1 Introduction

The evaluation of natural resource investments under uncertainty has historically been one of the most popular areas of application of real options analysis (ROA). Considering their very capital intensive and largely irreversible nature as well as the high degrees of uncertainty involved, ROA is well-suited to evaluate natural resource investments. Given the wide applicability of ROAFootnote 1 in terms of scope and scale, applications in this area are numerous and encompass a wealth of renewable and non-renewable natural resources. Following the more general works of Tourinho (1979); Pindyck (1980), early studies on natural resource investments focused on minerals (Trigeorgis 1990) and metals including copper (Brennan and Schwartz 1985) and gold (Kelly 1998); agricultural commodities such as rubber/palm-oil (Bailey 1991) and lumber/timber (Clarke and Reed 1989; Morck et al. 1989); land (Quigg 1993); as well as conventional fossil energy such as oil and gas (Paddock et al. 1988; Ekern 1988; Bjerksund and Ekern 1990). In particular the study of Brennan and Schwartz (1985), which is widely regarded as a “pioneering article” (Dixit and Pindyck 1994) and “seminal paper” (Lambrecht 2017), has received considerably attention from academics.

Natural resource investments typically contain many interacting flexibilities and their performance is generally affected by multiple uncertainties. For example, the original copper mine example of Brennan and Schwartz (1985) considered a portfolio of options: to temporarily mothball and irreversibly abandon the mine. Relevant portfolio extensions include the option to delay/defer the mine’s development (Gamba 2003); the option to expand production capacity (Cortazar and Casassus 1998); and a combined approach with operational, development and exploration options (Cortazar et al. 2001). The work of Brennan and Schwartz (1985) was not only one of the first to consider multiple options, but it also accounted for copper price uncertainty directly, rather than through a (single) risk-adjusted discount rate. Building upon their simple one-factor, constant-convenience model, where the price dynamics are described by a geometric Brownian motion, subsequent works aimed at accounting for the mean-reverting tendency of many commodities’ spot prices. In the joint stochastic process of the two-factor model of Gibson and Schwartz (1990) the convenience yield evolves stochastically by following an Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process, and the three-factor model of Schwartz (1997) extends this two-factor model by assuming that the risk-free interest rate also follows such a simple mean-reverting process (see, e.g., Cortazar and Schwartz (2003); Casassus and Collin-Dufresne (2005) for related models).

To value the flexibility provided by real options inherent in natural resource investments whilst accounting for uncertainty, there are, broadly speaking, three types of valuation approaches based on partial differential equations (PDEs), lattice models, or simulation (i.e. Monte Carlo sampling). Considering a hypothetical copper mine, Brennan and Schwartz (1985) first demonstrated how the value of such a natural resource investment can be mathematically modelled by PDEsFootnote 2 and then numerically approximated using a finite-difference method. Subsequently, Cortazar and Schwartz (1997) applied such an approach in the context of an undeveloped oil field. Following the development of the binomial options pricing model by Cox et al. (1979), early applications of binomial lattice techniques evaluated petroleum projects (Ekern 1988) and a gold mine (Kelly 1998). See McCarthy and Monkhouse (2002) for a mine-related application of a trinominal lattice technique (Boyle 1988). Due to their origin in option-pricing theory, the application of the above two types of valuation approaches to real assets is sometimes referred to as contingent claims analysis (Bjerksund and Ekern 1990).

Unlike PDE-based finite differences and binomial techniques, simulation-based approaches are readily applicable in multi-factor situations. Initially developed for the pricing of European call options by Boyle (1977), subsequent works presented simulation-based approaches to value American-style options. These include the bundling algorithm of Tilley (1993); the partitioning algorithm of Barraquand and Martineau (1995), which was applied to on an oil field example by Cortazar and Schwartz (1998); and an extension of the latter algorithm by Raymar and Zwecher (1997), which Castillo-Ramirez (2000) tested using the mine example of Brennan and Schwartz (1985). By contrast, the popular works of Carriere (1996); Tsitsiklis and Van Roy (2001); Longstaff and Schwartz (2001) combine simulation with regression to approximately solve the optimal stopping problem embedded in the pricing of American options. Extending the least-squares Monte Carlo (LSM) method of Longstaff and Schwartz (2001) to optimal switching problems, Gamba (2003), Abdel Sabour and Poulin (2006), Cortazar et al. (2008) re-assessed the copper mine example of Brennan and Schwartz (1985). However, as noted by Abdel Sabour and Poulin (2006), the switching decisions obtained by Gamba (2003), Cortazar et al. (2008) are not in line with Brennan and Schwartz (1985) and are also inconsistent because the switching policy of Gamba (2003) is cyclic in the copper price rather than being linear, and the policy implied by Cortazar et al. (2008) indicates that it is optimal to open the mine at US$ 0.70/lbs. Multi-factor model extensions of the mine example were studied by Cortazar et al. (2008), who applied the three-factor model of Cortazar and Schwartz (2003), and Tsekrekos et al. (2012) considered both the two-factor model of Gibson and Schwartz (1990) and the three-factor models of Schwartz (1997); Casassus and Collin-Dufresne (2005).

The capabilities of existing valuation approaches restrict the analysis of natural resource investments and the insights that can be gained by such analysis in different ways. Continuous-time approaches such as those based on PDEs are arguably the most popular choice amongst academics conducting theoretical research. This is because although PDE-based modelling is intuitively unappealing and (mathematically) complex, the obtained solutions and exercise policies are sometimes available in closed-form and often more tractable than those obtained by mathematically simpler discrete-time approaches such as those based on binomial techniques and simulation (Glasserman 2003; Brandão et al. 2005a, b; Lambrecht 2017). However, PDE-based finite differences as well as binomial techniques quickly lose their tractability in multi-factor situations and when there is path-dependencyFootnote 3 (Lambrecht 2017). In contrast, simulation-based approaches are readily applicable in such situations. To overcome the limitations of the LSM approach when it comes to valuing option portfolios (Smith 2005; Brandão et al. 2005a), several recent works introduced simulation-based alternatives. For example, Maier et al. (2020) proposed the influence diagram simulation-and-regression (IDSR) approach to value portfolios of interdependent real options and applied it to a complex natural resource investment that features four stochastic factors. Despite these successes, the key limitations of “black box” simulation-based valuation approaches are a lack of transparency and the difficulty to validate results (Brandão et al. 2005a; Lambrecht 2017).

In this work we re-evaluate a natural resource investment under three different models of the stochastic dynamics of commodity prices using the IDSR approach. The copper mine example under a simple one-factor model was initially evaluated in the seminal work of Brennan and Schwartz (1985), who mathematically modelled and numerically approximated the valuation problem using PDEs and finite-differences, respectively. This example serves as our benchmark natural resource investment in which only the copper spot price evolves stochastically (see Sect. 2). While we obtained results for both the mine values and the switching decisions that are in line with the ones of Brennan and Schwartz (1985), we detected, quite unexpectedly, technical issues in both the definitions and values of their fixed-output-rate mine and closure option (see Sect. 3). We performed a comprehensive portfolio analysis enabled by the IDSR approach and show that their fixed-output-rate mine includes the option to abandon the mine, whereas a fixed-output-rate mine does not, in fact, include any options. We demonstrate that the definition of their closure option is flawed due to an inconsistency in the way it is calculated, and also that its value is incorrect as it corresponds to the value of mothballing within the options portfolio. To account for mean reversion in the copper spot price, we replace the one-factor model with the highly-cited two- and three-factor models of Gibson and Schwartz (1990) and Schwartz (1997), respectively.

These important multi-factor extensions of our benchmark investment—first to a stochastic convenience yield and then to stochastic interest rates—were previously investigated by Tsekrekos et al. (2012) applying the LSM approach. However, when re-examining the effects of the two- and three-factor model on the mine value using the parameters of Tsekrekos et al. (2012) and comparing values, we find values that are noticeably different from those of Tsekrekos et al. (2012), and note also that our mine values exhibit the opposite behaviour with respect to changes of the correlation between the copper price and convenience yield process (see Sects. 4 and 5). To validate our results, we use a key insight from options theory about the investment-uncertainty relationship: higher volatility in the underlying generally leads to a higher investment value. As a proxy measure of the investment’s overall volatility we use analytical expressions that describe the volatilities implied by the multi-factor models and that are derived from solutions to futures prices’ PDEs. This enabled us to confirm our IDSR-based results by demonstrating that an increase in this correlation coefficient actually reduces overall (or total) volatility and, as such, mine value; by contrast, Tsekrekos et al. (2012) found values to be increasing in that coefficient. In addition, applying this proxy measure enabled us to disprove other related findings of their analyses such as the impact of the short rate’s volatility, thus providing further evidence of the benefit of implied volatilities in the analysis of natural resource investments in multi-factor situations.

Finally, in Sect. 6, we discuss existing option pricing and decision analysis approaches in the light of the findings obtained under the different stochastic models. We argue that while the limitations of PDE-based finite difference approaches may invalidate their use as practical and reliable methods for the valuation and analysis of portfolios of real options, analytical expressions obtained from PDE-based modelling may be profitably integrated into a simulation-based numerical analysis both to validate results and to provide new insights. These insights include demonstrating that the volatilities of futures returns implied by the considered multi-factor models may well be used as an adequate proxy measure for the copper mine project’s actual overall (or total) volatility. The implied volatilities can then be used to analyse the effects of the complex models’ parameters on investment values through their impact on overall volatility within the well-known investment-uncertainty relationship. Given the generally non-linear, non-monotonic dependency of overall volatility (and hence investment value) on models’ individual parameters, our analysis demonstrates that even though an individual stochastic factor becomes more volatile, the investment value may decrease as a result of a decline in overall volatility. This highlights the importance of applying such a transparent and intuitive approach for investment analysis in multi-factor situations.

The rest of our article is organised as follows: Sect. 2 presents the re-evaluation of a natural resource investment in a one-factor setting. Results of this re-evaluation are presented and discussed in Sect. 3. Section 4 extends this benchmark investment by considering two multi-factor models. Results of this extension are then presented and discussed in Sect. 5. In Sect. 6 we discuss existing option pricing and decision analysis approaches in the light of the findings obtained, and provide some concluding remarks.

2 Natural resource investments: the one-factor benchmark

In this section we re-evaluate the classical example of valuing a copper mine originally proposedFootnote 4 by Brennan and Schwartz (1985) applying the IDSR approach.

2.1 Problem setting

In this copper mine example, the decision maker has several possibilities to affect the mine’s operation. While it only contains one stochastic factor (copper spot price), the operational flexibility available in this copper mine example represents a portfolio of interdependent real options, which we refer to as the option to switch. This and the portfolio’s constituent real options are:

  1. (a)

    Option to switch: In addition to extracting the copper immediately until the mine inventory, \(Q_0\), is exhausted, the decision maker may decide to temporarily close the (operating) mine, to maintain or reopen the mine when it is closed, and/or to irreversibly abandon the copper mine before its inventory is fully exhausted, i.e. before \(Q_0/q\) years of operation at an annual output rate of q.

    1. (a-i)

      Option to temporarily mothball the mine: If the copper spot price at time t, \(X_t\), is too low in relation to the mine’s production costs, \(A_t\), the decision maker can close down the opened (i.e. operating) mine at a cost of \(K^{c}_t\), maintain the closed mine at an annual maintenance cost of \(M_t\), and, if the copper price becomes favourable again, reopen the closed mine at a cost of \(K^{o}_t\) at time t.

    2. (a-ii)

      Option to irreversibly abandon the mine: Whether opened or closed, the decision maker retains the right to permanently abandon the copper mine at any time t without incurring any cost.

The value of this portfolio of real options is affected by the uncertainty surrounding future commodity prices, in other words by copper price uncertainty. The copper spot price at time t, \(X_t\), is assumed to evolve according to a discretised version of the geometric Brownian motion used by Brennan and Schwartz (1985).

Fig. 1
figure 1

Influence diagram for the copper mine project – configuration (a)

2.2 Modelling

The flexibilities inherent in the copper mine are illustrated by the ID in Fig. 1. It contains two decision nodes (Opened (1) and Closed (4)) and two terminal nodes (Abandoned (2) and Exhausted (3)), as well as seven transitions that link these nodes, resulting in \({\mathcal {N}}=\{1,2,3,4 \}\) and \({\mathcal {H}}=\{1,2,\ldots ,7 \}\). The duration (in years) of transition \(h \in {\mathcal {H}}\) is \(\varDelta _h\). When the mine is Opened, the decision maker has to decide whether to Operate (1) for \(\varDelta _1\) year(s) whilst extracting \(q\varDelta _1\) of copper, temporarily Close (3), or irreversibly Abandon (4) the mine project. On the other hand, if the mine is Closed, the available transitions are to keep the mine Idle (6), Open (5) it, or irreversibly Abandon (7) the project. However, the mine closures (2) if the inventory is fully depleted and, as such, becomes Exhausted. Also, for the sake of definiteness, the mine has to be Abandoned when reaching its maximum lifetime of \(T^{max}\) years, thereby preventing the mine from having an infinite lifetime.

Let the node and the inventory of the mine at time t be denoted by \(N_t\) and \(Q_t\), respectively, as well as let the copper spot price at time t be denoted by \(X_t\). Then, the resource and information component of the state variable \(S_t\) are given by \(R_t=(t,N_t,Q_t)\) and \(I_t=X_t\), respectively. The state variable is then written as \(S_t=(t,N_t,Q_t,X_t)\). Since the mine’s commodity inventory can be depleted at an annual output rate q, which is assumed constant, it takes at least \(Q_0/q\) years to empty the finite inventory. While the assumption of a finite horizon (\(T^{max}\)) may result in an approximated numerical solution, adverse effects can be minimised, even avoided fully, by choosing \(T^{max} \gg Q_0/q\).

The binary decision variables \((a_{th})_{h \in b^D(N_t)}\) associated with transitions h (\(a_{th}=1\) if h is made at time t, and 0 otherwise) available at node \(N_t\) at time t, \(b^D(N_t)\), which are given by:

$$\begin{aligned} b^D(N_t) = {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \{ 1,2,3,4 \}, &{} \text {if } N_t=1,\\ \{ 5,6,7 \}, &{} \text {if } N_t=4,\\ \{\}, &{} \text {otherwise,} \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(1)

have to satisfy the feasible region \({\mathcal {A}}_{S_t}\), which is defined by the following set of constraints:

$$\begin{aligned}&a_{t1} + a_{t2} + a_{t3} + a_{t4} = 1 \qquad \qquad \text {if } N_t=1, \end{aligned}$$
(2)
$$\begin{aligned}&a_{t5} + a_{t6} + a_{t7} = 1 \qquad \qquad \qquad \quad \, \text {if } N_t=4, \end{aligned}$$
(3)
$$\begin{aligned}&a_{th} q \varDelta _h \le Q_t \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \, \forall h \in \{1,5 \}, \end{aligned}$$
(4)
$$\begin{aligned}&-Q_t < a_{t2} \le 1 - \frac{Q_t}{Q_0},&\end{aligned}$$
(5)
$$\begin{aligned}&t - T^{max} < a_{t2} + a_{t4},&\end{aligned}$$
(6)
$$\begin{aligned}&t - T^{max} < a_{t7}, \end{aligned}$$
(7)

where \(a_{th} \in \{0,1\}, \forall h \in {\mathcal {H}}\). These constraints accomplish the following: (2) and (3) ensure that exactly one transition is made at decision node 1 and 4, respectively; (4) make sure the inventory does not become negativeFootnote 5; (5) requires the mine to closure if and only if \(Q_t=0\); (6) ensures that if \(t=T^{max}\) and \(Q_{T^{max}}>0\) then \(a_{T^{max}4}=1\); and, lastly, (7) makes sure the mine is abandoned if closed at \(t=T^{max}\).

After having made a decision subject to these constraints, the resource state \(R_t\) evolves deterministically to \(R_{t+\varDelta _h}\) according to \(S^R(\cdot )\), whereas the information state \(I_t\) evolves stochastically to \(I_{t+\varDelta _h}\) under the risk-neutral measure represented by \(S^I(\cdot )\). With regard to \(S^R(\cdot )\), the evolution of t is straightforward as it simply evolves from t to \(t+\varDelta _h\), the evolution of \(N_t\) is implied by the adjacency matrix of the digraph \(({\mathcal {N}},{\mathcal {H}})\):

and the evolution of \(Q_t\) is specified by the following transition equation for all \(h \in {\mathcal {H}}\):

$$\begin{aligned} Q_{t+\varDelta _h} = Q_t - q \varDelta _1 (a_{t1} + a_{t5}) \end{aligned}$$
(8)

On the other hand, the copper spot price at time t, \(X_t\), evolves stochastically to \(X_{t+\varDelta _h}\) according to the following discrete diffusion process:

$$\begin{aligned} X_{t+\varDelta _h} = X_t \exp \left\{ \left( r -\delta - \frac{\sigma _x^2}{2} \right) \varDelta _h + \sigma _x \sqrt{\varDelta _h} \epsilon ^{x}_{t+\varDelta _h} \right\} , \end{aligned}$$
(9)

where r is the price trend, \(\delta \) is the instantaneous convenience yield, \(\sigma _x\) is the standard deviation of price changes, and \(\epsilon ^{x}_{t+\varDelta _h}\) is the driving zero-mean process—a standard normal random variable whose increments are iid.

The payoff obtained at t when making decision \(a_{t}\) given state \(S_t\) is:

$$\begin{aligned} \varPi _{t}\big ( S_t,a_t \big ) = {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} q\varDelta _1(X_t-A_t)-f(X_t) \varDelta _1,&{} \text {if }\quad a_{t1}=1, \\ -M_t \varDelta _3 -K^c_t,&{} \text {if }\quad a_{t3}=1, \\ q\varDelta _5(X_t-A_t)-f(X_t) \varDelta _5 -K^o_t,&{} \text {if }\quad a_{t5}=1, \\ -M_t \varDelta _6, &{} \text {if }\quad a_{t6}=1, \\ 0, &{} \text {otherwise}, \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(10)

where \(A_t=A_0 e^{\pi t}\) is the average (per unit) production cost at time t with inflation rate \(\pi \); \(f(X_t)=\tau _1 q X_t + \max \{\tau _2 q (X_t (1-\tau _1) - A_t), 0 \}\) is the sum of royalties and income tax paid at time t with \(\tau _1\) the royalty rate and \(\tau _2\) the income tax rate; \(M_t=M_0 e^{\pi t}\) is the maintenance cost at time t; and \(K^c_t=K^c_0 e^{\pi t}\) and \(K^o_t=K^o_0 e^{\pi t}\) are the costs to switch to the Closed and Opened node at time t, respectively.

2.3 Portfolio optimisation problem

The problem of determining the optimal value of the copper mine can be formulated as a multi-stage stochastic optimisation problem and then be solved algorithmically, in theory, via stochastic dynamic programming (SDP) recursions, as described by Maier et al. (2020). Let the optimal value of the copper mine at time t given state \(S_{t}\) be denoted by \(G_{t}(S_{t})\). The value of the copper mine, \(G_0(S_0)\), is then given by the optimal solution of:

$$\begin{aligned} G_{0}(S_{0}) =\! \underset{(a_t)_{t \in {\mathcal {T}}}}{\max } \,\, {\mathbb {E}} \Big [ \sum \nolimits _{t \in {\mathcal {T}}} e^{-k t} \varPi _{t}( S_{t},a_{t} ) \big \vert S_0 \Big ], \end{aligned}$$
(11)

where \(S_0\) is the state at time 0, \(a_t = (a_{th} )_{h \in b^D(N_{t}) }\), \(a_t \in {\mathcal {A}}_{S_{t}}\), \(a_{th} \in \{0,1\}\), k is the discount rate, and \(S_{t+\varDelta _h} = S^M(S_{t}, a_{t}, W_{t+\varDelta _{h}})\) with \(W_{t+\varDelta _{h}}=\epsilon ^{x}_{t+\varDelta _h}\).

To determine an optimal policy, i.e. a decision vector \(a_t^{*}=\big (a_t^{*}(S_t)\big )_{S_t \in {\mathcal {S}}_t}\) for all \(t \in {\mathcal {T}}\) that maximises the mine value given the state \(S_0\) at time 0, \(G_{0} (S_{0})\), we apply Bellman’s “principle of optimality” and hence solve the stochastic optimisation problem (11) recursively using the following value function when in state \(S_t\) at t:

$$\begin{aligned} G_{t} (S_{t})&= \underset{a_t}{\max } \bigg (\varPi _{t}(S_{t},a_t) + {\mathbb {E}} \Big [ e^{-k \varDelta _{h}} G_{t+\varDelta _{h}} (S_{t+\varDelta _{h}}) \big \vert S_t, a_t \Big ]\bigg ) \end{aligned}$$
(12)
$$\begin{aligned}&\ \ \quad \text {s.t.} \quad \ a_t \in {\mathcal {A}}_{S_{t}}, \end{aligned}$$
(13)
$$\begin{aligned}&\quad \ \quad a_{th} \in \{0,1\} \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \forall h \in b^D(N_{t}), \end{aligned}$$
(14)
$$\begin{aligned}&\quad \ \quad S_{t+\varDelta _{h}} = S^M(S_{t}, a_t, W{_{t+\varDelta _{h}}}) \quad \; \forall h \in b^D(N_{t}), \end{aligned}$$
(15)

with the terminal condition \(G_t(S_t)=0\), for all \(S_{t} \in \big \{ S_t^{\prime } \in {\mathcal {S}}_t: b^D(N_t^{\prime }) = \emptyset \big \}, t \in {\mathcal {T}}\).

Ultimately, since the SDP recursion (12)-(15) is, in general, computationally intractable, the value of the mine, \(G_{0} (S_{0})\), is approximated through a simulation-and-regression-based solution procedure that consists of a forward and backward induction—both are described in “Appendix A”, giving the approximation \({\bar{G}}_{0} (S_{0})\).Footnote 6

Table 1 Data for hypothetical copper mine of Brennan and Schwartz (1985)

2.4 Valuation

With regard to the valuation of this natural resource investment, we used the same parameter values as Brennan and Schwartz (1985), which are shown in Table 1. Furthermore, we considered five decisions to be made per year (i.e. \(\varDelta _1=\varDelta _3=\varDelta _5=\varDelta _6=1/5\), whereas \(\varDelta _2=\varDelta _4=\varDelta _7=0\)Footnote 7) and the first six (i.e. \(L=5\)) generalized Chebyshev polynomials as basis functions. Also, as in Tsekrekos et al. (2012), we considered 100,000 (\(=\vert \varOmega \vert \)) sample paths (half of which antithetic for variance reduction), where \(\varOmega \) is the set of sample realisations. While the inventory of the mine can be depleted as early as 15 years (=\(Q_0/q\)) after starting operation, a finite time horizon of \(T^{max}=60\) years was chosen for the time by which the right to extract copper from the mine expires. Since there is no payoff associated with transitions 4 and 7 nor a terminal value with the Abandoned node, we can use a constant discount rate of 12% (\(k=r+\lambda _1\)) in our computations.

Using the initialisation from the forward pass and applying the backward induction procedure of “Appendix A”, results are presented and discussed in the following section. Figure 5 provides an illustration of sample paths.

3 Results and discussion: the one-factor benchmark

This section begins with an analysis of the way in which the value of the (initially) opened and closed mine, \({\bar{G}}_{0} (S_{0})\), characterised by \(S_0=(0,1,Q_0,X_0)\) and \(S_0=(0,4,Q_0,X_0)\), respectively, are affected by the initial price of copper, \(X_0\). The results are shown in Table 2 and compared with those of Brennan and Schwartz (1985), who applied PDE-based finite differences. In terms of the mine values (the switching decisions), our IDSR-based numerical results converge very closely (are identical) to the ones obtained by Brennan and Schwartz (1985) and are in line with the conclusions reached by Abdel Sabour and Poulin (2006); Tsekrekos et al. (2012), thus confirming the adequacy of the IDSR approach to correctly value such a natural resource investment. “Appendix C” contains an analysis of the effects of the copper price and its uncertainty on the value of this benchmark natural resource investment.

Table 2 Value (in US$ millions) of mine for different copper prices according to alternative numerical methods
Table 3 Value of opened copper mine, \(\bar{G_0}(S_0)\) (in US$ millions), for different copper price levels

To evaluate the individual real options available in this natural resource investment, this section now analyses the extent to which the mine value with different configurations of option portfolios depends on the initial copper price, \(X_0\). Table 3 shows the sensitivity of the value of different portfolio configurations when \(X_0\) is in the range from US$ 0.30 to 1.00 per pound. Column (–) gives the expected value of the fixed-output-rate mine, which assumes it is operated at the rate of 10 million pounds/year until the 15-year inventory is fully exhausted. As can be seen, this value is negative for copper prices of US$ 0.50 per pound and below, making operation unprofitable.Footnote 8 As described in Sect. 2.1, columns (a-i) and (a-ii) display the value of the mine if it can be temporarily mothballed and irreversibly abandoned, respectively. Having the flexibility provided by the former (latter) option enables the copper mine to become economically viable for prices of US$ 0.50 (0.40) per pound and above, thus allowing the mine with such options to become viable in situations where the fixed-output-rate mine is not. By contrast, with the option to switch, whose value is shown in column (a) and which can be interpreted as the portfolio of options to mothball and abandon, the mine is economically viable for all copper prices under consideration. The IDsFootnote 9 illustrating the managerial flexibility available in the setting of columns (–), (a-i), (a-ii) and (a) are shown by Figs. 2a, 2c, 2b and 1, respectively.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Influence diagrams for different copper mine settings

In addition, Table 3 also displays the value added by the portfolio’s individual options—both in isolation and within the portfolio of options. Columns (a-i)-(–), (a-ii)-(–) and (a)-(–) report the value of the options to mothball the mine, to abandon the mine and to switch, respectively. These values were determined by the difference between the mine values with these individual options—shown in columns (a-i), (a-ii) and (a)—and column (–), which gives the value of the fixed-output-rate mine. As can be seen, the real options considered add substantial value to this natural resource investment. For all copper prices under consideration, abandoning the mine was found to be more valuable than mothballing, and switching more valuable than abandoning. Importantly, the option to switch, which in itself is a portfolio of options containing the other two options, will always be at least as valuable than its constituent options. As expected, the values of these options decrease as the operating margin increases since operational flexibility becomes less attractive. Nevertheless, the added value of switching is still almost 13% for the highest copper price considered, which is twice the cost of production.

Columns (a)-(a-ii) and (a)-(a-i) of the table give the value of the option to mothball and to abandon the mine, respectively, within the portfolio of options. In other words, these columns report how much an individual real option adds to the portfolio assuming that the other individual option is already contained in the portfolio. To determine the value of one option, the value of the mine with the options portfolio was measured against the value of the mine with the other option. For example, the difference between column (a) and (a-ii) results in the values shown in column (a)-(a-ii). Comparing the values shown in column (a)-(a-ii) with the ones of column (a)-(a-i) shows that, while the value of either option in the portfolio generally decreases as \(X_0\) increasesFootnote 10, abandoning adds substantially more value to the portfolio than mothballing, especially for high copper prices. This result is very intuitive given the above presented valuation of the options to mothball and abandon in isolation. It is interesting to note, however, that the relative portfolio value of mothballing generally decreases as the initial price of copper increases, whereas the relative value of adding the abandonment option to the option to mothball the mine always increases in \(X_0\). This indicates that adding strategic flexibility (to limit downside risk by abandoning the mine early) to the mine that already has operational flexibility (to exploit upside risk by deviating from the immediate extraction of copper) is more valuable in this portfolio context than the other way around.

Although Brennan and Schwartz (1985) were able to provide several insights into the valuation of this small options portfolio, there are some technical issues in their analysis that impacted on the reliability of some of their results. Table 4 reports the results of their numerical analysis. According to Brennan and Schwartz (1985), the relevant columns of their table are defined as follows:

Table 4 Value (in US$ millions) of copper mine for different copper price levels according to Brennan and Schwartz (1985)

Column 4 gives the value of the mine assuming that it cannot be closed down but must be operated at the rate of 10 million pounds per year until the inventory is exhausted in 15 years. The difference between column 4 and the greater of the values shown in columns 2 and 3 represents the value of the option to close down or abandon the mine if the price of copper falls far enough. The value of this closure option is shown in column 5. (Brennan and Schwartz 1985)

However, while the values reported in columns (2) and (3) have been widely confirmed in the literature including this work (see Table 2), both the definitions of the values and the actual values shown in columns (4) and (5) are flawed.

Firstly, the values of the fixed-output-rate mine shown in column (4) are given as positive (and convex in \(X_0\)) for all copper prices under consideration. By contrast, and as we would expect, we have found that the expected value of the mine—assuming copper must be extracted immediately until the 15-year inventory is fully exhausted—is highly negative if operating margins are low, and that this value is an increasing yet concave function of \(X_0\). As seen in column (–) of Table 3, the value of the fixed-output-rate mine is negative for copper prices of US$ 0.50 per pound and below. Our results are in line with Cortazar et al. (2008), who performed a comparative static analysis and showed that, considering the three-factor commodity model of Cortazar and Schwartz (2003), the expected NPV of the mine without any flexibility is negative for low spot prices of copper—see also Castillo-Ramirez (2000); Lin and Wang (2012). In addition to noting that the value of the mine with the option to switch is convex in \(X_0\), the figure shown by Cortazar et al. (2008) also appears to illustrate that the value of the fixed-output-rate mine is concave in \(X_0\), whilst converging to the value of the opened mine for high commodity prices.

The detailed portfolio analysis presented here gives insights into why the fixed-output-rate mine might have been overvalued in the analysis of Brennan and Schwartz (1985). Comparing these values in column (4) of Table 4 with our results in Table 3 shows that there is a similarity between their values and the values we have obtained for the mine with the option to abandon—see column (a-ii). This similarity suggests that their fixed-output-rate mine actually includes the option to abandon. Even though our results tend to be slightly low-biased in relation to theirs, particularly for low copper prices, the overall patterns are very similar. Surprisingly, our hypothesis that the fixed-output-rate mine of Brennan and Schwartz (1985) includes the abandonment option even seems to be confirmed by the authors themselves, who stated in their paper, two paragraphs below the one we cited above, that:

Ownership of a mine [...] involves three distinct types of decision possibilities or options: first, the decision to begin operations; second, the decision to close the mine when it is currently operating (and possibly to reopen it later), which we have referred to as the closure option; and third, the decision to abandon the mine early, before the inventory is exhausted. (Brennan and Schwartz 1985)

This statement seems inconsistent with the authors’ earlier definition presented above. In the earlier statement, Brennan and Schwartz (1985) define close down or abandon the mine as representing the closure option. However, the case of their fixed-output-rate mine represents actually a mine with the early abandonment option, and their closure option does not correspond with “the option to close down or abandon the mine” (Brennan and Schwartz 1985), which we have referred to as the option to switch. Instead, their closure option corresponds to an option that looks like our option to temporarily mothball the mine. Using IDs to graphically illustrate this inconsistency, for the fixed-output-rate mine, it appears that Brennan and Schwartz (1985) have considered the case that corresponds with the ID of Fig. 2b instead of the correct one shown by Fig. 2a, and the flexibility of their closure option (which is problematic in itself, as discussed in the following paragraph) corresponds to the ID of Fig. 2c rather than to the ID shown in Fig. 1.

Secondly, the definition of the closure option in Brennan and Schwartz (1985) is inconsistent, and this leads to an incorrect valuation. Given by the “difference between column 4 and the greater of the values shown in columns 2 and 3” (Brennan and Schwartz 1985), the value of their closure option is determined by subtracting a benchmark mine value—i.e. the value of the “fixed-output-rate mine”—from the maximum value of two different mines—an opened and a closed one. However, the minuend of this subtraction is inconsistent with its subtrahend given that the latter assumes the mine is opened at time \(t=0\) (\(N_0=1\)), whereas the former represents a mine that is either opened (\(N_0=1\)) or closed (\(N_0=4\)) at the beginning, so performing this subtraction does not generate meaningful data. The data thus obtained is therefore irrelevant regardless of the benchmark applied, that is whether the (real) value of the fixed-output-rate mine (Fig. 2a) or the value of the mine with the option to abandon (Fig. 2b) is being used since both have the same initial state. Moreover, since their benchmark values in column (4) seemingly correspond with the values of the mine with the option to abandon, the values shown in column (5) do not represent, as implied by the authors’ definition, the value of the closure option in isolation but instead within the portfolio that already contains the early abandonment option. Our analysis—the relevant values are given by column (a)-(a-ii) of Table 3—seems to confirm this when taking into account the above mentioned bias and inconsistency.

4 Natural resource investments: two- and three-factor model extensions

In this section we extend the mine example by integrating the two- and three-factor model of Gibson and Schwartz (1990) and Schwartz (1997), respectively.

4.1 Problem setting

While the original copper mine example of Brennan and Schwartz (1985) contained a portfolio of interdependent real options, it only treated the commodity spot price, i.e. the price of copper, to be stochastic. Here we extend their example by additionally considering both the instantaneous convenience yield and the instantaneous interest rate to be stochastic. As such, in terms of options portfolio considered this setting is the same as the one described in Sect. 2. In terms of uncertainties considered, however, we replace the one-factor setting of Brennan and Schwartz (1985) by the three-factor model of Schwartz (1997), which nests the two-factor model of Gibson and Schwartz (1990). Let the copper spot price, the instantaneous convenience yield, and the instantaneous interest rate at time t be denoted by \(X_t\), \(\delta _t\), and \(r_t\), respectively. As in Tsekrekos et al. (2012), the evolution of these three stochastic factors is described by discretised versions of the continuous stochastic processes of Schwartz (1997). Note that the two-factor model (copper price and convenience yield are stochastic) of Gibson and Schwartz (1990) is obtained by making the interest rate constant, i.e. by setting \(r_t=r_0\, \forall t \in {\mathcal {T}}\).

4.2 Modelling

The modelling of this investment problem is to a large extent identical to the modelling presented in Sect. 2.2; however, adaptations are necessary in the following two areas: the information state and its transition function. The information state component is given by \(I_t=(X_t,\delta _t,r_t)\). Hence, \(S_t=(t,N_t,Q_t,X_t,\delta _t,r_t)\). The information state \(I_t\) evolves to \(I_{t+\varDelta _h}\) according to:

$$\begin{aligned} X_{t+\varDelta _h}= & {} X_t \exp \left\{ \left( r_t -\delta _t - \frac{\sigma _x^2}{2} \right) \varDelta _h + \sigma _x \sqrt{\varDelta _h} \epsilon ^{x}_{t+\varDelta _h} \right\} , \end{aligned}$$
(16)
$$\begin{aligned} \delta _{t+\varDelta _h}= & {} \Big (1-e^{-\kappa _{\delta }\varDelta _h}\Big )\theta _{\delta } + e^{-\kappa _{\delta }\varDelta _h}\delta _t + \sigma _\delta \sqrt{ \frac{1-e^{-2\kappa _{\delta }\varDelta _h}}{2\kappa _\delta } } \epsilon ^{\delta }_{t+\varDelta _h}, \end{aligned}$$
(17)
$$\begin{aligned} r_{t+\varDelta _h}= & {} \Big (1-e^{-\kappa _r \varDelta _h}\Big )\theta _r + e^{-\kappa _r \varDelta _h}r_t + \sigma _r \sqrt{ \frac{1-e^{-2\kappa _r \varDelta _h}}{2\kappa _r} } \epsilon ^{r}_{t+\varDelta _h}, \end{aligned}$$
(18)

where \(\sigma _x\), \(\sigma _\delta \) and \(\sigma _r\) are the standard deviations of changes in \(X_t\), \(\delta _t\) and \(r_t\), respectively; \(\kappa _{\delta }\) and \(\kappa _{r}\) are positive mean reversion (speed of adjustment) coefficients; \(\theta _{\delta }\) and \(\theta _{r}\) are the long run mean of convenience yield and interest rate, respectively; and \(\epsilon ^{x}_{t+\varDelta _h}\), \(\epsilon ^{\delta }_{t+\varDelta _h}\) and \(\epsilon ^{r}_{t+\varDelta _h}\) are correlated standard normal random variables (mean 0, variance 1) with correlation matrix (= covariance matrix \(\varSigma \) here, see Glasserman (2003)):

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{pmatrix} 1 &{} \rho _{x,\delta } &{} \rho _{x,r} \\ \rho _{x,\delta } &{} 1 &{} \rho _{r,\delta } \\ \rho _{x,r} &{} \rho _{r,\delta } &{} 1 \end{pmatrix} \end{aligned}$$

4.3 Overall volatility and model equivalence

One of the key insights from (real) options theory is that there is a non-negative relationship between option value and underlying volatility, so higher volatility in the underlying asset generally results in a higher option value as flexibility becomes more valuable (Dixit and Pindyck 1994). In recent years, this relationship between option value and underlying uncertainty has received increasing interest by academics, e.g. see Caballero (1991); Sarkar (2000); Cappuccio and Moretto (2001); Lund (2005); Gryglewicz et al. (2008). Existing works have studied the investment-uncertainty relationship from a range of perspectives, that is considering different interpretations of this relationship such as the impact of uncertainty on the optimal investment trigger, or the probability that investment will take place in a certain time interval. In this work, we interpret the investment-uncertainty relationship as the effect of overall (or total) volatility on the value of the investment with the portfolio of real options.

As a proxy measure of the investment’s actual overall volatility, we use the volatility of commodity futures returns. With regard to commodity futures, Schwartz (1997) derived analytical expressions that describe the volatilities implied by the two- and three-factor model, which, in the limiting caseFootnote 11, converge to:

$$\begin{aligned} \sigma _{M_2}^2 = \sigma _x^2 + \frac{\sigma _{\delta }^2}{\kappa _{\delta }^2} - \frac{2\rho _{x,\delta }\sigma _x \sigma _\delta }{\kappa _\delta }, \end{aligned}$$
(19)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \sigma _{M_3}^2 = \sigma _x^2 + \frac{\sigma _{\delta }^2}{\kappa _{\delta }^2} + \frac{\sigma _{r}^2}{\kappa _{r}^2} - \frac{2\rho _{x,\delta }\sigma _x \sigma _\delta }{\kappa _\delta } + \frac{2\rho _{x,r}\sigma _x \sigma _r}{\kappa _r} - \frac{2\rho _{r,\delta }\sigma _\delta \sigma _r}{\kappa _\delta \kappa _r}. \end{aligned}$$
(20)

Even though (19) and (20) describe the volatility of futures returns in the two- and three-factor model, respectively, so consider commodity futures contracts rather than a natural resource investment with flexibility, it may be reasonable to assume that the overall volatility of the copper mine investment with the options portfolio could be represented by a similar functional relationship in terms of the two models’ parameters involved. In fact, since these expressions were obtained by Schwartz (1997) from the solution to the PDEs that must be satisfied by futures prices in the respective model, the concept of contingent claims analysis (Cortazar and Schwartz 1994) suggests that if the contingent claim is an investment project—in our case the copper mine—instead of a futures contract with linear payoff, then term structure of the volatility may be obtained, in theory, by expanding the valuation model’s PDE(s) accordingly. In this sense, it can be expected that, in the two-factor setting, (19) reflects the investment’s actual overall volatility more accurately than (20) does in the three-factor setting, because in the former \(\delta _t\) affects the valuation only indirectly through \(X_t\), whereas when using the more complex three-factor model \(r_t\) has both indirect (via \(X_t\)) and direct (as a discount factor) effects on the valuation.

To numerically analyse the effects of the multi-factor models’ parameters on the mine value, we perform an equivalence analysis of the three stochastic models. In doing so, we investigate the influence of parameters of the convenience yield (\(\sigma _\delta \), \(\kappa _\delta \), \(\rho _{x,\delta }\) and \(\rho _{r,\delta }\)) and interest rate process (\(\sigma _r\), \(\kappa _r\), and \(\rho _{x,r}\))—described by (17) and (18), respectively—on the implied volatilities of (19)-(20). In fact, we can eliminate the contribution of the convenience yield process to \(\sigma _{M_2}^2\) of (19) as well as the contributions of both the convenience yield and interest rate process to \(\sigma _{M_3}^2\) of (20) by determining, e.g., the values of \(\rho _{x,\delta }\) at which both \(\sigma _{M_2}^2\) and \(\sigma _{M_3}^2\) equal \(\sigma _x^2\). In other words, we can determine the respective \(\rho _{x,\delta }\)-values such that the sum of the 2nd and 3rd term of the right side of (19) becomes zero, and such that the sum of the 2nd to 6th term of the right side of (20) becomes zero, thereby having \(\sigma _{M_2}^2 = \sigma _{x}^2\) and \(\sigma _{M_3}^2 = \sigma _{x}^2\). Analytical expressions for these values of the correlation coefficient \(\rho _{x,\delta }\), which we refer to as equivalence correlations, are given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \rho _{x,\delta }^* = \frac{\sigma _{\delta }}{2 \kappa _{\delta } \sigma _x}, \end{aligned}$$
(21)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \rho _{x,\delta }^* = \frac{\sigma _{\delta }}{2 \kappa _{\delta } \sigma _x} + \frac{\sigma _r}{\kappa _r} \bigg [ \frac{\sigma _r \kappa _\delta }{2 \kappa _r \sigma _\delta \sigma _x} + \frac{\rho _{x,r} \kappa _\delta }{\sigma _\delta } - \frac{\rho _{r,\delta }}{\sigma _x} \bigg ]. \end{aligned}$$
(22)

Hence, when \(\rho _{x,\delta }\) equals the respective \(\rho _{x,\delta }^*\) then the volatilities in the multi-factor models equal the copper price variance, \(\sigma _x^2\), of the one-factor model of Brennan and Schwartz (1985), in which only the copper spot price is stochastic. The mine values from Brennan and Schwartz (1985) are therefore used as benchmark in our equivalence analysis.

Table 5 Parameters of convenience yield process for different specifications of Tsekrekos et al. (2012)

4.4 Valuation

For the valuation of this extended mine example, we used the parameter values presented in Sect. 2.4 for the copper mine and, to ensure comparability, of Tsekrekos et al. (2012) for the two multi-factor models. For the sake of our numerical analysis, yet without loss of generality, we focus on the three combinations of parameters of the convenience yield process shown in Table 5. These three specifications correspond with the 1st, 11th, and 21st specification of Tables 3, 4, 5 and 6 of Tsekrekos et al. (2012) and are the most relevant specifications used by the authors. This choice is sufficient for our analysis, more specifically, for studying the effects of different parameters of the two models on the investment value. Additional parameters used for the three-factor model are: \(\kappa _r=0.50\), \(\theta _r=r_0=0.10\), \(\sigma _r=0.015\), \(\rho _{r,\delta }=0.10\) and \(\rho _{x,r}=0.15\). Also, as Tsekrekos et al. (2012), we considered \(X_0=0.70\), 100,000 paths (half of which antithetic) and the complete set of polynomials in the parametric model, but, unlike the authors, we used generalised Chebyshev polynomials (with \(L=5\), which implies 56 basis functions).

To evaluate this extension, we adapted the backward procedure of “Appendix A” (now \(k_t=r_t+\lambda _1\)) and changed the second step of the forward pass to: use (18), (17) and (16) to sample \(\vert \varOmega \vert \) paths of \(r_t\), \(\delta _t\) and \(X_t\), respectively, giving \(\big (X_t(\omega ),\delta _t(\omega ),r_t(\omega )\big )_{\omega \in \varOmega }, \forall t \in {\mathcal {T}}\). Figure 6 gives an illustration of sample paths.

Table 6 Value of opened mine, \(\bar{G_0}(S_0)\) (in US$ millions), under the two- and three-factor model for the three specifications of Table 5 according to different numerical methods

5 Results and discussion: two- and three-factor model extensions

This section begins with an analysis of the way in which the value of the mine is affected by the different dynamics of the two multi-factor models. Table 6 summarises the results under both the two-factor model of Gibson and Schwartz (1990)—described by (16)-(17) with \(r_t=r_0\, \forall t \in {\mathcal {T}}\)—and the three-factor model of Schwartz (1997) given by (16)-(18), whilst considering the three specifications of Table 5 and three different values of the correlation between the copper price and convenience yield process, \(\rho _{x,\delta }\). In addition, Table 6 reports the corresponding results of Tsekrekos et al. (2012), who used the LSM approach. Comparing their results with ours shows that results are noticeably different. Not only (i) are our mine values consistently lower than theirs, they also (ii) exhibit the opposite behaviour with respect to changes in \(\rho _{x,\delta }\). Indeed, our mine values decrease in \(\rho _{x,\delta }\), whereas Tsekrekos et al. (2012) found values to be increasing in \(\rho _{x,\delta }\):

For the given set of parameters for the short-rate process, project values are found to be increasing [...] in the correlation between spot price and convenience yield changes, [...] much like in Section 3 where interest rates were assumed constant. (Tsekrekos et al. 2012)

Fig. 3
figure 3

Value of opened mine, \(\bar{G_0}(S_0)\) (in US$ millions), and volatility in two-factor model (\(\sigma _{M_2}^2\), left) and in three-factor model (\(\sigma _{M_3}^2\), right) as a function of correlation between copper price and convenience yield process (\(\rho _{x,\delta }\))

With regard to (ii), it should be noted that the value of a real options portfolio can be affected positively or negatively by correlation between the underlying stochastic factors (Brosch 2008). From (19) and (20) we can observe that the correlation coefficient \(\rho _{x,\delta }\) negatively affects the volatility in both the two- (\(\sigma _{M_2}^2\)) and three-factor model (\(\sigma _{M_3}^2\)). As such, an increase in \(\rho _{x,\delta }\) generally results in a decrease of the value of the mine as overall volatility in the underlying decreases. This is, however, in contrast to what has been found by Tsekrekos et al. (2012). Intuitively, we would expect such a negative relationship considering the way in which \(\delta _t\) of (17) is nested in the dynamics of \(X_t\) in (16). For non-negative \(\rho _{x,\delta }\) (Schwartz 1997), Fig. 3 plots the value of an opened mine (\(\bar{G_0}(S_0)\)) and the volatilities implied by both the two- and three-factor model as a function of \(\rho _{x,\delta }\). It can be seen from these figures that the implied volatilities \(\sigma _{M_2}^2\) and \(\sigma _{M_3}^2\) and, hence, \(\bar{G_0}(S_0)\) decrease as \(\rho _{x,\delta }\) increases, for the three specifications under consideration. While the implied volatilities decrease linearly in \(\rho _{x,\delta }\), as evident from (19)-(20), \(\bar{G_0}(S_0)\) is a nonlinear function of \(\rho _{x,\delta }\) and it is apparent that the decline in mine value, \(\frac{\partial \bar{G_0}(S_0) }{ \partial \rho _{x,\delta }}\), is larger—i.e. more negative—for lower (higher) values of \(\rho _{x,\delta }\) (\(\sigma _{M_2}^2\) and \(\sigma _{M_3}^2\)). This is consistent with the results reported in Fig. 7a and the nonlinear relationshipFootnote 12 is in line with Schwartz (1997):

When the option element of the investment is considered, the values obtained under the different models will be nonlinear functions of the spot price (and also of the other factors in the particular model). (Schwartz 1997)

Table 7 Results of equivalence analysis for both the two- and three-factor model with the three specifications of Table 5

To address (i) and verify the vertical position of the \(\bar{G_0}(S_0)\)-curves in Fig. 3, we preformed an equivalence analysis. The results are shown by Table 7 and are also included in Fig. 3. It can be observed in Table 7 that the values of the opened mine, \(\bar{G_0}(S_0)\), under the two-factor model converge very closely to the benchmark mine value, \({\hat{G}}_0(S_0)\), for all three specifications under consideration. Even though mine values under the three-factor model are marginally below the one-factor benchmark values, these results are in line with the previously mentioned (and to be expected) differences in quality of the implied volatilities as proxy measures of the mine project’s actual overall volatility. This is due to the higher complexity of the three- over the two-factor model as well as other influencing factors related to both the numerical procedure applied here and non-linearities in parameters such as \(X_0\), \(\delta _0\) and \(r_0\) (e.g., see Fig. 7a).

According to the above analysis, consistent with option pricing theory, the value of the copper mine decreases in the correlation coefficient \(\rho _{x,\delta }\) as a consequence of the decrease in overall volatility. Tsekrekos et al. (2012) also claimed that “values under a stochastic mean-reverting convenience yield will be higher than those under a constant convenience yield assumption”. However, it is misleading to suggest that this is always the case. Our equivalence analysis, as indicated in Fig. 3, demonstrates that for \(\rho _{x,\delta }\)-values below the equivalence correlation (\(0 \le \rho _{x,\delta } < \rho _{x,\delta }^*\)), \(\bar{G_0}(S_0)\)-values under both models are indeed higher than the benchmark mine value under the one-factor model, \({\hat{G}}_0(S_0)\), which assumes a constant convenience yield. At \(\rho _{x,\delta }=\rho _{x,\delta }^*\), we approximately have \({\bar{G}}_0(S_0)={\hat{G}}_0(S_0)\). However, for \(\rho _{x,\delta }^* < \rho _{x,\delta } \le 1\), mine values \({\bar{G}}_0(S_0)\) are lower than \({\hat{G}}_0(S_0)\) and, as \(\rho _{x,\delta }\) approaches 1, these are even considerably lower than the constant one-factor benchmark value, which was obtained in a constant convenience yield setting and is therefore independent of \(\rho _{x,\delta }\).

With regard to the three-factor model, Tsekrekos et al. (2012) have also analysed how variations in both the standard deviation of changes in the interest rate (\(\sigma _r\)) and the correlation between the interest rate and convenience yield process (\(\rho _{r,\delta }\)) affect the value of the opened mine. The authors statedFootnote 13:

Moreover, [...] Figure 3 demonstrates that the value of the investment is increasing in the volatility of the short rate and its correlation with convenience yield changes, since higher variability in expected project cash flows makes the flexibility to alter the operating mode of the project more valuable. (Tsekrekos et al. 2012)

Fig. 4
figure 4

Volatility in three-factor model (\(\sigma _{M_3}^2\)) and value of opened mine, \(\bar{G_0}(S_0)\) (in US$ millions), as a function of both the standard deviation of the interest rate (\(\sigma _r\)) and the correlation between the interest rate and convenience yield process (\(\rho _{r,\delta }\)), with \(\theta _\delta =0.15\)

We also performed this analysis and report results for \(\theta _\delta \) equalling 0.15 and 0.12 in Figs. 4 and 8, respectively. The figures on the left- and right-hand sides show \(\sigma _{M_3}^2\)-values and \(\bar{G_0}(S_0)\)-values, respectively. Since the authors’ choice of value for \(\kappa _\delta \) is not given, rather than choosing only one \(\kappa _\delta \)-value, as in Tsekrekos et al. (2012), we ran our valuation algorithm for all three possible \(\kappa _\delta \)-values of 0.30, 0.50 and 0.80, with results shown in Figures 4a–c, respectively. Of these, it appears that our results for \(\kappa _\delta =0.80\) are qualitatively most similar to those of Tsekrekos et al. (2012). It is evident that the mine value surfaces obtained here are in exceptionally good agreement with the volatility surfaces implied by the three-factor model. For \(\sigma _r=0\), \(\bar{G_0}(S_0)\)-values are constant because \(\sigma _{M_3}^2\) is, as evident from (20), independent of \(\rho _{r,\delta }\). For \(\sigma _r>0\), as is apparent from Panel (a) of their figure, we also find mine values to be decreasing in \(\rho _{r,\delta }\).

In contrast to Tsekrekos et al. (2012), however, our results demonstrate that the mine value is not always increasing in the volatility of the interest rate process. As we can see from Figs. 4a and 4b, which consider \(\kappa _\delta \)=0.30 and \(\kappa _\delta \)=0.50, respectively, \(\bar{G_0}(S_0)\)-values are increasing in \(\sigma _r\) for low values of \(\rho _{r,\delta }\), yet decreasing for relatively high \(\rho _{r,\delta }\)-values. Interestingly, we observe from Fig. 4c (\(\kappa _\delta \)=0.80) that while \(\bar{G_0}(S_0)\)-values increase in \(\sigma _r\) for the four lowest \(\rho _{r,\delta }\)-values under consideration, there is a twofold effect of the degree of \(\sigma _r\) on the investment value for \(0.4 \le \rho _{r,\delta } \le 0.8\): \(\bar{G_0}(S_0)\)-values actually decrease in \(\sigma _r\) for low \(\sigma _r\)-values, but increase in \(\sigma _r\) for high \(\sigma _r\)-values; this change from decrease to increase seems to occur at higher \(\sigma _r\)-values the higher the value of the correlation coefficient \(\rho _{r,\delta }\). The evidence provided by our analysis, particularly the volatility surface of Fig. 4c, seems to confirm that the nonlinear dependency of \(\sigma _{M_3}^2\) on \(\sigma _r\) is the cause of this non-monotonic effect. It can be inferred therefore that the implied volatilities can be used as a proxy measure to accurately describe how the mine value will be affected by changes in the complex multi-factor models’ parameters.

6 Discussion and conclusions

In this work, we have re-evaluated a well-known natural resource investment under three different commodity price models using the IDSR approach. Despite having many advantages as a framework to represent sequential decision problems, IDs have rarely been used in the context of ROA. A reason for this might be, as Wallace (2010) suggests, that real option analysts, like their financial counterparts, are generally interested in determining the value of single well-defined options (possibly compound but still predefined), rather than identifying and defining the portfolio of options. This focus on valuing single options is perhaps derived from financial option theory, which addresses decision making problems in which the representation of the investment proposition requires less sophistication than when considering complex physical assets. However, realistic and practical real option problems are generally more complex, so their analysis benefits from the more sophisticated representation of their underlying decision problems that can be addressed via IDs. Indeed, unlike the intuitively unappealing modelling based on PDEs (Brandão et al. 2005a), the flexibilities available to decision makers in alternative option portfolio configurations can be simply and intuitively represented by an ID, as demonstrated in Figs. 1 and 2.

In order to approximate the value of the portfolio of interdependent real options embedded in the copper mine project, we applied simulation in combination with regression. In contrast, the mathematically more complex valuation approach of Brennan and Schwartz (1985) used PDE-based modelling to describe the value of the mine and then applied a finite difference technique to approximately solve their valuation problem. As shown in Sect. 3, however, there are technical issues at the portfolio decomposition stage in their illustrative example, and given that the inaccuracy was in this relatively simple example, this suggests that the approach is not a good basis for the analysis of real option portfolios. By contrast, the IDSR approach, which can be easily implementedFootnote 14 and efficiently applied (e.g. parallel computing), is capable of correctly evaluating both the mine with the options portfolio and its individual real options through simply adapting the optimisation problem’s feasible region. Our portfolio analysis showed that the value of the fixed-output-rate mine of Brennan and Schwartz (1985) is incorrect and that this mine appears to include an abandonment option. As a result, the value of their closure option represents the value of mothballing within the portfolio rather than the closure option in isolation.

A controversial issue in the real options community is whether to apply option pricing or decision analysis approaches. Adequately evaluating natural resource investments under uncertainty requires the proper modelling of the embedded sequential stochastic decision problem. Only then is it possible to devise and apply adequate and powerful algorithmic strategies for the valuation of complex and risky investments. We agree with Wallace (2010) in that option pricing theory has traditionally tended to focus on valuation, whilst neglecting the modelling of the underlying sequential decision problem, whereas decision analysis and the related tools generally have the decision context as a starting point. An example of this can be found in Christiansen and Wallace (1998), who compared a decision analysis (decision tree solved via dynamic programming) and an option pricing approach (valuation by arbitrage via a replication argument) using a simple example, and showed that although both approaches deliver the same result, they are methodologically different, with the latter focusing on determining the optimal value whilst delivering the optimal decisions as a consequence, and vice versa.

So are option pricing and decision analysis approaches just two sides of the same coin? This question not only highlights one of the more contentious debates in the field of ROA, but also implies that the approach taken here of integrating PDE-based analytical expressions into our simulation-and-regression-based numerical analysis may well be a more promising approach. While the LSM approach has inherent limitations when it comes to valuing complex real option portfolios (Smith 2005; Brandão et al. 2005a; Maier et al. 2020), it has been successfully extended to such simple switching problems as the one-factor benchmark mine. We therefore believe the issues found in the two multi-factor extensions of Tsekrekos et al. (2012) are related to the simulation steps, most likely to the correlation matrix used for sampling correlated paths; the fact that the exact source of the error is undetecable is a criticism of “black box” simulation-based approaches (Brandão et al. 2005a; Lambrecht 2017).Footnote 15 To validate the values obtained in our re-evaluation, we use a key insight from options theory: higher underlying volatility generally means higher investment value. As a proxy measure of the investment’s actual overall volatility, we use PDE-based analytical expressions that describe the volatilities implied by the multi-factor models. This enabled us to validate in a transparent and intuitive way our results, and to provide important insights into the investment-uncertainty relationship.

To conclude this discussion, we believe our re-evaluation of natural resource investments under uncertainty directly addresses a number of open and important research questions in the field of ROA. While there is certainly no “magic bullet” (Smith 2005) for evaluating complex option problems, this study revisits highly influential works in the field and demonstrates an alternative way to solve real-life problems that can provide new insights. Traditional option pricing approaches based on PDE modelling and finite difference approximations—such as the approach introduced in Brennan and Schwartz (1985), which remains as a cornerstone of the real options literature—are known to become impractical in multi-factor situations, but our study also casts doubt on their practicality and reliability in portfolio situations, i.e. when there are multiple, possibly interdependent real options. Indeed, based on our numerical analyses and the above discussions, we believe the limitations of PDE-based approaches owing to (mathematical) complexity and lack of intuition (Glasserman 2003; Brandão et al. 2005b) probably invalidate their use in real option portfolio applications. At the same time, however, analytical expressions obtained by PDE modelling—such as those describing the volatilities implied by multi-factor models—can contribute to validating simulation-based, numerical analyses of complex problems. As demonstrated, the integration of such expressions into our IDSR-based numerical analysis provides important benefits including transparency and intuition, thereby addressing the key challenge (Brandão et al. 2005a; Lambrecht 2017) of simulation-based valuation approaches.