} = \left( {p_{pr}^{B} - c_{r} } \right)D_{pr}^{B} + w_{p}^{B} D_{po}^{B} , $$
(C6)
$$ \pi_{po}^{B} = \left( {p_{po}^{B} - w_{p}^{B} - c} \right)D_{po}^{B} . $$
(C7)

Similar to the proof process of Theorem 1, we can obtain the equilibrium pricing decisions for the member firms under each structure, which are summarized in following Table 5.

Table 5 Equilibrium decisions under structures A and B in the presence of digital showrooms

According to above results, we can compare the equilibrium profits of supply chain members with/without digital showrooms. We define \(\mu = \frac{{\left( {2 + \alpha } \right)}}{{\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)}}\).

  1. (1)

    Under structure A, we define \(\mu = \frac{{\left( {2 + \alpha } \right)}}{{\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)}}\), then we have

    $$ \pi_{pr}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{r}^{A*} = \frac{{\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {3\theta^{P} \gamma + 2\theta } \right)^{2} \left( {c\gamma - \theta^{P} c_{r} \gamma + h\gamma - \theta c_{r} + v\theta } \right)^{2} }}{{t\left( {\theta^{P} \gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {9\theta^{P} \gamma + 8\theta } \right)^{2} }} - \frac{{\mu^{2} \left( {h\alpha - \left( {c_{r} - v\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)\theta } \right)^{2} }}{t} $$

    and \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \left( {\pi_{pr}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{r}^{A*} } \right)}}{{\partial h^{2} }} = - \frac{2\alpha }{t}\left( {\frac{{\alpha \mu^{2} \left( {\theta^{P} \gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {9\theta^{P} \gamma + 8\theta } \right)^{2} - \gamma \theta \left( {3\theta^{P} \gamma + 2\theta } \right)^{2} }}{{\left( {\theta^{P} \gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {9\theta^{P} \gamma + 8\theta } \right)^{2} }}} \right) < 0\).

    By setting \(\pi_{pr}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{r}^{A*} = 0\), we can derive.

    $$ h_{pr}^{A} = \frac{{\left( \begin{gathered} \mu \left( {\theta^{P} \gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {9\theta^{P} \gamma + 8\theta } \right)\left( {3\theta^{P} \gamma + 2\theta } \right)\sqrt {\frac{{\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {c\alpha \gamma - \theta^{P} c_{r} \alpha \gamma - \theta c_{r} \left( {\alpha - \gamma } \right)} \right)^{2} }}{{\left( {\theta^{P} \gamma + \theta } \right)}}} + \hfill \\ \theta \mu^{2} \left( {c_{r} - v\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)} \right)\left( {81\left( {\theta^{P} } \right)^{3} \gamma^{3} + 208\theta^{P} \gamma \theta^{2} + 225\left( {\theta^{P} } \right)^{2} \gamma^{2} \theta + 64\theta^{3} } \right) \hfill \\ + \theta \left( {4\theta^{2} \left( {c\gamma - \theta \left( {c_{r} - v} \right)} \right) - 9\left( {\theta^{P} } \right)^{3} \gamma^{3} c_{r} + \theta^{P} \left( {4\gamma \theta + 3\theta^{P} \gamma^{2} } \right)\left( {3c\gamma - \theta \left( {7c_{r} - 3v} \right)} \right)} \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{\alpha \mu^{2} \left( {81\left( {\theta^{P} } \right)^{3} \gamma^{3} + 225\left( {\theta^{P} } \right)^{2} \gamma^{2} \theta + 208\theta^{P} \gamma \theta^{2} + 64\theta^{3} } \right) - \gamma \theta \left( {4\theta^{2} + 12\theta^{P} \gamma \theta + 9\left( {\theta^{P} } \right)^{2} \gamma^{2} } \right)}}. $$

    Hence, when \(h \le h_{pr}^{A}\), we have \(\pi_{pr}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{r}^{A*} \ge 0\); otherwise, \(\pi_{pr}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{r}^{A*} < 0\).

    Similarly, we have.

    $$ \frac{{\partial^{2} \left( {\pi_{pm}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A*} } \right)}}{{\partial h^{2} }} = \frac{{\left( \begin{gathered} 2\alpha \theta \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {3\left( {\theta^{P} } \right)^{2} \left( {7 - 4\theta^{P} } \right)\gamma^{2} + 8\theta^{P} \left( {4 - 3\theta^{P} } \right)\gamma \theta + 12\left( {1 - \theta^{P} } \right)\theta^{2} } \right) \hfill \\ - \alpha \theta^{P} \left( {9\theta^{P} \gamma + 8\theta } \right)^{2} \left( {8 - \alpha \left( {3 + \alpha } \right)} \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{t\theta^{P} \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {9\theta^{P} \gamma + 8\theta } \right)^{2} }} < 0, $$

    then we can derive one root \(h_{pm}^{A}\) by setting \(\pi_{pm}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A*} = 0\). Hence, when \(h \le h_{pm}^{A}\), \(\pi_{pm}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A*} \le 0\); otherwise, \(\pi_{pm}^{A*} - \hat{\pi }_{m}^{A*} > 0\).

  2. (2)

    Under structure B, we have

    $$ \pi_{po}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{o}^{B*} = \frac{1}{t}\left( {\frac{{\alpha \theta \left( {c - \theta^{P} c_{r} + h - t} \right)^{2} \left( {3\theta^{P} \gamma + 2\theta } \right)^{2} }}{{\theta^{P} \left( {9\theta^{P} \gamma + 8\theta } \right)^{2} }} - \alpha \mu^{2} \left( {h - t - c_{r} \theta } \right)^{2} } \right) $$

and \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \left( {\pi_{po}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{o}^{B*} } \right)}}{{\partial h^{2} }} = \frac{{2\alpha \theta \left( {3\theta^{P} \gamma + 2\theta } \right)^{2} - 2\alpha \mu^{2} \theta^{P} \left( {9\theta^{P} \gamma + 8\theta } \right)^{2} }}{{t\theta^{P} \left( {9\theta^{P} \gamma + 8\theta } \right)^{2} }} < 0\).

By setting \(\pi_{po}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{o}^{B*} = 0\), we can derive.

$$ h_{po}^{B} = \frac{{\left( \begin{gathered} \mu^{2} \left( {81\left( {\theta^{P} } \right)^{3} t\gamma^{2} + 4\theta^{3} 16\theta^{P} c_{r} + 9\theta \gamma \left( {\theta^{P} } \right)^{2} \left( {16t + 9\theta^{P} c_{r} \gamma } \right) + {16}\theta^{P} \theta^{2} \left( {{4}t + {9}\theta^{P} c_{r} \gamma } \right)} \right) \hfill \\ { + }\theta \left( {c - \theta^{P} c_{r} - t} \right)\left( {{12}\theta^{P} \theta \gamma { + }9\left( {\theta^{P} } \right)^{2} \gamma^{{2}} { + }4\theta^{{2}} } \right) - \mu \sqrt {\theta^{P} \theta \left( {3\theta^{P} \gamma + 2\theta } \right)^{2} \left( {9\theta^{P} \gamma + 8\theta } \right)^{2} \left( {c - c_{r} \left( {\theta^{P} - \theta } \right)} \right)^{2} } \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)}}{{\mu^{2} \left( {81\left( {\theta^{P} } \right)^{3} \gamma^{2} + 144\left( {\theta^{P} } \right)^{2} \gamma \theta + 64\theta^{P} \theta^{2} } \right) - \theta \left( {12\theta^{P} \theta \gamma + 4\theta^{2} + 9\left( {\theta^{P} } \right)^{2} \gamma^{2} } \right)}}. $$

Hence, when \(h \le h_{po}^{B}\), we have \(\pi_{po}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{o}^{B*} \le 0\); otherwise, \(\pi_{po}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{o}^{B*} > 0\).

Similarly, we have \(\frac{{\partial^{2} \left( {\pi_{pm}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{pm}^{B*} } \right)}}{{\partial h^{2} }} = - \frac{2\alpha }{t}\left( {\frac{{\theta^{P} \left( {9\theta^{P} \gamma + 8\theta } \right) - \theta \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {\theta^{P} \gamma + \theta } \right)}}{{\theta^{P} \left( {9\theta^{P} \gamma + 8\theta } \right)\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)}}} \right) < 0\). By setting \(\pi_{pm}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{pm}^{B*} = 0\), we can derive.

$$ h_{pm}^{B} = G - \sqrt {G^{2} - \alpha \left( \begin{gathered} \alpha \left( {\theta^{P} } \right)^{2} \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {9t^{2} \gamma + 2\theta \left( {18tv - 4cc_{r} - 5c_{r} t + 2\theta^{P} c_{r}^{2} } \right)} \right) \hfill \\ + 4\theta \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {\left( {c - t} \right)^{2} \theta + \theta^{P} \left( {3t^{2} \gamma - 2tc\gamma - 2t\theta c_{r} + c^{2} \gamma - 2cc_{r} \theta } \right)} \right) \hfill \\ + 2\theta c_{r} \left( {\theta^{P} } \right)^{2} \left( {9\alpha t\left( {4 + \alpha } \right) + 2c_{r} \left( {8 - \alpha \left( {16 + \alpha } \right)} \right)\theta } \right) \hfill \\ - t^{2} \theta^{P} \left( {2 + \alpha } \right)^{2} \left( {9\theta^{P} \gamma + 8\theta } \right) - 16\theta^{P} \theta^{2} c_{r} \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {2\theta c_{r} - 4t - \alpha t} \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right)} . $$

where \(G = \frac{{\theta^{P} \left( {9\theta^{P} t\gamma + \theta \left( {8t + 9\theta^{P} c_{r} \gamma } \right) + 8\theta^{2} c_{r} } \right) + \theta \left( {\theta^{P} \gamma + \theta } \right)\left( {c - \theta^{P} c_{r} - t} \right)\left( {8 + \alpha } \right)}}{{\theta^{P} \left( {9\theta^{P} \gamma + 8\theta } \right) - \theta \left( {8 + \alpha } \right)\left( {\theta^{P} \gamma + \theta } \right)}}\).

Hence, when \(h \le h_{pm}^{B}\), we have \(\pi_{pm}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{pm}^{B*} \le 0\); otherwise, \(\pi_{pm}^{B*} - \hat{\pi }_{pm}^{B*} > 0\).

In summary, in the case of digital showrooms partially resolve match uncertainty, the effects of the digital showrooms on the profits of supply chain members are as shown in Table 6.

Table 6 Effects of digital showrooms on the players’ profits

By comparing the results in Table 6 and those in Proposition 3, we can find that the main results in our base model remain robust when digital showrooms partially solve match uncertainty. □

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Sun, Y., Wang, Z., Yan, S. et al. Digital showroom strategies for dual-channel supply chains in the presence of consumer webrooming behavior. Ann Oper Res 329, 1109–1148 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-021-04475-5

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-021-04475-5

Keywords

Navigation