Skip to main content
Log in

The interplay between quality improvement and information acquisition in an E-commerce supply chain

  • S.I. : Information- Transparent Supply Chains
  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study investigates an e-commerce supply chain comprising a supplier and an online retailer, wherein the supplier determines the quality improvement of products and the online retailer decides whether or not to acquire information on consumer preference. Consumer preference is ex-ante unknown to both the supplier and online retailer but can be resolved by the online retailer’s information acquisition behavior. We consider two widely adopted information acquisition strategies, namely, the committed acquisition strategy and contingent acquisition strategy, which differ in whether the online retailer’s information acquisition decision is made prior to or after the supplier’s quality improvement decision. We find that, under either strategy, the online retailer acquires information only when the cost of information acquisition is relatively small. Moreover, compared with the contingent one, the committed acquisition scheme boosts the online retailer’s motivation to gain information. Additionally, by comparing firms’ equilibrium profits under these two acquisition strategies, we uncover that the supplier always prefers the committed acquisition scheme. However, the online retailer’s preference toward these two information acquisition strategies is not unidirectional, that is, the online retailer prefers either the committed or the contingent strategy. Specifically, the online retailer is indifferent between these two acquisition strategies when the acquisition cost is either sufficiently low or high; otherwise, when the cost of information acquisition is moderate, the online retailer will shift her strategy from the contingent strategy to the committed strategy as the acquisition cost increases.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Available at https://new.qq.com/rain/a/20201118A02Y3S00.

  2. Available at https://www.sohu.com/a/168132429_468071.

  3. Available at http://www.pc-fly.com/a/shumachanpin/article-122159-1.html.

  4. Available at http://www.lohas-china.com/a/fashion/news/2019/0613/1444.html.

References

  • Abhishek, V., Jerath, K., & Zhang, Z. J. (2016). Agency selling or reselling? Channel structures in electronic retailing. Management Science, 62(8), 2259–2280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arya, A., & Mittendorf, B. (2013). Discretionary disclosure in the presence of dual distribution channels. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 55(2–3), 168–182.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arya, A., Mittendorf, B., & Sappington, D. E. (2007). The bright side of supplier encroachment. Marketing Science, 26(5), 651–659.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banker, R. D., Khosla, I., & Sinha, K. K. (1998). Quality and competition. Management Science, 44(9), 1179–1192.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cai, G. G. (2010). Channel selection and coordination in dual-channel supply chains. Journal of Retailing, 86(1), 22–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, J., Liang, L., Yao, D. Q., & Sun, S. (2017). Price and quality decisions in dual-channel supply chains. European Journal of Operational Research, 259(3), 935–948.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, K. Y., Kaya, M., & Özer, Ö. (2008). Dual sales channel management with service competition. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 10(4), 654–675.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chernonog, T. (2020). Strategic information sharing in online retailing under a consignment contract with revenue sharing. Annals of Operations Research. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-020-03807-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiang, W. Y. K., Chhajed, D., & Hess, J. D. (2003). Direct marketing, indirect profits: A strategic analysis of dual-channel supply-chain design. Management Science, 49(1), 1–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chu, W., & Messinger, P. R. (1997). Information and channel profits. Journal of Retailing, 73(4), 487–499.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dan, B., Xu, G., & Liu, C. (2012). Pricing policies in a dual-channel supply chain with retail services. International Journal of Production Economics, 139(1), 312–320.

    Google Scholar 

  • Desiraju, R., & Moorthy, S. (1997). Managing a distribution channel under asymmetric information with performance requirements. Management Science, 43(12), 1628–1644.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dukes, A., & Liu, L. (2016). Online shopping intermediaries: The strategic design of search environments. Management Science, 62(4), 1064–1077.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geng, X., Tan, Y., & Wei, L. (2018). How add-on pricing interacts with distribution contracts. Production and Operations Management, 27(4), 605–623.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guan, X., & Chen, Y. J. (2015). Hierarchical quality disclosure in a supply chain with cost heterogeneity. Decision Support Systems, 76, 63–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guan, X., & Chen, Y. J. (2017). The interplay between information acquisition and quality disclosure. Production and Operations Management, 26(3), 389–408.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guan, X., Mantrala, M., & Bian, Y. (2019). Strategic information management in a distribution channel. Journal of Retailing, 95(1), 42–56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guo, L. (2009). The benefits of downstream information acquisition. Marketing Science, 28(3), 457–471.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guo, L., & Iyer, G. (2010). Information acquisition and sharing in a vertical relationship. Marketing Science, 29(3), 483–506.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guo, L., & Zhao, Y. (2009). Voluntary quality disclosure and market interaction. Marketing Science, 28(3), 488–501.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gurnani, H., Erkoc, M., & Luo, Y. (2007). Impact of product pricing and timing of investment decisions on supply chain co-opetition. European Journal of Operational Research, 180(1), 228–248.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ha, A. Y., Tong, S., & Zhang, H. (2011). Sharing demand information in competing supply chains with production diseconomies. Management Science, 57(3), 566–581.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hagiu, A., & Wright, J. (2014). Marketplace or reseller? Management Science, 61(1), 184–203.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hao, L., & Tan, Y. (2019). Who wants consumers to be informed? Facilitating information disclosure in a distribution channel. Information Systems Research, 30(1), 34–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hu, N., Dow, K. E., Chong, A. Y. L., & Liu, L. (2018). Double learning or double blinding: An investigation of vendor private information acquisition and consumer learning via online reviews. Annals of Operations Research, 270(1–2), 213–234.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang, S., Guan, X., & Chen, Y. J. (2018). Retailer information sharing with supplier encroachment. Production and Operations Management, 27(6), 1133–1147.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iyer, G. (1998). Coordinating channels under price and nonprice competition. Marketing Science, 17(4), 338–355.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jeuland, A. P., & Shugan, S. M. (1983). Managing channel profits. Marketing Science, 2(3), 239–272.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jiang, Z. Z., Zhao, J., Yi, Z., & Zhao, Y. (2020). Inducing information transparency: The roles of gray market and dual-channel. Annals of Operations Research. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-020-03719-0

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kwark, Y., Chen, J., & Raghunathan, S. (2017). Platform or wholesale? A strategic tool for online retailers to benefit from third-party information. MIS Quarterly, 41(3), 763–785.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, H. L., So, K. C., & Tang, C. S. (2000). The value of information sharing in a two-level supply chain. Management Science, 46(5), 626–643.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lei, Y., Jasin, S., & Sinha, A. (2018). Joint dynamic pricing and order fulfillment for e-commerce retailers. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 20(2), 269–284.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, G., Li, L., & Sun, J. (2019a). Pricing and service effort strategy in a dual-channel supply chain with showrooming effect. Transportation Research Part e: Logistics and Transportation Review, 126, 32–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, G., Wu, H., & Dai, J. (2020a). Production sourcing strategy for an apparel original brand manufacturer in the presence of technology spillover. IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management. https://doi.org/10.1109/TEM.2020.3007209

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, G., Wu, H., Sethi, S. P., & Zhang, X. (2021a). Contracting green product supply chains considering marketing efforts in the circular economy era. International Journal of Production Economics, 234, 108.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, G., Zhang, X., Chiu, S. M., Liu, M., & Sethi, S. P. (2019b). Online market entry and channel sharing strategy with direct selling diseconomies in the sharing economy era. International Journal of Production Economics, 218, 135–147.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, G., Zheng, H., Sethi, S. P., & Guan, X. (2020b). Inducing downstream information sharing via manufacturer information acquisition and retailer subsidy. Decision Sciences, 51(3), 691–719.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, G., Zheng, H., & Tian, L. (2021b). Information sharing in an online marketplace with co-opetitive sellers. Production and Operations Management. https://doi.org/10.1111/poms.13460

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, G., Zhang, J., & Tang, W. (2015). Joint dynamic pricing and investment strategy for perishable foods with price-quality dependent demand. Annals of Operations Research, 226(1), 397–416.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mantin, B., Krishnan, H., & Dhar, T. (2014). The strategic role of third-party marketplaces in retailing. Production and Operations Management, 23(11), 1937–1949.

    Google Scholar 

  • Markopoulos, P. M., & Hosanagar, K. (2018). A model of product design and information disclosure investments. Management Science, 64(2), 739–759.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morath, F., & Münster, J. (2018). Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Management Science, 64(1), 360–380.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niu, B., Li, J., Zhang, J., Cheng, H. K., & Tan, Y. (2019). Strategic analysis of dual sourcing and dual channel with an unreliable alternative supplier. Production and Operations Management, 28(3), 570–587.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ru, J., Shi, R., & Zhang, J. (2015). Does a store brand always hurt the manufacturer of a competing national brand? Production and Operations Management, 24(2), 272–286.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sun, H., Fan, M., & Tan, Y. (2020). An empirical analysis of seller advertising strategies in an online marketplace. Information Systems Research, 31(1), 37–56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tian, L., Vakharia, A. J., Tan, Y., & Xu, Y. (2018). Marketplace, reseller, or hybrid: Strategic analysis of an emerging e-commerce model. Production and Operations Management, 27(8), 1595–1610.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vives, X. (1988). Aggregation of information in large Cournot markets. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 56, 851–876.

    Google Scholar 

  • Xiao, L., Chen, S., & Huang, S. (2020a). Observability of retailer demand information acquisition in a dual-channel supply chain. Annals of Operations Research. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-020-03629-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xiao, L., Xu, M., Zheng, J. J., & Huang, S. (2020b). Inducing manufacturer’s quality enhancement via retailer’s acquisition strategy. Omega, 93, 102032.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yan, Y., Zhao, R., & Liu, Z. (2018). Strategic introduction of the marketplace channel under spillovers from online to offline sales. European Journal of Operational Research, 267(1), 65–77.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yao, D. Q., & Liu, J. J. (2005). Competitive pricing of mixed retail and e-tail distribution channels. Omega, 33(3), 235–247.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yi, Z., Wang, Y., Liu, Y., & Chen, Y. J. (2018). The impact of consumer fairness seeking on distribution channel selection: Direct selling vs. agent selling. Production and Operations Management, 27(6), 1148–1167.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zennyo, Y. (2020). Strategic contracting and hybrid use of agency and wholesale contracts in e-commerce platforms. European Journal of Operational Research, 281(1), 231–239.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Hong Zheng is the corresponding author of this paper. The authors sincerely thank the editor and the reviewers for their constructive comments and suggestions that improve the paper. The authors have also benefited from the support of National Natural Science Foundation of China (71971027, 91746110). Hong Zheng thanks the support of China Scholarship Council for this research.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hong Zheng.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proposition 1

Proof

By comparing the equilibrium quality improvement level with acquisition and non-acquisition under the committed acquisition strategy, we demonstrate that \(m^{D} = \frac{{5(1 - \alpha )(\rho ^{2} \alpha ^{2} - 2\rho (4 - \rho )\alpha + (\rho + 2)^{2} )}}{{8k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)}}\) is always greater than \(m^{N} = \frac{{(1 - \alpha )(\rho ^{2} \alpha ^{2} - 2\rho (4 - \rho )\alpha + (\rho + 2)^{2} )}}{{2k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)}}\).□

1.2 Proposition 2

Proof

If and only if \(\Pi _{r}^{D} \ge \Pi _{r}^{N}\), then the online retailer will opt to obtain consumers’ quality preference information. Thus, we can derive that the online retailer will opt to obtain consumers’ quality preference information when \(c \le \tilde{c}_{1} (\alpha ,\rho ,k) = \frac{{9(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{64k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }}\); otherwise, the online retailer will opt to obtain consumers’ quality preference information.□

1.3 Corollary 1

Proof

By calculating the first derivative of \(\tilde{c}_{1} (\alpha ,\rho ,k)\) to \(\rho\), we have \(\Delta = \frac{{\partial \tilde{c}_{1} (\alpha ,\rho ,k)}}{{\partial \rho }} = - \frac{\begin{gathered} 9( - 1 + \alpha )[8\alpha ^{8} ( - 4 + \rho )\rho ^{4} + \alpha ^{9} \rho ^{5} - 2(2 + \rho )^{3} ( - 10 + 35\rho + 2\rho ^{2} ) \hfill \\ + 2\alpha ^{7} \rho ^{3} (192 - 79\rho + 12\rho ^{2} ) + 2\alpha ^{6} \rho ^{2} ( - 1020 + 352\rho - 85\rho ^{2} + 14\rho ^{3} ) \hfill \\ + 2\alpha ^{5} \rho (2056 + 1220\rho - 704\rho ^{2} + 153\rho ^{3} - 7\rho ^{4} ) \hfill \\ + \alpha ^{3} (1856 + 22752\rho - 6512\rho ^{2} + 640\rho ^{3} + 438\rho ^{4} - 112\rho ^{5} ) \hfill \\ + \alpha (192 + 3984\rho + 3816\rho ^{2} + 384\rho ^{3} - 330\rho ^{4} - 27\rho ^{5} ) \hfill \\ - 2\alpha ^{2} (832 + 6880\rho + 1948\rho ^{2} - 1312\rho ^{3} + 119\rho ^{4} + 38\rho ^{5} ) \hfill \\ - 2\alpha ^{4} (272 + 8256\rho - 3216\rho ^{2} + 1440\rho ^{3} - 395\rho ^{4} + 42\rho ^{5} )] \hfill \\ \end{gathered} }{{32k[8 + 2\alpha ( - 4 + \rho ) + \rho + \alpha ^{2} \rho ]^{4} }}\). By calculating \(\Delta\), we derive that the thresholds of \(\tilde{\alpha }\), \(\rho _{1} (\alpha )\), and \(\rho _{2} (\alpha )\) exist. When \(0 < \alpha \le \frac{1}{3}\) and \(0 < \rho < \rho _{1} (\alpha )\), when \(\frac{1}{3} < \alpha \le \tilde{\alpha }\) and \(0 < \rho \le \frac{{6\alpha - 2}}{{(1 + \alpha )^{2} }}\), or when \(\tilde{\alpha } < \alpha < 1\) and \(\rho _{2} (\alpha ) < \rho \le \frac{{6\alpha - 2}}{{(1 + \alpha )^{2} }}\), \(\Delta = \frac{{\partial \tilde{c}_{1} (\alpha ,\rho ,k)}}{{\partial \rho }} > 0\). Otherwise, \(\Delta = \frac{{\partial \tilde{c}_{1} (\alpha ,\rho ,k)}}{{\partial \rho }} < 0\).□

1.4 Corollary 2

Proof

According to the equilibrium upstream supplier’s and online retailer’s profits with acquisition and non-acquisition, we demonstrate that the online retailer’s profits \(\frac{{25(1 - \alpha )((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)K(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{64k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }} - c\) decrease linearly with acquisition cost when \(c \le \tilde{c}_{1} (\alpha ,\rho ,k)\). Moreover, the retailer’s profits \(\frac{{(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{4k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }}\) is independent of acquisition cost when \(c > \tilde{c}_{1} (\alpha ,\rho ,k)\). Thus, the online retailer’s profits tend to decrease along with information acquisition cost. For the supplier, when \(c > \tilde{c}_{1} (\alpha ,\rho ,k)\), his profits have a decreasing jump. Therefore, the profit of the supplier also decreases along with information acquisition cost.□

1.5 Proposition 3

Proof

Assuming that the online retailer opts to obtain information on consumers’ quality preference, when \(\theta = \theta _{L}\), the profit of the online retailer is \(\frac{{K(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{4((1 + \alpha )^{2} - 8\alpha + 8)^{2} }}m - c\), and when \(\theta = \theta _{H}\), the profit of the online retailer is \(\frac{{K(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{((1 + \alpha )^{2} - 8\alpha + 8)^{2} }}m - c\). However, when the online retailer refuses to obtain such information, her profit is \(\frac{{K(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{2((1 + \alpha )^{2} - 8\alpha + 8)^{2} }}m\). By comparing these equilibrium profits with the equilibrium profit under non-acquisition, if and only if \(c \le \frac{{K(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{8((1 + \alpha )^{2} - 8\alpha + 8)^{2} }}m\), then the online retailer will opt to obtain consumers’ quality preference information. Building on the optimal information acquisition decision of online retailers, we analyze the decision of the upstream supplier regarding the product quality improvement level. We consider the following scenarios:

  1. (1)

    If the downstream retailer opts to obtain information about consumers’ quality preferences, then the upstream supplier solves the following optimization problem:

    $$ \begin{aligned} & Max\Pi _{s}^{D} (m) = \underbrace {{\frac{1}{2}\left(\frac{{(1 - \alpha )((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)}}{{(1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8}}m - \frac{{km^{2} }}{2}\right)}}_{{\theta = \theta _{H} }} + \underbrace {{\frac{1}{2}\left(\frac{{(1 - \alpha )((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)}}{{4((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)}}m - \frac{{km^{2} }}{2}\right)}}_{{\theta = \theta _{L} }} \\ & \qquad s.t.\;c \le \frac{{K(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{8((1 + \alpha )^{2} - 8\alpha + 8)^{2} }}m. \\ \end{aligned} $$

We can obtain the optimal solution to the optimization problem as follows: if \(c \le \frac{{5(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{64k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }}\), then \(m^{\# } = \frac{{5(1 - \alpha )(\rho ^{2} \alpha ^{2} - 2\rho (4 - \rho )\alpha + (\rho + 2)^{2} )}}{{8k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)}}\); otherwise, \(m^{\# } = \frac{{(1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8}}{{K(\alpha ,\rho )}}c\). Therefore, when \(c \le \frac{{5(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{64k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }}\), the profits of the upstream supplier are \(\Pi _{s}^{\# } = \frac{{25(1 - \alpha )^{2} ((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)^{2} }}{{128k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{2} }}\); otherwise, \(\Pi _{s}^{\# } = \frac{{(1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)(5(1 - \alpha )((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)K(\alpha ,\rho ) - 32ck((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} )}}{{(K(\alpha ,\rho ))^{2} }}c\).

  1. (2)

    If the downstream retailer refuses to obtain information about consumers’ quality preference, then the upstream supplier solves the following optimization problem:

    $$ \begin{aligned} & Max\Pi _{s}^{N} (m) = \frac{{(1 - \alpha )((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)}}{{2((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)}}m - \frac{{km^{2} }}{2} \\ & \quad s.t.\;c > \frac{{K(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{8((1 + \alpha )^{2} - 8\alpha + 8)^{2} }}m. \\ \end{aligned} $$

We can obtain the optimal solution to the optimization problem as follows: if \(c > \frac{{(1 - \alpha )((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)K(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{2k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{2} }}\), then \(m^{*} = \frac{{(1 - \alpha )(\rho ^{2} \alpha ^{2} - 2\rho (4 - \rho )\alpha + (\rho + 2)^{2} )}}{{2k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)}}\); otherwise, \(m^{{\text{*}}} = \frac{{(1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8}}{{K(\alpha ,\rho )}}c\). Therefore, when \(c > \frac{{(1 - \alpha )((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)K(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{2k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{2} }}\), the profits of the upstream supplier are \(\Pi _{s}^{*} = \frac{{(1 - \alpha )^{2} ((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)^{2} }}{{8k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{2} }}\); otherwise, \(\Pi _{s}^{{\text{*}}} = \frac{{(1 - \alpha )((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)}}{{2((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)}} - \frac{{8ck((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{2} }}{{K(\alpha ,\rho )}}\).□

The following inequality holds:

\(\frac{{25(1 - \alpha )^{2} ((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)^{2} }}{{128k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{2} }} \ge \frac{{(1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)(5(1 - \alpha )((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)K(\alpha ,\rho ) - 32ck((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} )}}{{(K(\alpha ,\rho ))^{2} }}c\); \(\frac{{(1 - \alpha )^{2} ((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)^{2} }}{{8k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{2} }} \ge \frac{{(1 - \alpha )((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)}}{{2((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)}} - \frac{{8ck((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{2} }}{{K(\alpha ,\rho )}}\); \(\frac{{25(1 - \alpha )^{2} ((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)^{2} }}{{128k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{2} }} \ge \frac{{(1 - \alpha )^{2} ((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)^{2} }}{{8k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{2} }}\).

Therefore, we can derive that (1) when \(c \le \tilde{c}_{2} (\alpha ,\rho ,k) = \frac{{5(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{64k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }}\), the online retailer opts to obtain consumers’ quality preference information; (2) when \(\frac{{5(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{64k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }} = \tilde{c}_{2} (\alpha ,\rho ,k) < c \le \tilde{c}_{3} (\alpha ,\rho ,k) = \frac{{(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{8k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }}\), the upstream supplier induces the online retailer to obtain information about consumers’ quality preferences by improving product quality level; and (3) when \(c > \tilde{c}_{3} (\alpha ,\rho ,k)\), the upstream supplier induces the online retailer not to obtain consumers’ quality preference information.

1.6 Corollary 3

The process of the proof is similar to that of Corollary 1. Therefore, we omit the related discussion here for brevity.

1.7 Corollary 4

Proof

In accordance with Proposition 3, for the supplier, when \(c \le \tilde{c}_{2} (\alpha ,\rho ,k) = \frac{{5(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{64k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }}\), his profits are independent of information acquisition cost. When \(\frac{{5(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{64k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }} = \tilde{c}_{2} (\alpha ,\rho ,k) < c \le \tilde{c}_{3} (\alpha ,\rho ,k) = \frac{{(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{8k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }}\), \(\frac{{\partial \Pi _{s}^{\# } }}{{\partial c}} = \frac{{((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)(64ck((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} - 5(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{K(\alpha ,\rho )}} < 0\), but when \(c > \tilde{c}_{3} (\alpha ,\rho ,k) = \frac{{(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{8k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }}\), his profits are independent of information acquisition cost. Given that supplier profit is a continuous function of information disclosure cost, this profit tends to decrease along with information acquisition cost.□

For the online retailer, when \(c \le \tilde{c}_{2} (\alpha ,\rho ,k) = \frac{{5(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{64k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }}\), her profit decreases linearly along with acquisition cost. When \(\frac{{5(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{64k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }} = \tilde{c}_{2} (\alpha ,\rho ,k) < c \le \tilde{c}_{3} (\alpha ,\rho ,k) = \frac{{(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{8k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }}\), her profits increase linearly along with information acquisition cost. However, there is a declining jump in profits for downstream retailers when \(c = \tilde{c}_{3} (\alpha ,\rho ,k) = \frac{{(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{8k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }}\). Moreover, when \(c > \tilde{c}_{3} (\alpha ,\rho ,k) = \frac{{(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{8k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }}\), the profits of the online retailer are independent of information acquisition cost.

1.8 Propositions 4 and 5

Comparing the results for Propositions 1 to 3 yields Propositions 4 and 5. Therefore, we omit the related discussion here for simplicity.

1.9 Proposition 6

Proof

According to Propositions 2 and 3, when \(c \le \tilde{c}_{2} (\alpha ,\rho ,k) = \frac{{5(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{64k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }}\) or \(c > \tilde{c}_{1} (\alpha ,\rho ,k) = \frac{{9(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{64k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }}\), the profits of the downstream retailer, upstream suppliers, and the whole supply chain differ between the two acquisition strategies. We only focus on \(\tilde{c}_{2} (\alpha ,\rho ,k) < c \le \tilde{c}_{1} (\alpha ,\rho ,k)\) below:

  1. (1)

    When \(\frac{{5(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{64k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }} = \tilde{c}_{2} (\alpha ,\rho ,k) < c \le \tilde{c}_{3} (\alpha ,\rho ,k) = \frac{{(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{8k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }}\), \(\Pi _{r}^{{\text{*}}} - \Pi_{r}^{\# } {\text{ = }}\frac{{25(1 - \alpha )((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)K(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{64k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }} - 5c \le 0\), \(\begin{gathered} \Pi _{s}^{*} - \Pi _{s}^{\# } = \frac{{25(1 - \alpha )^{2} ((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)^{2} }}{{128k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{2} }} \hfill \\ - \frac{{(1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)(5(1 - \alpha )((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)K(\alpha ,\rho ) - 32ck((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} )}}{{(K(\alpha ,\rho ))^{2} }}c \ge 0 \hfill \\ \end{gathered}\), \((\Pi _{r}^{*} + \Pi _{s}^{*} ) - (\Pi _{r}^{\# } + \Pi _{s}^{\# } ) < 0\).

  2. (2)

    When \(\frac{{(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{8k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }} = \tilde{c}_{3} (\alpha ,\rho ,k) < c \le \tilde{c}_{1} (\alpha ,\rho ,k) = \frac{{9(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{64k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }}\), \(\Pi _{r}^{*} - \Pi _{r}^{\# } = \frac{{25(1 - \alpha )((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)K(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{64k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }} - \frac{{(1 - \alpha )T(\alpha ,\rho )}}{{4k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{3} }} - c \ge 0\), \(\Pi _{s}^{*} - \Pi _{s}^{\# } = \frac{{25(1 - \alpha )^{2} ((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)^{2} }}{{128k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{2} }} - \frac{{(1 - \alpha )^{2} ((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho ^{2} + 4(1 - 2\alpha )\rho + 4)^{2} }}{{8k((1 + \alpha )^{2} \rho - 8\alpha + 8)^{2} }} > 0\), \((\Pi _{r}^{*} + \Pi _{s}^{*} ) - (\Pi _{r}^{\# } + \Pi _{s}^{\# } ) > 0\).□

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Wu, H., Zheng, H. & Li, J. The interplay between quality improvement and information acquisition in an E-commerce supply chain. Ann Oper Res 329, 847–870 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-021-04158-1

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-021-04158-1

Keywords

Navigation