Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The tragedy of product homogeneity and knowledge non-spillovers: explaining the slow pace of energy technological progress

  • S.I.: Energy and Climate Policy Modeling
  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

There is a growing body of literature mentioning the slow progress of energy technological innovation as compared to information technology (IT), but the reasons why the energy sector is perplexed by slow innovation remain unexplained. Based on a variety-expanding endogenous technological change model, this paper investigates the economic mechanism that underlines the slow pace of energy technological progress. We show that in the market equilibrium the growth rate of energy technology variety is always lower than that of IT variety, this outcome stems from both the market fundamentals where the homogeneity of end-use energy goods is less likely to harness the pecuniary externality embedded in the love-for-variety household, and the technology fundamentals where capital-intensiveness of energy technology assets inhibits the non-pecuniary technological externality associated with knowledge spillovers. We further show that the social planner allocation can raise the rate of technological progress in both energy and IT sectors, but still fails to achieve an outcome in which technological progress in the energy sector can catch up with the IT sector. Finally, using efficiency-improving revenue-neutral policy interventions that subsidize energy sectors and tax IT sectors, the decentralized market equilibrium can achieve an outcome in which both energy and IT sectors have the same rate of technological progress.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The only exceptions are previous peak spending during the late 1970s due to the Arab Oil Embargo and year 2009 stimulus spending for recovery from economic recessions.

  2. This is except for year 2009 “green” stimulus spending, but “green” stimulus budgets are one-time increases in funds, and new commitments to energy R&D may be ending. Given that most of the IEA countries risk falling into a budget deficit, whether the sudden push for energy R&D expenditure is sustainable over the long term is uncertain (IEA 2010).

  3. In the early 1990s, when R&D intensity (R&D expenditure as a share of sales revenues) across all US industries averaged 3–4 intensity in energy industries is less than 1 %. More recently, the industry-wide average increased somewhat, to about 3.4 % of revenues, while the figure for energy sector R&D dropped to only 0.1 %.

  4. This is according to the US Patent and Trademark Office’s “Patent Bibliographic Database” (PTO 1998). The data on energy technology patents is generated from keyword searches that include: oil, natural gas, coal, photovoltaic, hydroelectric, hydropower, nuclear, geothermal, solar, wind.

  5. The reason for this treatment is that end-use energy goods (i.e. electric utility) have a substantial degree of homogeneity in terms of varieties and functions, while IT products are characterized by a substantial degree of heterogeneity in the sense that there exists a large variety of differentiated end-use IT product with new attributes and functions.

  6. As detailed later, the asset holdings consist of market values of firms (each has the technology to produce a differentiated variety of products) that are owned by the representative household, \(A(t)=\int _0^{N_E (t)} {V_E (i,t)} \cdot di+\int _0^{N_T (t)} {V_T (j,t)} \cdot dj\), where \(N_E (t),N_T (t)\) are the number of differentiated energy and IT technology variety, and \(V_E (i,t),V_T (j,t)\) are the market value of the firms owning each energy and IT technology variety.

  7. Intermediate production input means that the energy embodied in these primary energy resources is fully converted into the end-use, secondary energy products.

  8. To be specific, in addition to traditional fossil fuel-based energy technologies, energy sectors also involves a large number of differentiated varieties of primary energy technologies based on nuclear, hydropower, solar, wind, ocean wave, bioenergy, and geothermal etc. The variety-expanding model used here is closely related to and builds on the endogenous growth models, for example, Romer (1986, 1990); Smulders and de Nooij 2003), van Zon and Yetkiner (2003) and Acemoglu et al. (2012).

  9. This market-driven view that profit opportunities are the primary determinant of innovation is articulated in the seminal work of Schmookler (1962, 1966), arguing that innovation is largely an economic activity which, like other economic activities, is pursued for profit gains. The studies by Griliches (1957), and Griliches and Schmookler (1963) also provide empirical supports for the market-driven perspective that technological innovation is closely linked to the profitability in commercial markets. Similar conclusions are also reached in more recent studies, especially in the induced innovation literature. For example, Lichtenberg (1986), Jaffe and Palmer (1997), Newell et al. (1999), Goulder and Schneider (1999), Grubb et al. (2002), Popp (2002), and Acemoglu (2002).

  10. In the model, the social optimal level of using individual primary energy variety is given by \(x_E ^{S}(i,t)=(1-\varepsilon _E ^{-1})^{-\varepsilon _E }L\). In contrast, in the market equilibrium level of using each variety of primary energy input is given as \(x_E (i,t)=L\). Given \(\varepsilon _E >1\), \(x_E ^{S}(i,t)>x_E (i,t)\) holds.

  11. In the model, the structure of demand for individual IT product variety is the same between the social optimum and market equilibrium as given in (14).

  12. In the model, the socially optimal amount of workforce allocated to IT R&D is equal to \(L_{TR}^{S}(t)=L-(\varepsilon _T -1)\eta ^{-1}\rho \), as given in (65) in “Appendix 4”, and the market equilibrium amount of workforce allocated to IT R&D is equal to \(L_{TR} =\varepsilon _T ^{-1}\cdot [L-(\varepsilon _T -1)\eta ^{-1}\rho ]\), as given in (50) in “Appendix 2”.

References

  • Acemoglu, D. (2002). Directed technical change. Review of Economic Studies, 69, 781–809.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D. (2009). Introduction to modern economic growth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Aghion, P., Bursztyn, L., & Hemous, D. (2012). The environment and directed technical change. American Economic Review, 102(1), 131–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (1998). Endogenous Growth Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anadón, L. D. (2012). Missions-oriented RD&D institutions in energy between 2000 and 2010: A comparative analysis of china, the united kingdom, and the united states. Research Policy, 41(10), 1742–1756.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anadon, L., & Holdren, J. (2009). Policy for energy technology innovation. Chap. 5 in Acting in time on energy policy. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bakos, Y., & Brynjolfsson, E. (1999). Bundling information goods: Pricing, profits and efficiency. Management Science, 45, 1613–1630.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berndt, E., & Rappaport, N. (2001). Price and quality of desktop and mobile personal computers: A quarter century historical overview. American Economic Review, 91(2), 268–273.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brynjolfsson, E., & Hitt, L. (2000). Beyond computation: Information technology, organizational transformation and business performance. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(4), 23–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brynjolfsson, E., & Hitt, L. (2003). Computing productivity: Firm-level rvidence. Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(4), 793–808.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dewan, S., & Min, C. (1997). Substitution of information technology for other factors of production: A firm-level analysis. Management Science, 43(12), 1660–1675.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fri, R. (2003). The role of knowledge: Technological innovation in the energy system. Energy Journal, 24(4), 51–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallagher, K., Grübler, A., Kuhl, L., Nemet, G., & Wilson, C. (2012). The energy technology innovation system. Annual Review of Environment and Resources, 37, 137–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallagher, K., Holdren, J., & Sagar, A. (2006). Energy technology innovation. Annual Review of Environment and Resources, 31, 193–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goulder, L., & Schneider, S. (1999). Induced technological change and the attractiveness of CO\(_2\) abatement policies. Resource and Energy Economics, 21, 211–253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z., & Schmookler, J. (1963). Inventing and maximizing. American Economic Review, 53, 725–729.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1957). Hybrid corn: an exploration in the economics of technological change. Econometrica, 25, 501–522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grubb, M., Koehler, J., & Anderson, D. (2002). Induced technical change in energy/environmental modelling: analytic approaches and policy implications. Annual Review of Environment and Resources, 27, 271–308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grubb, M. (2004). Technology innovation and climate change policy: An overview of issues and options. Keio Economic Studies, 41(2), 103–132.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grübler, A., Aguayo, F., Gallagher, K., Hekkert, M., Jiang, K., Mytelka, L., et al. (2012). Policies for the energy technology innovation system. Chap. 24 in Global energy assessment—Toward a sustainable future. Cambridge/Laxenburg: Cambridge University Press/International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grübler, A., Nakićenović, N., & Victor, D. (1999). Dynamics of energy technologies and global change. Energy Policy, 27(5), 247–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson, R., & Newell, R. (2010). Accelerating energy innovation: Insights from multiple sectors. NBER Working Paper 16529. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Holdren, J., & Sagar, A. (2002). Assessing the global energy innovation system: Some key issues. Energy Policy, 30(6), 465–469.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • International Energy Agency (IEA). (2010). Global gaps in clean energy RD&D. Paris: OECD/IEA.

  • Jaffe, A., Newell, R., & Stavins, R. (2005). A tale of two market failures: Technology and environmental policy. Ecological Economics, 54, 164–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe, A., & Palmer, K. (1997). Environmental regulation and innovation: A panel data study. Review of Economics and Statistics, 79, 610–619.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson, D., & Stiroh, K. (1999). Information technology and growth. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 89(2), 109–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenberg, F. (1986). Energy prices and induced innovation. Research Policy, 15(2), 67–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Margolis, R., & Kammen, D. (1999a). Underinvestment: the energy technology and R&D policy challenge. Science, 285, 690–692.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Margolis, R., & Kammen, D. (1999b). Evidence of under-investment in energy R&D in the United States and the impact of Federal Policy. Energy Policy, 27(10), 575–584.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Narayanamurti, V., Anadon, L., & Sagar, A. (2009). Transforming energy innovation. Issues in Science and Technology, 26(Fall), 57–64.

    Google Scholar 

  • National Science Foundation (NSF). (2012). Research and development in industry. Washington, DC: National Science Foundation.

  • Nemet, G., & Kammen, D. (2007). U.S. energy research and development: Declining investment, increasing need, and the feasibility of expansion. Energy Policy, 35(1), 746–755.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neuhoff, K. (2005). Large scale deployment of renewables for electricity generation. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 21(1), 88–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newell, R., Jaffe, A., & Stavins, R. (1999). The induced innovation hypothesis and energy-saving technological change. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 907–940.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newell, R. (2008). A U.S. innovation strategy for climate change mitigation. The Brookings Institution, Discussion Paper 2008-15, December 2008.

  • Newell, R. (2010). The role of markets and policies in delivering innovation for climate change mitigation. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 26(2), 253–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newell, R. (2011). The energy innovation system: A historical perspective. In R. H. Henderson & R. G. Newell (Eds.), Accelerating energy innovation: Insights from multiple sectors. Chicago: University of Chicago Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Noberg-Bohm, V. (2000). Creating incentives for environmentally enhancing technological change: Lessons from 30 years of US energy technology policy. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 65, 125–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Popp, D. (2002). Induced innovation and energy prices. American Economic Review, 92, 160–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Popp, D., Newell, R., & Jaffe, A. (2009). Energy, the environment, and technological change. NBER Working Paper 14832. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • PTO (Patent and Trademark Office). (1998). Patent bibliographic database. U.S. Patent and Trademark Office, 1998 (cited November and December 1998). http://www.uspto.gov.

  • Romer, P. (1986). Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, 94, 1002–1037.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy, 98, S71–S102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sagar, A. D., & van der Zwaan, B. (2006). Technological innovation in the energy sector: R&D, deployment, and learning-by-doing. Energy Policy, 34, 2601–2608.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P., & Varian, H. (2002). The ’New Economy’ and information technology policy. In Jeffrey Frankle (Ed.), Economic policy during the Clinton administration. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmookler, J. (1962). Economic sources of inventive activity. Journal of Economic History, 22(1), 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmookler, J. (1966). Invention and economic growth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Smulders, S., & de Nooij, M. (2003). The impact of energy conservation on technology and economic growth. Resource and Energy Economics, 25(1), 59–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Department of Energy (DOE). (2010). FY2011 congressional budget request: Budget highlights. Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Energy.

  • van Zon, A., & Yetkiner, I. H. (2003). An endogenous growth model with embodied energy-saving technical change. Resource and Energy Economics, 25(1), 81–103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Varian, H. (2000). Versioning information goods. In Brian Kahin & Hal R. Varian (Eds.), Internet Publishing and Beyond. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Worrell, E., & Biermans, G. (2005). Move over! Stock turnover, retrofit and industrial energy efficiency. Energy Policy, 33(7), 949–962.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to the editors and two anonymous referees for suggesting ways to improve both the substance and exposition of this work. This paper was presented at the 5th World Congress of Environmental and Resource Economists in Istanbul and the 21st Annual Conference of the European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists in Helsinki, and various economics seminars. We thank participants for their comments. This work was financially supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant No. 71373055), China’s Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities (Grant No. PSYI201402), and Qianjiang Talent Research Program (Grant No. QJC1402002). Research results and conclusions expressed here are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the grant providers. The authors bear sole responsibility for any errors and omissions that may remain.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to ZhongXiang Zhang.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Solving the household problem

Solving the household’s problem requires setting the current-value Hamilton as,

$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm{H}(C_T, C_E, A,\lambda )= & {} InC_T (t)+InC_E (t)+\lambda (t)\cdot [r(t)\cdot A(t)\\&+w(t)\cdot 2L-P_T (t)\cdot C_T (t)-C_E (t)]. \end{aligned}$$

The interior necessary conditions with respect to four endogenous variables are as follow,

$$\begin{aligned} C_E:&\mathrm{H}_{C_E } (C_E, C_T, A,\lambda )=C_E (t)^{-1}-\lambda (t)=0 \end{aligned}$$
(40)
$$\begin{aligned} C_T:&\mathrm{H}_{C_T } (C_E, C_T, A,\lambda )=C_T (t)^{-1}-\lambda (t)\cdot P_T (t)=0 \end{aligned}$$
(41)
$$\begin{aligned} A:&\mathrm{H}_A (C_E, C_T, A,\lambda )=\lambda (t)\cdot r(t)=\rho \cdot \lambda (t)-\dot{\lambda }(t) \end{aligned}$$
(42)
$$\begin{aligned} \lambda :&\mathrm{H}_\lambda (C_E, C_T, A,\lambda )=r(t)\cdot A(t)+w(t)\cdot 2L-P_T (t)\cdot C_T (t)-C_E (t)=\dot{A}(t)\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(43)

Differentiating (40)–(41) with respect to time obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\dot{C}_E (t)}{C_E (t)}=-\frac{\dot{\lambda }(t)}{\lambda (t)}, \frac{\dot{P}_T (t)}{P_T (t)}+\frac{\dot{C}_T (t)}{C_T (t)}=-\frac{\dot{\lambda }(t)}{\lambda (t)}. \end{aligned}$$
(44)

Substituting (42) into (44) captures the time path of consumption of energy and IT products

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\dot{C}_E (t)}{C_E (t)}=-\frac{\dot{\lambda }(t)}{\lambda (t)}=r(t)-\rho , \frac{\dot{P}_T (t)}{P_T (t)}+\frac{\dot{C}_T (t)}{C_T (t)}=r(t)-\rho \end{aligned}$$

and the transversality condition

$$\begin{aligned} \mathop {\lim }\limits _{t\rightarrow +\infty } A(t)\cdot \exp \left[ {-\int _0^t {r(s)\cdot ds} } \right] =0 \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Appendix 2: Proof of Proposition 1

Given that the instantaneous flow profit \(\pi _E (i,t)\) is independent of primary intermediate energy input variety, the market value of primary energy firms is independent of primary energy variety and the HJB equation takes the form as \(r(t)\cdot V_E (t)-\dot{V}_E (t)=\pi _E (t)=\varepsilon _E ^{-1}L\). Meanwhile, the FEC of energy R&D requires that \(\eta \cdot V_E (t)=1\) for all time t when there is positive R&D for energy technological progress, implying that \(\dot{V}_E (t)=0\) for all time t. Substituting it into the HJB equation yields the equilibrium market interest rate \(r(t)=\eta L/\varepsilon _E \). Substituting \(r(t)=\eta L/\varepsilon _E \) into (2) yields the equilibrium growth rate of household consumption of final energy goods,

$$\begin{aligned} g_{C_E } (t)\equiv \frac{\dot{C}_E (t)}{C_E (t)}=r(t)-\rho =\frac{\eta L}{\varepsilon _E }-\rho . \end{aligned}$$
(45)

Given that energy market clearing condition always holds \(C_E (t)+X_E (t)+R_E (t)=Y_E (t)\), we get that final energy consumption should grow at the same rate as the output of energy goods. Furthermore, aggregating the whole set of varieties of primary energy intermediate inputs obtains the total outputs of end-use, secondary energy products

$$\begin{aligned} Y_E (t)=\frac{1}{1-a}\left[ {\int _0^{N_E (t)} {x_E (i,t)^{1-a}di} } \right] \cdot L^{a}=\frac{\varepsilon _E }{\varepsilon _E -1}\cdot L\cdot N_E (t), \end{aligned}$$
(46)

(46) implies that the equilibrium growth rate of secondary energy goods outputs is equal to that of primary energy technology variety,

$$\begin{aligned} g_{C_E } (t)=g_{Y_E } (t)=g_{N_E } (t)=\frac{\eta L}{\varepsilon _E }-\rho , \end{aligned}$$

where \(g_{Y_E } (t)\equiv \dot{Y}_E (t)/Y_E (t)\), \(g_{C_E } (t)\equiv \dot{C}_E (t)/C_E (t)\), \(g_{N_E } (t)\equiv \dot{N}_E (t)/N_E (t)\) is the growth rate of end-use energy outputs, final energy consumption, and primary energy variety, respectively.

Turn to IT sectors, given that the instantaneous flow profit of IT firms producing each differentiate variety of IT consumer product is independent of product varieties \(\pi _T (t)=\pi _T (j,t)\), the HJB equation (18) thus takes the form \(r(t)\cdot V_T (t) -\dot{V}_T (t)=\pi _T (t)\), and rearranging obtains

$$\begin{aligned} V_T (t)=\frac{\pi _T (t)}{r(t)-g_{V_T } (t)}, \end{aligned}$$
(47)

where \(g_{V_T } (t)\equiv \dot{V}_T (t)/V_T (t)\) is the growth rate of the market value of IT firms at time t. From the FEC of IT R&D (20), we have \(g_{N_T } (t)+g_{V_T } (t)=g_w (t)\), where \(g_{N_T } (t)\), \(g_{V_T } (t)\), \(g_w (t)\) is the growth rate of IT technology variety, market value, and wage rate at time t, respectively. Plugging it into (47) obtains

$$\begin{aligned} V_T (t)=\frac{\pi _T (t)}{r(t)-g_w (t)+g_{N_T } (t)}. \end{aligned}$$
(48)

Then using the instantaneous flow profit \(\pi _T (t)=(\varepsilon -1)^{-1}\cdot w(t)\cdot L_{TP} (t)/N_T (t)\) and FEC of IT R&D (20) to substitute \(\pi _T (t)\) and \(V_T (t)\), (48) can be simplified as,

$$\begin{aligned} \eta \cdot L_{TP} (t)=(\varepsilon _T -1)\cdot [r(t)-g_w (t)+g_{N_T } (t)]. \end{aligned}$$
(49)

Plugging the IPF in IT sectors (19) and the growth rate of wage rate \(g_w (t)=r(t)-\rho \) into (49), we derive the amount of workforce employed in IT sectors for output production and technology R&D,

$$\begin{aligned} L_{TP} (t)=\frac{(\varepsilon _T -1)\cdot (\rho +\eta L)}{\varepsilon _T \cdot \eta }, L_{TR} (t)=\frac{\eta L-(\varepsilon _T -1)\cdot \rho }{\varepsilon _T \cdot \eta }. \end{aligned}$$
(50)

From the IPF in IT sectors (19) we obtain the equilibrium growth rate of the number of IT variety

$$\begin{aligned} g_{N_T } (t)\equiv \frac{\dot{N}_T (t)}{N_T (t)}=\eta \cdot L_{TR} (t)=\frac{\eta L-(\varepsilon _T -1)\cdot \rho }{\varepsilon _T }. \end{aligned}$$
(51)

Based on the output of each individual variety of IT product given by \(c_T (j,t)=L_{TP} (t)/N_T (t)\), the amount of aggregate consumption of IT product composite is determined by,

$$\begin{aligned} C_T (t)=\left[ {\int _0^{N_T (t)} {c_T (j,t)^{\frac{\varepsilon _T -1}{\varepsilon _T }}dj} } \right] ^{\frac{\varepsilon _T }{\varepsilon _T -1}}=N_T (t)^{\frac{\varepsilon _T }{\varepsilon _T -1}}\cdot c_T (t)=L_{TP} (t)\cdot N_T (t)^{\frac{1}{\varepsilon _T -1}}, \end{aligned}$$
(52)

and the equilibrium growth rate of consumption of IT product is thus given by

$$\begin{aligned} g_{C_T } \equiv \frac{\dot{C}_T }{C_T }=\frac{1}{\varepsilon _T -1}\cdot g_{N_T } =\frac{\eta L-(\varepsilon _T -1)\cdot \rho }{\varepsilon _T (\varepsilon _T -1)}. \end{aligned}$$
(53)

\(\square \)

Appendix 3: Proof of Proposition 2

The growth rate of energy technology and IT variety \(g_{N_E} (t), g_{N_T } (t)\) is given by (22) and (24), and the difference in their growth rate is equal to

$$\begin{aligned} g_{N_T } (t)-g_{N_E } (t)=\frac{\eta L+\rho }{\varepsilon _T }-\rho -\left[ {\frac{\eta L}{\varepsilon _E }-\rho } \right] =\eta L\frac{\varepsilon _E -\varepsilon _T }{\varepsilon _T \varepsilon _E }+\frac{\rho }{\varepsilon _T } \end{aligned}$$

Consider that the differentiated variety in both energy and IT sector are gross substitutes, and the elasticity of substitution of primary energy input variety is sufficiently larger than that of IT product variety \(\varepsilon _E >\varepsilon _T >1\), we have \(g_{N_T} (t)>g_{N_E } (t)\). Moreover, the growth rate of consumption of energy and IT products \(g_{C_E } (t), g_{C_T} (t)\) is given by (22) and (23), and the difference in their growth rate is equal to

$$\begin{aligned} g_{C_T } (t)-g_{C_E } (t)=\frac{\eta L}{\varepsilon _T (\varepsilon _T -1)}-\frac{\rho }{\varepsilon _T }-\frac{\eta L}{\varepsilon _E }+\rho =\eta L\cdot \frac{\varepsilon _E -\varepsilon _T (\varepsilon _T -1)}{\varepsilon _E \varepsilon _T (\varepsilon _T -1)}+\rho \cdot \frac{\varepsilon _T -1}{\varepsilon _T} \end{aligned}$$

Given that \(\varepsilon _E >>\varepsilon _T >1\), we have \(g_{C_T }(t)>g_{C_E } (t)\). \(\square \)

Appendix 4: Proof of Proposition 3

The current-value Hamilton is given by (we drop time to simplify notation),

$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm{H}(C_E, C_T, N_E, N_T )= & {} InC_E +InC_T +\lambda _E \cdot \eta \cdot [(1-\varepsilon _E ^{-1})^{-\varepsilon }\cdot \varepsilon _E ^{-1}\cdot L\cdot N_E -C_E ] \\&+\lambda _T (t)\cdot \eta \cdot N_T (t)\cdot \left[ {L-C_T ^{S}(t)\cdot N_T ^{S}(t)^{\frac{1}{1-\varepsilon _T }}} \right] , \end{aligned}$$

where \(C_E, C_T \) are control variables, and \(N_E, N_T \) are state variables. The necessary conditions for an interior solution are as follows,

$$\begin{aligned}&C_E : C_E ^{-1}-\lambda _E \cdot \eta =0, \end{aligned}$$
(54)
$$\begin{aligned}&C_T : C_T ^{-1}-\lambda _T \cdot \eta \cdot N_T \cdot N_T ^{\frac{1}{1-\varepsilon _T }}=C_T ^{-1}-\lambda _T \cdot \eta \cdot N_T ^{\frac{2-\varepsilon _T }{1-\varepsilon _T }}=0 \end{aligned}$$
(55)
$$\begin{aligned}&N_E : \lambda _E \cdot \eta \cdot \left( 1-\varepsilon _E ^{-1}\right) ^{-\varepsilon _E }\cdot \varepsilon _E ^{-1}\cdot L=\rho \cdot \lambda _E -\dot{\lambda }_E, \end{aligned}$$
(56)
$$\begin{aligned}&N_T : \lambda _T \cdot \eta \cdot \left( L-C_T \cdot N_T ^{\frac{1}{1-\varepsilon _T }}\right) -\lambda _T \cdot \eta \cdot N_T \cdot C_T \cdot \frac{1}{1-\varepsilon _T }\cdot N_T ^{\frac{\varepsilon _T }{1-\varepsilon _T }}=\rho \cdot \lambda _T -\dot{\lambda }_T.\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(57)

From (54) and (56), we obtain the growth rate of energy consumption in the social optimum

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\dot{C}_E ^{S}(t)}{C_E ^{S}(t)}=\eta \cdot \varepsilon _E ^{-1}\cdot \left( 1-\varepsilon _E ^{-1}\right) ^{-\varepsilon _E }\cdot L-\rho . \end{aligned}$$
(58)

From energy market clearing condition, we obtain that the growth rate for energy consumption should be equal to the growth rate of energy technology variety,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\dot{N}_E ^{S}(t)}{N_E ^{S}(t)}=\frac{\dot{C}_E ^{S}(t)}{C_E ^{S}(t)}=\eta \cdot \varepsilon _E ^{-1}\cdot \left( 1-\varepsilon _E ^{-1}\right) ^{-\varepsilon _E }\cdot L-\rho . \end{aligned}$$
(59)

To solve for the growth rate of IT technology variety in the optimal growth path, differentiating (55) with respect to time t obtains

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\dot{C}_T }{C_T }=-\frac{\dot{\lambda }_T }{\lambda _T }-\frac{2-\varepsilon _T }{1-\varepsilon _T }\cdot \frac{\dot{N}_T }{N_T }. \end{aligned}$$
(60)

From (57) we obtain

$$\begin{aligned}&\eta \left( L-C_T \cdot N_T ^{\frac{1}{1-\varepsilon _T }}\right) -\frac{\eta }{1-\varepsilon _T }\cdot C_T \cdot N_T ^{\frac{1}{1-\varepsilon _T }}=\rho -\frac{\dot{\lambda }_T }{\lambda _T } \Rightarrow -\frac{\dot{\lambda }_T }{\lambda _T }\nonumber \\&\quad =\eta \cdot L-\eta \cdot \frac{2-\varepsilon _T }{1-\varepsilon _T }\cdot C_T \cdot N_T ^{\frac{1}{1-\varepsilon _T }}-\rho \end{aligned}$$
(61)

From the innovation possibility frontier we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\dot{N}_T }{N_T }=\eta \cdot \left[ L-C_T \cdot N_T ^{\frac{1}{1-\varepsilon _T }}\right] \Rightarrow -\frac{2-\varepsilon _T }{1-\varepsilon _T } \frac{\dot{N}_T }{N_T }=-\frac{2-\varepsilon _T }{1-\varepsilon _T }\eta \cdot \left[ {L-C_T \cdot N_T ^{\frac{1}{1-\varepsilon _T }}} \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(62)

Substituting (61)–(62) into (60) obtains the growth rate of IT product consumption in the social optimal growth path (superscript “S” corresponds to the social optimum.)

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\dot{C}_T ^{S}(t)}{C_T ^{S}(t)}=\frac{\eta L}{\varepsilon _T -1}-\rho . \end{aligned}$$
(63)

Furthermore, based on the IT market clearing condition \(C_T (t)=N_T (t)^{\frac{1}{\varepsilon _T -1}}\cdot L_{TP} (t)\), we derive the growth rate of IT technology variety in the social optimal growth path as

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\dot{N}_T ^{S}(t)}{N_T ^{S}(t)}=(\varepsilon _T -1)\cdot \frac{\dot{C}_T ^{S}(t)}{C_T ^{S}(t)}=(\varepsilon _T -1)\cdot \left( {\frac{\eta L}{\varepsilon _T -1}-\rho } \right) =\eta L-(\varepsilon _T -1)\rho \end{aligned}$$
(64)

Substituting (64) into the IPF derive the amount of workforce allocated for R&D and production in IT sector,

$$\begin{aligned} L_{TR} ^{S}(t)=\frac{1}{\eta }\cdot \frac{\dot{N}_T ^{S}(t)}{N_T ^{S}(t)}=L-(\varepsilon _T -1)\eta ^{-1}\rho , L_{TP} ^{S}(t)=L-L_{TR} ^{S}(t)=(\varepsilon _T -1)\eta ^{-1}\rho \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(65)

\(\square \)

Appendix 5: Proof of Proposition 4

Comparing (24) with (28), we obtain that the socially optimal growth rate of technology variety in the energy sector is always greater than that in the market equilibrium. Meanwhile, comparing (23) with (29), we obtain that the socially optimal growth rate of technology variety in the IT sector is always greater than that in the market equilibrium. Furthermore, we compare the growth rates of energy technology variety with that of IT variety in the optimal growth path,

$$\begin{aligned} g_E ^{S}(t)=\eta \cdot L\cdot \varepsilon _E ^{-1}\cdot \left( 1-\varepsilon _E ^{-1}\right) ^{-\varepsilon _E }-\rho , g_T ^{S}(t)=\eta L-(\varepsilon _T -1)\rho , \end{aligned}$$

where \(g_E ^{S}(t)\equiv \dot{N}_E ^{S}(t)/N_E ^{S}(t)\), \(g_T ^{S}(t)\equiv \dot{N}_T ^{S}(t)/N_T ^{S}(t)\) denotes the optimal growth rate of energy and IT technology variety, respectively. The comparison thus boils down to

$$\begin{aligned} g_E ^{S}(t)-g_T ^{S}(t)=\eta \cdot L\cdot \left[ \varepsilon _E ^{-1}\cdot \left( 1-\varepsilon _E ^{-1}\right) ^{-\varepsilon _E }-1\right] +(\varepsilon _T -2)\cdot \rho , \end{aligned}$$
(66)

Given that the amount of workforce allocated to production in IT sector is less than the workforce endowment available in IT sector, \(L_{TP} ^{S}(t)=(\varepsilon _T -1)\rho \eta ^{-1}<L\). Substituting it into (66) obtains

$$\begin{aligned}&\eta \cdot L\cdot \left[ \varepsilon _E ^{-1}\cdot \left( 1-\varepsilon _E ^{-1}\right) ^{-\varepsilon _E }-1\right] \nonumber \\&\quad +\left( \varepsilon _T -2\right) \cdot \rho >\rho \cdot \left[ (\varepsilon _T -1)\cdot \left[ \varepsilon _E ^{-1}\cdot \left( 1-\varepsilon _E ^{-1}\right) ^{-\varepsilon _E }-1\right] +(\varepsilon _T -2)\right] , \end{aligned}$$
(67)

whether the right-hand side of (67) is positive (social optimal growth rate of energy technology variety is larger than that of IT variety) boils down to

$$\begin{aligned} \varepsilon _E ^{-1}\cdot (1-\varepsilon _E ^{-1})^{-\varepsilon _E }-1>\frac{2-\varepsilon _T }{\varepsilon _T -1} \Rightarrow \left( {\frac{\varepsilon _E -1}{\varepsilon _E }} \right) ^{-\varepsilon _E }>\left( {\frac{\varepsilon _T -1}{\varepsilon _E }} \right) ^{-1}. \end{aligned}$$
(68)

Given that the elasticity of substitution between primary energy inputs \(\varepsilon _E \) is sufficiently greater than the elasticity of substitution between IT consumer products \(\varepsilon _T \), (68) does not necessarily hold, that is, the social planner solution can’t achieve an outcome in which energy technology variety grows faster than IT variety.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Jin, W., Zhang, Z. The tragedy of product homogeneity and knowledge non-spillovers: explaining the slow pace of energy technological progress. Ann Oper Res 255, 639–661 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-016-2144-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-016-2144-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation