1 Introduction

The cornerstone concept of performance and the “corporate objective” in the traditional theory of the firm is shareholder wealth maximization.Footnote 1 For example, the corporate agency conflict literature,Footnote 2 sparked by the seminal paper of Jensen and Meckling (1976), has focused for the most part on some form of wealth creation, such as stock returns or Tobin’s Q, and has ignored how stock returns or the changes in Tobin’s Q are distributed.Footnote 3 Modern investment theory, however, has shown the importance of the distribution of wealth outcomes as well as the level of wealth itself.Footnote 4 Although the literatures on corporate finance and modern investment theory are both based on the principle of utility maximization (see, for example, Ross 1973; Jensen and Meckling 1976), heterogenous and unknown shareholder utility functions make it difficult to define a firm goal common to all shareholders based on maximum utility. In other words, all unsatiated, risk averse shareholders prefer more to less, but their attitudes to volatility, skewness, kurtosis, etc. can vary according to each individual utility function, thereby isolating wealth maximization as the only obvious preference common to all investors. The Fisher Separation Theorem shows that in a short run, partial equilibrium framework where no risk exists or where it can be perfectly hedged, return distributions can be excluded from the analysis and that wealth maximization is the common firm goal that also maximizes shareholder utility.Footnote 5

Excluding return distributions from the analysis overcomes the problem of heterogenous shareholders with different and unknown utility functions, but it comes at the cost of ignoring crucial information affecting shareholder preferences and investment decision making, which is at the heart of utility theory and modern portfolio analysis. Consider, for example, two firms with the same mean returns and the same volatility but firm A has positive skewness and low kurtosis while firm B has negative skewness and high kurtosis. Since it is well known that investors show a preference for positive skewness and an aversion to kurtosis (see, Kraus and Litzenberger 1976; Athayde and Flôres 2000; Fang and Lai 1997; Dittmar 2002; Post et al. 2008), other things being equal, investment A would be preferred to investment B by any risk averse investor.

This paper seeks to fill this void by developing a measure of firm performance compatible with the preferences of all risk averse shareholders that incorporates all the moments of the distribution—including the mean, the variance, the skewness and the kurtosis as well as all the higher moments. The total performance measure (TPM) we propose reflects the relative performance of the firm with respect to the market portfolio ranked by the marginal utilities of all risk averse shareholders. By including shareholder preferences towards risk in the measure of firm performance, we bring together the corporate finance literature and the literature on portfolio investment theory and practice. We argue that TPM contains a different set of information that can be useful in understanding the complicated relationships between decision making and firm performance. Our approach is very general. We make no assumptions about the return distributions, the specific form of the utility functions or the efficiency of the market portfolio. The only assumptions are that investors are risk averse and hold their wealth in the market portfolio.

The empirical testing involves two stages. First, we show that TPM does reflect the individual moments of the return distribution. We then use TPM to study the effect of managerial ownership (MO) on firm performance, the well-known manager/shareholder agency conflict has been a major issue in economics and management science for over 70 years. We show that there is a significant quartic relationship between firm performance measured as TPM and MO, a relationship with a straightforward interpretation for the risk averse shareholder’s utility over each interval. When we examine the relationship between MO and other measures of firm performance, such as returns, return volatility, skewness and kurtosis, the effects on whether or not they enhance the risk averse shareholder’s utility are often conflicting. This is evidence that the individual moments provide only a partial and potentially misleading picture of overall stock performance that is difficult to interpret when standing alone. It is also evidence that the more comprehensive TPM provides additional insights into firm performance. We pursue this proposition and show that after orthogonalizing TPM with respect to Tobin’s Q, another common measure of firm performance, TPM retains a significant amount of performance information. These results are robust to controls for endogeneity, institutional ownership, firm size, leverage, firm age, and auditing quality.

This paper extends the previous literature by adding a basic but versatile measure of firm performance to the corporate finance empirical literature that goes beyond wealth to include the distribution of wealth outcomes as well. As such, it refines the corporate objective to reflect utility maximization and brings together the portfolio investment and corporate finance literature.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. The next section develops the framework and methodology for constructing TPM. Section 3 analyzes TPM in the framework of the manager/shareholder agency conflict. Section 4 compares the information content of TPM with other popular performance measures, such as Tobin’s Q and the raw moments of the return distribution. Section 5 concludes.

2 Total firm performance: framework and methodology

To construct the utility based proxy for firm performance, noted as TPM, we proceed as follows. We assume that shareholder wealth is represented by the market portfolio and that shareholders are rational, non-satiating and risk averse. Each investor has a utility function \( u(r) \) satisfying the following conditions:

$$ u^{{\prime }} (r) \ge 0,\quad \, u^{{\prime \prime }} (r) \le 0 \, \quad \forall r $$
(1)

where primes denote derivatives and r is the rate of return of an investment. Let \( x_{i} \) represent the percent of asset i in the market portfolio, \( r_{M} = \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{n} {x_{i} r_{i} } \) represent the return on the market, and \( q_{i} = x_{i} (r_{i} - r_{M} ) \) represent the change in \( r_{M} \) due to asset i. The contribution to utility by asset i can be found by expanding \( u(r_{M} - q_{i} ) \) in a Taylor series around \( r_{M} \) and ignoring terms above the first derivative:

$$ u(r_{M} - q_{i} ) = u(r_{M} ) - q_{i} u^{{\prime }} (r_{M} ) $$
(2)

where \( q_{i} = x_{i} (r_{i} - r_{M} ) \). Rearranging gives:

$$ u(r_{M} ) = u(r_{M} - q_{i} ) + q_{i} u^{\prime}(r_{M} ) $$
(3)

Thus, asset i’s contribution to utility is equal to \( q_{i} u^{\prime}(r_{M} ) \) = \( x_{i} (r_{i} - r_{M} )u^{\prime}(r_{M} ) \). For a given value of \( q_{i} \) the contribution to total utility depends on \( r_{M} \). Since \( \, u^{\prime\prime}(r) \le 0 \, \), the contribution will be greater the lower the level of \( r_{M} \). For example, in Fig. 1 an increase in one unit of wealth from 3 to 4 on the x-axis increases utility on the y-axis by approximately 0.3, whereas an increase of one unit of wealth from 16 to 17 only increases it by about 0.1.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Graph of a risk averse utility function y = ln(x)

Because the marginal utilities of individual shareholders are different and unknown, we cannot estimate the utility of specific shareholders. To overcome this problem, we build on the condition of decreasing marginal utility and rank the states of nature according to the returns on the market portfolio from lowest to highest. Ranking in this way is equivalent to ranking by decreasing marginal utility for each shareholder because utility is defined over total wealth reflected in the market portfolio.Footnote 6 Thus, all risk averse shareholders, regardless of their individual utility functions and ownership in the company, must be in agreement with this ranking. Individual shareholders may not derive the same marginal utility from returns on the market portfolio, but they all agree on the ranking of the marginal utilities of these returns. From this it is clear that the ranking of the states of nature with respect to portfolio returns is the necessary and sufficient information to provide a ranking with respect to marginal utility. We can use this ranking to derive a measure of performance for each firm that reflects decreasing marginal utility.

We start by matching the returns on each firm with the ranked returns on the market portfolio. We then calculate \( (r_{i} - r_{M} ) \), the difference between the firm returns and the returns on the market portfolio, for each value of \( r_{M} \). These differences reflect the relative performance of each firm with respect to the market portfolio at each state of nature. The higher (lower) the difference, the better (worse) is the relative performance.

The partial performance measure we propose is based on the statistic developed by Chow (2001) calculated as the average excess return, \( E(r_{i} - r_{M} ) \), divided by its standard deviation. This test is designed to reflect the effect of decreasing marginal utility on performance. It follows a studentized maximum modulus distribution. The critical values are available in Stoline and Ury (1979). It has been used primarily in studies based on marginal conditional stochastic dominance (e.g. Clark et al. 2011; Belghitar et al. (2011); Clark and Kassimatis 2013). Its construction involves dividing the vector of relative performance for each firm into deciles.Footnote 7 We use the deciles to form subsamples of the data that we use to construct partial performance measures for each firm. The first subsample is comprised of return differences obtained from the first decile of the ranking. The second subsample is comprised of return differences obtained from the first and second deciles of the ranking. The third subsample is comprised of return differences obtained from the first, second and third deciles and so on, until the whole distribution is included in the final subsample. This can be written formally as:

$$ Z^{k} (\tau_{i} ) = \frac{{\overline{\Phi }^{k} (\tau_{i} )}}{{\hat{S}^{k} (\tau_{i} )}},\quad {\text{for}}\quad {\text{i }} = \, 1, \ldots ,{\text{ m}}. $$
(4)

where

$$ \bar{\Phi }^{k} (\tau_{i} ) = \overline{{r_{pk} I(\tau_{i} )}} - \overline{{r_{M} I(\tau_{i} )}} ,\quad {\text{ i}} = 1,2, \ldots ,{\text{m}}\,{\text{and}}\,{\text{k}} = 1,2, \ldots ,{\text{K}}, $$
(5)

and \( \overline{\Phi }^{k} (\tau_{i} ) \) is the mean excess conditional return of stock k relative to the market portfolio below a target rate of return \( \tau \). The index i denotes the set of prespecified target rates of return. \( \hat{S}^{k} (\tau_{i} ) \) is the estimated standard error of \( \overline{\Phi }^{k} (\tau_{i} ) \) and \( I(\tau_{i} ) \) is an indicator variable such that \( I(\tau_{i} ) \) = 1 if rM τ and 0 otherwise.Footnote 8 Using deciles, (i.e. i = 1,…, 10), gives 10 individual Z statistics as partial performance measures.

It is important to note that we make no assumptions about any of the return distributions, such that each partial performance measure reflects the complete empirical distribution of a firm’s returns compared to the return on the market over each subsample. Since it is measured over the entire empirical distribution of each subsample, it will also reflect all the moments of the distribution of the subsamples, including the third, fourth and higher moments. TPM is calculated as the average of these ten partial performance measures. It reflects the attribute of decreasing marginal utility by giving more weight to the outcomes at the lower states of nature. For example, the outcomes of the first decile count for approximately 28.5% of TPM, the outcomes of the second decile for approximately 19.5%, etc.

As an example of how TPM is calculated, consider a period of 50 working days, which gives 50 daily returns for the market portfolio (M) and stock i. First, market returns are ranked from lowest to highest and matched with the corresponding returns of stock i so that the return on stock i is conditional on the return on the market portfolio. The sample is then split into deciles, each consisting of 5 pairs. Columns 2 and 3 in Table 1 report the 15 lowest hypothetical returns for the market portfolio and the corresponding returns for stock i. For example, the 3rd lowest return of the market portfolio during the 50 day period was − 7.2%. On that day the return of stock i was − 7%. The third step is to calculate the difference for each pair of returns, which is reported in the 4th column of the table. Next, we calculate the average difference in returns for the first 5 observations, the first 10 observations, the first 15 observations, and so on, until we include the entire sample. Finally, we calculate the standard deviation of the differences in returns [St.Dev.(Ri − RM)] reported in column 5. The Z statistic is calculated as the average difference in returns divided by the standard deviation of these differences for each sub-sample. In the hypothetical example, the TPM statistic is the equally weighted average of the ten Z statistics for the 50 day period. In the analysis that follows, TPM is calculated on an annual basis, employing daily returns over each calendar year.

Table 1 Steps in the calculation of TPM

By design, TPM should reflect the range of shareholder preferences embedded in the return distributions. To test this proposition we use a sample that includes all listed non financial firms on three US exchanges—New York Stock Exchange (NYSE), American Stock Exchange (AMEX), and Nasdaq—for the period 2002–2010. The market portfolio is proxied by the S&P 500. We then regress TPM on the first four moments of the return distributions with respect to the market portfolio, i.e. excess returns (ERET), covariance (COV), coskewness (COSK) and cokurtosis (COKU). In this way we control for market based effects while respecting that TPM is measured against the market portfolio. Thus, we offer the following specification, where the coefficients’ standard errors are adjusted for the effects of non-independence by clustering on each firm:

$$ TPM_{it} = \kappa_{0} + \kappa_{1} ERET_{it} + \kappa_{2} COV_{it} + \kappa_{3} COSK_{it} + \kappa_{4} COKU_{it} + \varepsilon_{it} $$
(6)

where ERET, COV, COSK and COKU are the explanatory variables defined above, the \( \kappa 's_{{}} \) are estimated coefficients and \( \varepsilon_{t} \) is the error term.

Table 2 reports the results. The adjusted \( R_{{}}^{2} \) is over 50% in both specifications, the four explanatory variables are highly significant in both specifications and have the right signs for risk averse investors with decreasing absolute risk aversion. Average excess returns and coskewness have a positive coefficient while covariance and cokurtosis have a negative coefficient. This is strong evidence that TPM reflects the individual moments of the return distribution and that it is compatible with utility maximization for risk averse investors, which makes it a good proxy for firm performance.

Table 2 The relationship between TPM and Excess returns

3 Managerial ownership and firm performance

We now turn to the application of TPM to an important problem in the corporate finance literature, the effect of managerial ownership (MO) on firm performance. The effect of managerial ownership on the manager/shareholder agency conflict has been a major issue in economics and management science for over seventy years.Footnote 9 The conflict, which arises when corporate ownership is separate from corporate control and the interests of managers and shareholders diverge, can result in opportunistic behavior by managers that is incompatible with their mandate to act in the best interest of shareholders.Footnote 10 The seminal paper of Jensen and Meckling (1976) argued that this “agency conflict” can be mitigated through managerial compensation that aligns the interests of managers and shareholders.Footnote 11

The initial thrust of the literature that analyzes the effect of managerial ownership on firm performance was that greater managerial ownership benefits shareholders because it increases managers’ incentives to accept riskier, more profitable projects that increase firm value (e.g. Jensen and Meckling 1976; Morck et al. 1988; Stulz 1988; Tosi et al. 1997).Footnote 12 Other studies pointed out, however, that if managers own a substantial percentage of a firm’s shares, they may try to entrench themselves in the company they manageFootnote 13 by over-investing (empire building)Footnote 14 and accepting negative present value projects that reduce corporate wealth (e.g. Demsetz 1983; and Fama and Jensen 1983).Footnote 15 Another strand of the literature focuses on the principle of diversification. Acharya and Bisin (2009) argue that managers are restricted in trading the stock of the firm they manage and, thus, they cannot diversify their firm specific risk through the financial markets. However, they are not restricted in trading other securities so they may favor projects with greater market risk, but which is diversifiable and can be hedged in the financial markets using instruments such as stock indices. The higher market risk increases the firm’s cost of capital and reduces the firm’s market value. Thus, because of under-diversification, higher levels of managerial ownership decrease firm value and increase the misalignment between managerial and shareholder interests.Footnote 16

In the traditional theory of the firm, the empirical literature has focused for the most part on some form of wealth creation, such as stock returns or Tobin’s Q, and has ignored how stock returns or the changes in Tobin’s Q are distributed. For example, Kirchmaier and Grant (2005), Zhang (2009) and Von Lilienfeld-Toal and Ruenzi (2014) have used stock returns as a performance proxy. Another important strand of this literature uses Tobin’s Q to test for non-linearity. McConnell and Servaes (1990) find quadratic non-linearity while De Miguel et al. (2004) find quadratic and cubic non-linearity; Morck et al. (1988), Short and Keasey (1999), Faccio and Lasfer (1999) and Holderness, Kroszner, and Sheehan (1999) (for their 1935 sample) find cubic non-linearity; Hermalin and Weisbach (1991) find quartic non-linearity and Davies et al. (2005) find the non-linearity is quintic.

The overall thrust of the empirical literature suggests that there is a significant, non-linear relationship between firm value and managerial ownership, but besides Gadhoum and Ayadi (2003), who examine how ownership structure affects the volatility of Canadian companies and identify a non-linear positive relationship between volatility and managerial ownership, and Chen and Steiner (1999), who find a similar relationship for U.S. companies, there has been little or no research on how MO affects the distribution of wealth outcomes.

Using TPM as a performance measure provides some interesting insights into the foregoing discussion. It furnishes evidence that firm performance does change as a result of a change in investment strategy due to incentives embedded in different levels of MO and that this change includes changes in shareholder returns as well as how these returns are distributed. It also shows that overall performance that reflects all the moments of wealth outcomes can differ sharply from the one dimensional performance measures considered in the literature.

3.1 Sample description

The sample includes the sample described above of all listed non financial firms on three US exchanges—New York Stock Exchange (NYSE), American Stock Exchange (AMEX), and Nasdaq—for the period 2002–2010 with available data for the analysis. Specific firm data was obtained from Worldscope. Data on firm ownership structure was obtained from Thomson One Banker. Following Holderness et al. (1999), Helwege et al. (2007), and Fahlenbrach and Stulz (2009), managerial ownership, MO, is measured as the percentage of total shares held by firm executive directors.Footnote 17, Footnote 18 The market portfolio used to calculate TPM is proxied by the S&P 500.

We consider a number of control variables suggested in the empirical studies on the relationship between managerial ownership and stock performance. Given the dearth of theoretical analysis and empirical evidence relating the control variables to third and higher moments of the return distribution, we have no strong priors on the signs of the control variables with respect to any of the dependent variables. The first control variable is the size effect (SIZE), measured as the log of total assets (see, e.g. Florackis et al. 2009). The second control variable is financial distress, represented by leverage (LEV), measured as total debt to total assets. The third control variable is dividend yield (DIV), measured as total cash dividend to total assets. The fourth control variable is institutional ownership (INST), measured as the percentage of the total number of shares held by financial institutions. The fifth and sixth control variables are firm age (AGE), defined as the number of years since firm creation, suggested by Bennett et al. (2003), and auditing quality (AUD4) represented by a dummy variable that takes the value of one if the audit firm is from the Big 4 and zero otherwise. After excluding firms without the requisite ownership information and firm specifics, the final unbalanced sample consists of 2936 firms for the period 2002–2009. Table 3 reports correlations between our variables and Table 4 reports descriptive statistics for the data series.

Table 3 Correlation matrix
Table 4 Descriptive statistics

3.2 Empirical results

One important question to be addressed in the analysis is whether the empirical results are the interpretation of equilibrium or out-of-equilibrium phenomena. In equilibrium managerial ownership is likely to be endogenously determined (Demsetz and Lehn 1985; Demsetz and Villalonga 2001). According to Core et al. (2003), the interpretation depends largely on the magnitude of adjustment costs in correcting suboptimal contracts. For example, when the costs of ownership adjustments are high, managerial ownership will change only occasionally. Demsetz (1983) argues that firms are not able to re-contract because they are hindered by the large adjustment costs. This implies that the optimal managerial ownership rests on the firm’s contracting environment that may change over time (Cheung and Wei 2006).

To account for sub-optimal contracting, we examine the managerial-performance relation in a dynamic setting. The dynamic setting recognizes the possibility that firms adjust to their targeted managerial ownership levels gradually over time and sheds light on the dynamics of managerial ownership and its relationship to changes in firm performance.

We employ the following dynamic panel data specification:

$$ TPM_{it} = \, \gamma TPM_{it - 1} + \sum^{4}_{j = 1} \left( {\varsigma_{j} MO^{j}_{it} } \right) + \, \delta X_{it} + \, n_{i} + \, \lambda_{t} + \, \xi_{it} $$
(7)

where TPM is the dependent variable, the total performance measure, MO is managerial ownership, and X is a vector of control variables that include institutional ownership (INST), firm size (SIZE), leverage (LEV), dividends (DIV), and firm age (AGE). The parameter γ is a scalar, ς and δ are k-dimensional vectors of coefficients. The variables ni and λt are respectively unobserved firm fixed effects and time effects that capture the effects of unobserved firm heterogeneity and economy-wide factors that are outside the firm’s control. Similarly, the lagged dependent variable in Eq. (7) is allowed to be correlated with unobserved heterogeneity.

The problems of endogeneity outlined above suggest the use of an instrumental variables (IV) methodology to estimate Eq. (7), where the lagged dependent variable (TPMit−1) and endogenous regressors (MO) are instrumented. The preferred estimator for Eq. (7) is the Generalised Method of Moments (GMM) system estimator (Arellano and Bover 1995; Blundell and Bond 1998) because: (a) the panel consists of a small number of time periods (small T) and a large number of firms (large N); (b) the dependent variable (TPM) is dynamic, in the sense that it depends on past realizations;Footnote 19 (c) the GMM system explicitly allows for heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation within firms.

Following Arellano and Bover (1995), the dynamic performance model is estimated by the forward orthogonal deviations transform in order to purge the data of unobserved firm heterogeneity.Footnote 20 Thus, the GMM system estimator combines a set of orthogonal deviation equations with equations in levels, where instrumental variables are generated within the system. The consistency of the GMM estimates is subject to an optimal choice of instruments and the absence of higher-order serial correlation in the idiosyncratic error term, ξit.

To determine the order of non-linearity we employed a stepwise procedure starting with the quadratic. The squared variable was significant at the 5% level. We then added the cubed variable, which was significant at the 5% level without reducing the significance or changing the sign of the squared variable. When we added the variable raised to the 4th power it was significant without reducing the significance or changing the signs of the squared and cubed variables. The variable raised to the 5th power was not significant at any conventional level. Thus, we concluded that the quartic relationship was appropriate for our sample.

The results of the GMM system of tests are reported in Table 5. The Sargan test of over-identifying restrictions is not significant, indicating that the instruments used in the GMM estimation are not correlated with the error term (i.e. valid instruments). As expected, the AR(1) and AR(2) tests confirm the existence of serial correlation of order one, but not of order two. The results suggest that the dynamic nature of firm performance is not rejected. Specifically, the estimated coefficient of the previous year’s performance (TPMt−1) is positive and significant. The adjustment speed (which is given by 1 − γ) for model 1 is 0.575 and model 2 is 0.568. This gives, on average, an adjustment speed of 0.571. This is equivalent to a Koyck duration interval of 5.34 with p = 95%, where p is the percentage of the decay. This implies that it requires 5.34 years to complete a 95% adjustment, suggesting that adjustment costs are quite high.Footnote 21 This finding along with the instrumented MO is consistent with Demsetz’s (1983) argument which suggests that firms are not able to re-contract because they face substantial adjustment costs when they wish to adjust to the equilibrium level of managerial ownership, where the optimal level is not constant over time and moves with the changes in the determinants of firm performance.

Table 5 GMM system results for TPM

As indicated in Eq. (7), we test for the nonlinearity by including in the analysis the square root, the cube and the quartic of managerial ownership (MO2, MO3, MO4). Consistent with prior studies, all MO coefficients are statistically significant (model 1) suggesting that the relationship between TPM and MO is not linear. The quartic relationship suggests that there are four distinct managerial ownership intervals with three turning points. Given this evidence, in model 2 we consider a piecewise linear specification to test the relationship between TPM and MO over each interval. The turning points can be optimally derived by taking the first derivative of

$$ \varsigma_{4} MO_{{}}^{4} + \varsigma_{3} MO_{{}}^{3} + \varsigma_{2} MO_{{}}^{2} + \varsigma_{1} MO_{{}} $$
(8)

and setting it equal to zero. This gives

$$ 4\varsigma_{4} MO_{{}}^{3} + 3\varsigma_{3} MO_{{}}^{2} + 2\varsigma_{2} MO + \varsigma_{1} = 0 $$
(9)

Solving for MO gives turning points at 8.7, 32 and 57.2%

Since \( \varsigma_{1} = -\, 18.46 \), the interval between 0 and 8.7% is downward sloping and 8.7% is a local minimum. This result is evidence of the under-diversification theory of managerial misalignment with shareholder preferences. The most likely explanation for the negative relationship is that at low levels of ownership, increased ownership increases the costs associated with under-diversification more than the potential gains from the shareholder friendly projects that would improve TPM. These costs can also be exacerbated by issues such as restrictions on short sales, restrictions on trading during blackout periods, and required minimum levels of stock ownership.

With \( \varsigma_{2} = 151.0 \), the interval between 8.7 and 32% is upward sloping with a local maximum at 32%. This is strong evidence supporting managerial alignment. With the coefficient \( \varsigma_{3} = - 375.5 \) negative, the interval between 32 and 57.2% is negative with a local minimum at 57.2%. This result supports the argument for entrenchment and/or empire building. The coefficient \( \varsigma_{4} = 286.2 \) is positive, which means that the fourth interval is positive. This result supports the argument that at high levels of MO managerial and shareholder interests coincide.

The piecewise regression (Table 5, model 2) results support the conclusion derived from model 1. Over the interval 0–8.7%, MO has a negative, statistically significant effect at the 5% level on TPM. This is further evidence of misalignment. It has a positive, statistically significant (5% level) effect over the interval 8.7–32%, which is further evidence for alignment. Over the interval 32–57.2%, the effect is negative and statistically significant, but only at the 10% level. This is weak evidence for the entrenchment hypothesis. After 57.2% of managerial ownership, the relationship between MO and TPM seems to break down, probably because at this level of ownership the managers own so much of the company that their preferences coincide with those of the normal shareholder to the extent that there is nothing to be gained from further increases.

Overall, our results show that there is a statistically significant relationship between managerial ownership and our measure of firm performance. This relationship is non-linear, as suggested elsewhere in the literature based on other, less comprehensive measures of performance. We find that alignment occurs at ownership levels between 8.7 and 32% and above 57.2%. Between 32 and 57.2% we find evidence for misalignment and entrenchment. Interestingly and importantly, we find that at very low levels of MO (up to 8.7%) increasing managerial ownership actually exacerbates the agency conflict of manager/shareholder misalignment and reduces performance.

4 Analyzing and testing TPM’s information content

4.1 TPM versus the raw moments of the return distribution

In Sect. 2 we showed that TPM represents a broad measure of firm performance that is measured over the entire empirical distribution of shareholder returns and, thus, reflects returns to shareholders as well as how those returns are distributed. In the preceding section we documented a strong statistical, non-linear relationship between TPM and MO. In this section we study whether and how TPM contributes to understanding firm performance. We start by testing the relationship between MO and the first four moments of the distribution of the raw returns and analyzing their effect on shareholder utility. We then compare the results with those of TPM in Table 5. We show that MO significantly affects the individual moments of firm returns, but the effects on whether or not they enhance the risk averse shareholder’s utility are often conflicting.

Consider, for example, the results on the piecewise regressions reported in Table 6. In the first segment from 0 to 8.7%, returns, skewness and kurtosis decrease with MO, while volatility increases. Increased volatility and decreased returns and skewness are bad for risk averse investors, whereas decreased kurtosis is good. The trade-offs reflected in this conflicting information is resolved with TPM. The piecewise regressions Table 5 shows that the overall effect of MO from 0 to 8.7% on TPM is negative and significant. Over the second segment, the information does not conflict. Returns and skewness increase with MO, while volatility and kurtosis decrease, all of which is good for the risk averse investor, a result verified by the positive coefficient for TPM in Table 5 for the same segment. In the 3rd segment in Table 6, returns increase and volatility decreases, which is good for the risk averse investor, but skewness decreases and kurtosis increases, which is bad. Furthermore, none of the coefficients are significant. Based on returns alone or returns and volatility as the performance indicators, the conclusion would be no significant relationship or a weak positive one. Based on all four moments, no significant relationship would be forthcoming. Using TPM as the performance measure makes it possible to reconcile this conflicting information. In column 2 of Table 5 the coefficient of MO on TPM, which reflects the trade-offs of these four moments, is negative and statistically significant at the 10% level. In the fourth segment, all moments increase with MO and only the coefficient for volatility is statistically significant. Thus, there are two good effects (increased returns and skewness) and two bad ones (increased volatility and kurtosis). Taken together these results are difficult to interpret with respect to overall stock performance. The results for TPM in Table 5 show a negative coefficient that is not statistically different from zero at any reasonable level of significance, which is evidence that for MO above 57%, there is no overall relationship between stock performance and MO. The gist of this analysis is that examining the effect of MO on individual measures of stock performance provides a partial and potentially misleading picture of overall performance that can be resolved by using the more comprehensive TPM.

Table 6 GMM system results for piecewise moments

4.2 TPM versus Tobin’s Q

We now turn our attention to examining the relationship between TPM and Tobin’s Q vis-à-vis managerial ownership. TPM represents the performance proxy for expected utility in the investment literature. As outlined above, Tobin’s Q, defined as the ratio of the market value of assets to the book value of assets, where the market value of assets is measured as the book value of assets less the book value of equity plus the market value of equity, is often used in the corporate finance literature as the wealth variable to proxy for firm performance.

To explore the relationships among TPM, Tobin’s Q and MO, we begin by testing the relationship between TPM and Tobin’s Q in a regression of TPM on Tobin’s Q. We find a strong, significant relationship. Tobin’s Q is significant at the 1% level and the overall equation has an R2 of 17%.Footnote 22 The implication is that TPM reflects the performance information contained in Tobin’s Q. We then save the residuals from this regression and re-run the regressions of Table 5 with the saved residuals in place of TPM. The intuition behind this test is straightforward. The residuals, orthogonalized with respect to Tobin’s Q, contain all the information included in TPM after eliminating the effect of Tobin’s Q. The results of this regression measure the effect of MO on expected utility net of the Tobin’s Q wealth effect. If the effect of managerial ownership on firm performance is predominantly a wealth effect, then using TPM instead of Tobin’s Q for this type of analysis should offer no additional benefits. In this case we should find no relationship between the residuals and MO. The results are reported in Table 7. Clearly, there is a strong relationship between the residuals and MO. The magnitude of the coefficients is different to those reported in Table 5, which is expected because we removed the wealth effect from TPM. Besides that, the results reported in Tables 5 and 7 are identical. This is strong evidence that TPM provides additional insights into the effect of MO on firm performance.

Table 7 GMM system results for TPM information not included in Tobin’s q

5 Discussion and conclusion

In this paper we propose a methodology to address the problem of heterogenous and unknown shareholder utility functions that make it difficult to define a corporate objective common to all shareholders based on maximum utility. Using the concept of ranked marginal utility, we develop a multi-dimensional measure of firm performance that reflects the preferences of all risk averse shareholders towards all aspects of risk. We verify empirically that this is, in fact, the case for the first four moments of a large sample of US stocks over the period 2002–2010. When we use TPM in the manager/shareholder agency conflict, we show that it provides some novel insights. First of all, we verify that the non-linear relationship between managerial ownership and firm performance documented in the literature holds for TPM. We show that TPM reflects the trade-offs in utility caused by changes in the first four moments of the return distribution and that one dimensional performance measures, such as mean returns, volatility or Tobin’s Q can lead to erroneous inference. Importantly, we also show that after orthogonalizing with respect to Tobin’s Q, TPM contains significant information content on shareholder preferences. By including shareholder preferences towards risk in the measure of firm performance as the corporate objective, we bring together the corporate finance literature and the literature on portfolio investment theory and practice.