Introduction

Agroforestry has clear potential to enhance ecosystem services within agricultural landscapes of tropical regions (Jose 2009). However, like any agricultural innovation, farmers will only integrate trees into their farming systems if they perceive agroforestry to align with their objectives and available resources (Pannell et al. 2006). Farmers’ attitudes towards agroforestry will therefore play a key role for adoption (Frey et al. 2012; Meijer et al. 2014). Understanding how farmers perceive the advantages and drawbacks of different agroforestry systems will help to identify systems that best meet farmers’ needs, and to target extension activities accordingly.

Previous research into farmers’ knowledge and perceptions of agroforestry has typically relied on qualitative methods (e.g. Calle et al. 2009; Frey et al. 2012; Garen et al. 2009; Hand and Tyndall 2018). Quantitative studies are less common and have been mostly limited to temperate regions (Laroche et al. 2018; Shrestha et al. 2004). Quantitative data, however, are often needed for land-use modelling approaches. These models can help analyse trade-offs between various objectives achieved by different farming and agroforestry systems, providing a powerful decision support tool for researchers, policy-makers and land managers (Kaim et al. 2018; Le Gal et al. 2011). Farm level models can also serve as a discussion aid to support co-learning between researchers and farmers (Le Gal et al. 2013; Voinov and Bousquet 2010).

Our study combines positive and normative approaches to investigate farmers’ perceptions of agroforestry and conventional land-use systems (Fig. 1). We obtain quantitative data from farmer interviews using a rapid rural appraisal technique in which farmers evaluated the ability of six land-uses to achieve 10 pre-defined socio-economic and ecological objectives. In the first (empiric) analysis stage we aim to understand potential differences in how distinct groups of farmers perceive agroforestry. We use hierarchical cluster analysis to group farms with similar land-use and income strategies. It is known that farm and household characteristics can influence farmers’ attitudes towards agricultural innovations (Meijer et al. 2014; Pannell et al. 2006). Therefore, we are interested to compare the perceptions of each farmer group to check for potential differences in how they rated agroforestry relative to the conventional land-use systems.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Overview of research approach

Empiric ratings, however, may not be enough to understand farmers’ potential land-use decisions when striving to meet multiple household goals under uncertainty. These ratings can identify the best land-use for achieving a single objective, but identifying the best mix of land-uses to achieve multiple objectives is more difficult, especially if accounting for farmers’ uncertainty about the ability of each land-use to achieve each objective. This uncertainty is important, given that in regions where agroforestry is not widespread, farmers may vary considerably in their knowledge and familiarity of the systems. Therefore, empiric ratings alone may be insufficient to assess agroforestry’s potential to help meet the multiple needs and constraints of heterogeneous farmer groups.

In the second stage of the analysis we therefore move to a mechanistic, multi-objective modelling approach, to investigate if agroforestry, as part of a diversified land-use portfolio, might help to reduce trade-offs between farm-level goals. Based on the land-use perceptions of each group of farmers we derive theoretically optimal land-use compositions that balance the achievement of the pre-defined socio-economic and ecological objectives under uncertainty. This allows us to look beyond farmers’ existing land-use decisions to investigate the likelihood of different farmer groups to adopt agroforestry.

Testing this approach in a forest frontier region of Eastern Panama, our research questions are:

  • How do farmers with different land-use and income strategies perceive agroforestry relative to existing land-use systems?

  • Will the type and share of agroforestry selected in an optimised land-use portfolio differ between farms with different land-use and income strategies?

By exploring these questions we aim to show how the coupled rapid rural appraisal and optimisation approach may help tailor policy recommendations to different groups of farmers, and to demonstrate its potential for informing group discussions in participatory planning processes.

Methods

Data collection

Study area and sampling method

We test our modelling approach with farmers in Tortí, a township with around 1600 inhabitants (INEC 2010) on the Pan-American Highway, around 125 km east of Panama City. The natural vegetation of the area is classed as humid tropical forest, with 1910 mm annual rainfall and a dry season from January to March (ETESA 2018). Large-scale forest clearing began five decades ago, when colonists from Panama’s western provinces began to settle in the region. Pasture for cattle grazing now comprises 64% of the land-use of the wider Tortí region, with 17% forest cover, 8% cropland and 8% fallow land (INEC 2011).

We targeted farmers using a mixed sampling method: going door-to-door in Tortí and its surrounding villages, approaching landholders at a local cattle auction, and asking interviewees to suggest other farmers. The interview had two parts. First we used a semi-structured questionnaire and participatory resource mapping (where farmers drew a map of their farm), to identify the current land-use composition of each farm and obtain household data. We used this data to identify groups of similar farmers via a cluster analysis. In the second part of the interview we quantified farmer opinion of different land-uses. We used this data to compare the perceptions of the different farm groups and to derive the optimised land-use portfolios for each group. The interviews took 40 min to 3 h to complete and were conducted in Spanish in April–May 2018.

Selected land-uses and indicators and their rapid appraisal

Our study quantifies farmers’ perceptions of six land-uses (Table 1) against 10 socio-economic and ecological indicators (Table 2). Pasture, cropland, teak plantation and natural forest represent the most common land covers in the study area. In contrast, alley cropping and silvopasture (with a tree density of ≈ 200 trees per hectare) are not commonly practiced in Tortí: these two agroforestry systems represent innovative land-use systems for the region.

Table 1 Description of the six land-use options, l, that farmers evaluated
Table 2 The 10 indicators, i, against which farmers evaluated the six land-uses

The 10 indicators against which farmers evaluated each land-use were identified from previous studies in Panama and Latin America (Table 2). They reflect different goals that farmers may consider when deciding what to produce on their farm, as well as potential benefits and drawbacks of agroforestry.

Borrowing techniques from rapid rural appraisal (Riley and Fielding 2001), we used ranking and scoring to quantify farmers’ judgement of each land-use against each indicator. Before starting the evaluation task we described the land-uses with visual aids, discussing each system with the farmer to ensure a common understanding. Next we recorded farmers’ general preferences by asking interviewees to rank the six land-uses from the one they like best to the one they like least (they did so by arranging six cards depicting each land-use in order of their preference). Farmers then evaluated the land-uses against the remaining indicators in two steps. First they ranked the land-uses (by arranging the cards) from best to worst for achieving a given indicator. They then scored the performance of each land-use for that indicator on a scale of 0–10. From these individual scores, \(y_{i,l,k}\), of each farmer, k, for each land-use, l, and indicator, i, we computed the mean score, \(\hat{y}_{i,l,f} ,\) for the farm types, f, identified in the cluster analysis (described next).

Empiric analysis to identify farm types and corresponding land-use perceptions

During the interviews we asked farmers to identify all land-uses on their farm and with the help of the farm map quantify the area (in hectares) of each. We also asked farmers about their management practices (e.g. whether they use fertiliser and pesticides) and household characteristics (e.g. size of the household, sources of on-farm income). Based on this interview data we used hierarchical cluster analysis to identify groups of similar farms. We chose this analysis as an objective way to divide farmers into groups that may be relevant for political decision-makers. The cluster analysis included 12 variables related to farm size and ownership, current land-use and management practices, labour availability and income structure (Table 3). Sources of on-farm income included crops, cattle, timber and other processed products (e.g. honey from sugarcane). We used standardised values (z-scores) for each variable and squared Euclidean distance as the similarity measure. We chose Ward’s method because of its tendency to generate homogeneous clusters that are relatively equal in size (Hair et al. 2014); this clustering algorithm is commonly used when identifying farm typologies (e.g. Köbrich et al. 2003; Nainggolan et al. 2013). Following Hair et al. (2014) we assessed the percentage changes in within-cluster heterogeneity via the agglomeration schedule, which suggested a three-cluster solution. This also allowed for a meaningful interpretation when comparing the characteristics of each cluster; we therefore decided to retain the three-cluster solution and refer to the clusters as farm types.

Table 3 Variables included in the cluster analysis

Based on the individual land-use scores, \(y_{i,l,k}\), obtained in the farmer interviews, we computed the mean score, \(\hat{y}_{i,l,f} ,\) for the first nine indicators for the three identified farm types, f, where K is the total number of farmers in each group:

$$\hat{y}_{i,l,f} = \frac{1}{{K_{f} }} \mathop \sum \limits_{k = 1}^{{K_{f} }} y_{i,l,k} \quad {\text{for}}\,\,i = 1,2,3, \ldots ,9;\quad {\text{for}}\,\,f = 1,2,3. .$$
(1)

We also computed the standard error of the mean, \(SEM_{i,l,f}^{{}} ,\) where SD is the standard deviation:

$$SEM_{i,l,f} = \frac{{SD_{i,l,f} }}{{\sqrt {K_{f} } }}\quad {\text{for}}\,\,i = 1,2,3, \ldots ,9;\quad {\text{for}}\,\,f = 1,2,3.$$
(2)

Following Knoke et al. (2014), we measured farmers’ general preferences (the tenth indicator) as the number of times farmers from each farm type selected a given land-use as their first or second choice:

$$\hat{y}_{10,l,f} = \left( {\# best + \# second\,best} \right)_{l,f}$$
(3)

The standard error of this estimate \((SEM_{10,l,f} )\) was computed within each farm type as follows (for clarity the subscript f, denoting farm type, has been omitted):

$$\begin{aligned} p_{l} & = \frac{{\hat{y}_{10,l} }}{{\mathop \sum \nolimits_{l}^{L} \hat{y}_{10,l} }} = \frac{{\hat{y}_{10,l} }}{n} \\ SEM_{10,l} & = n \cdot \sqrt {p_{l} \cdot \left( {1 - p_{l} } \right)/n} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(4)

where n is the total number of ‘best’ and ‘second best’ choices across all land-uses for each farm type, and \(p_{l}\) is the relative frequency of ‘best’ and ‘second best’ choices for a given land-use within that farm type.

Normative analysis to explore the potential of agroforestry to meet farmers’ objectives

We couple the farm perception data of each farm type with a normative model to investigate the role of agroforestry in theoretical land-use portfolios that minimise trade-offs between farm-level goals. These optimised land-use portfolios represent a hypothetical farm comprising various shares of the six land-uses. We use the optimisation method developed by Knoke et al. (2015, 2016) for land allocation problems in tropical landscapes. The model is formulated as a Min–Max (Chebyshev) problem (Romero 2001) that considers multiple objectives. In our study the 10 indicators serve as objectives, which are weighted equally in the optimisation. For each indicator we set a target level and the model selects the mix of land-uses that minimises the largest (worst) shortfall between the target and achieved level across all indicators. This results in a compromise solution that balances the achievement of all indicators. High performance in one indicator does not compensate for poor performance in another; the model instead always seeks to improve the contribution of the worst performing indicator (Romero 2001).

A strength of the modelling approach is its ability to integrate uncertainty in land-use decisions. Here uncertainty describes our lack of knowledge about how much a land-use will actually contribute to a given objective now and in the future. The model captures this uncertainty through so-called “uncertainty scenarios”, which describe potential fluctuations in the performance of each land-use against each indicator. The model searches for a land-use allocation that improves the minimum performance across all uncertainty scenarios and indicators, thereby guaranteeing a minimum performance level for each indicator even in worst-case situations. This is a form of robust decision-making, which is recommended when facing high levels of uncertainty (Walker et al. 2013). Essentially, our model simulates a risk averse decision-maker who seeks to minimise potential losses or poor performance of any indicator in worst cases (Knoke et al. 2015). Considering uncertainty promotes diversified land-use portfolios even when optimising for a single objective, because diversification provides insurance against poor performance of a single land-use for achieving that objective.

In our study we use the mean land-use scores, \(\hat{y}_{i,l,f}\), derived from the interviews to estimate the ability of each land-use, l, to achieve each indicator, i, from the perspective of each farm type, f. To account for potential variation in these scores (and therefore in land-use performance) the model computes unwanted deviations within the uncertainty scenarios, by either adding or subtractingFootnote 1 multiples, \(f_{U}\), of the \(SEM_{i,l,f}\) to or from the mean scores (Eq. S3 in the supplementary methods). Therefore our measure of uncertainty is based on variability of farmer opinion within each farm type.

We ran the optimisation separately for each farm type using the land-use scores and SEM specific to each. The model calculates the distance, Di,u, between the target (best possible) performance level and level achieved by a hypothetical farm portfolio for each indicator in each uncertainty scenario, u. These distances represent underperformance. The model then selects the land-use composition (mix of the six land-uses) that minimises the largest distance (worst underperformance, β) across all uncertainty scenarios. The optimised land-use portfolios therefore represent the land-use mix that minimises the worst underperformance of any indicator. We describe the optimisation procedure in detail in the supplementary material with an accompanying optimisation sheet (Excel file), while the main steps are summarised in Fig. 2. We also refer the reader to Knoke et al. (2020) for further details of the modelling approach.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Overview of the optimisation procedure

For the main analysis we included all indicators and land-uses in the model and ran the optimisation for each farm type for \(f_{U}\) = 0, 0.5, 1, … 3. The factor \(f_{U}\) influences the size of the unwanted deviations of land-use scores within the uncertainty scenarios, and thus dictates the level of uncertainty included in the model: \(f_{U}\) = 0 ignores uncertainty and \(f_{U}\) = 3 represents a high level of uncertainty (Knoke et al. 2016). Hence, optimised land-use portfolios at lower \(f_{U}\) values are derived for less cautious decision-makers and the portfolios at higher \(f_{U}\) for more cautious decision-makers.

We also tested different model setups as sensitivity analyses. First we excluded the two agroforestry options from the optimisation to check the plausibility of the optimised land-use portfolios (Fig. 5). We also reran the optimisation using a relative SEM for all land-use scores (Eq. S3), to better understand the effect of uneven sample sizes. Lastly, we optimised each indicator individually to help understand potential drivers and barriers to agroforestry adoption (Fig. S1).

Results

Farm types identified through the cluster analysis

We interviewed 35 farmers who managed a total area of 2681 ha; farm size ranged from five to 271 ha (mean 77 ha). All farms had similar access to markets. Based on the cluster analysis we divided our sample into three farm types with different land-use and income characteristics: ‘Crop-based farms’, ‘Diversified cattle farms’ and ‘Non-diversified cattle farms’ (Table 4).

Table 4 Comparison of the three farm types based on variables included in the cluster analysis (see Table 3)

Crop-based farms is the largest cluster, comprising 17 farms. Crops provide at least half of farm income for all but one of these farms. Farms in this cluster comprise more crops (mean share 45%) and less pasture (mean share of 37%) than the other farm types; land-use is also more diversified (mean Shannon index of 0.8). The diversified cattle farms are typically dominated by pasture (mean share of 83%) and derive most, but not all, of their on-farm income from cattle. In contrast, non-diversified cattle farms obtain 100% of their on-farm income from cattle; on-farm income is therefore less diversified than for the other farm types. These farms comprise a high percentage of pasture (mean share 91%) and are less intensified than the other farm types. A higher proportion of household members (on average 87%) also work on the farm.

Alley cropping and silvopasture (as defined in Table 1) were not present on any of the interviewed farms. Therefore, the perceptions and opinions expressed by farmers towards these agroforestry systems represent the views of “non-adopters”. A respective 76 and 45% of interviewees reported having indirect experience with silvopasture and alley cropping systems similar to those included in our study, for example when visiting farms of relatives in other regions. A fifth (21%) of farmers, however, reported no experience with either system. Therefore their assessment was based on their general experience as farmers in Tortí and our descriptions of the agroforestry systems during the farmer interviews.

Farmers’ perceptions of land-uses

Figure 3 displays the land-use scores (\(\hat{y}_{i,l,f}\)) of the three highest rated land-uses, l, for each indicator, i, for the three farm types, f. For many indicators the rankings were similar across farm types. All farm types rated pasture as the best option for maintaining liquidity, followed by silvopasture and cropland (Fig. 3). Each farm type also rated forests as the best choice for reducing labour demand, establishment costs and management complexity and for protecting soil and water resources. Finally, each group selected cropland, pasture and silvopasture as the best options for meeting household needs, and expressed strong general preferences for the two cattle-based land-uses (with crop-based farms expressing the highest preference for silvopasture).

Fig. 3
figure 3

Mean scores (\(\hat{y}_{i,l,f}\)) of the three best performing land-uses, l, for each indicator, i, as rated by each farm type, f, where 0 = low and 10 = high. Asterisks denote indicators where a lower score is desirable. Values for general preferences (\(\hat{y}_{10,l,f}\)) are the percent of farmers who chose a given land-use as best or second best. Striped bars represent identical scores between two land-uses (both land-uses share third place). Error bars represent the SEMi,l,f

For some indicators the rankings diverged between farm types. Each group rated a different land-use as the most stable against environmental and economic shocks: diversified cattle farms selected teak plantation, crop-based farms silvopasture and non-diversified cattle farms forest. Crop-based and diversified cattle farmers rated teak plantation as the most profitable land-use, whereas non-diversified cattle farms selected alley cropping. Compared to the other farm types, the non-diversified cattle farmers perceived pasture and silvopasture to be less labour intensive, which could reflect that these farmers tended to run less intensified cattle operations with lower stocking rates. Interestingly, the crop-based farmers rated silvopasture and alley cropping more favourably for investment costs than the other farm types. This group also ranked silvopasture within the three least complex land-uses. This suggests that crop-based farmers may perceive establishment costs and management complexity to pose less of a barrier to agroforestry adoption.

Compared to silvopasture, farmers tended to express more negative opinions towards alley cropping; for five indicators each farm type ranked it in the three worst land-uses. The non-diversified cattle farmers were most positive towards alley cropping: scoring it higher for long-term income and the two ecological indicators and expressing a higher general preference. For these farmers long-term profitability and protecting soil and water resources could be important motivations to adopt the agroforestry system. However, the non-diversified cattle farmers also scored alley cropping more poorly for labour demand, management complexity and establishment costs (supplementary Table S1), highlighting potential barriers to adoption for this group of farmers.

Our comparison of land-use scores between the farm types is descriptive in nature. Significant differences between farm types at the 0.05 level were found for land-use scores within the indicators labour, investment costs and complexity, as well as for long-term income for p < 0.06 (based on one-way ANOVA with LSD post hoc comparisons—see Table S1). Our focus, however, is not on the absolute difference in land-use scores between each farm type. Instead, we want to understand differences in (a) how farmers’ perceive the relative performance of agroforestry compared to the other land-use options, and (b) the variability of these perceptions (as a measure of uncertainty or risk). These relative differences are likely to be important drivers of modelled land-use decisions, but cannot be captured in a single statistical test. In the next section we show how our normative model, which accounts for the relative performance of all land-use options and their variability, allows us to analyse the possible consequences of different farmer perceptions for their simulated optimal land-use decisions.

Pairing empiric data with the normative model

Using the perceptions and preferences of each farm type, we determined the optimal land-use composition to balance the achievement of the 10 socio-economic and ecological indicators. While agroforestry was always selected in the optimal land-use portfolio, we found that the type and share of agroforestry included in the portfolios differed considerably between farm types (Fig. 4). Looking first at an uncertainty level of \(f_{U}\) = 2 (representing the perspective of a more cautious decision-maker), we see that both silvopasture and alley cropping appear in the optimised portfolios of the two cattle-based farm types, but only silvopasture is present in the optimised portfolio of the crop-based farms. The overall share of agroforestry, however, was higher in the portfolio for the crop-based farms (42%) than in the portfolios for the two cattle-based farm types (21 and 33% respectively).

Fig. 4
figure 4

Optimised farm composition (share of land allocated to each land-use) for balancing the achievement of the 10 indicators under increasing uncertainty, \(f_{U}\), based on the perceptions and preferences of each farm type: a crop-based farms, b diversified cattle farms and c non-diversified cattle farms

In all cases, the optimised portfolios are very different to the current land-use composition, where agroforestry is not present (Fig. 5, left bars). Excluding agroforestry from the optimisation produces land-use portfolios dominated by pasture for the cattle-based farm types, and by cropland at higher uncertainty levels for crop-based farms, with natural forest shares of 11–17% (Fig. 5, right bars). This is similar to the aggregated land-use of each farm type, although teak plantation is overrepresented in the optimised portfolios of the cattle-based farms.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Right columns: Optimised farm composition (share of land allocated to each land-use) for each farm-type for balancing the achievement of the 10 indicators under high uncertainty (\(f_{U}\) = 2.5) when excluding silvopasture and alley cropping from the optimisation. Left columns: Aggregated land-use composition of farms within each farm type (recorded in the farmer interviews)

Returning now to the portfolios including agroforestry, the ideal composition for the crop-based farms is quite stable across a wider range of uncertainty (\(f_{U}\) = 0 to \(f_{U}\) = 3). In contrast, the optimised portfolios of the two cattle-based farm types become more diversified with increasing uncertainty (Fig. 4). This reflects the relatively large SEMi,l,f for these farm types. When expressed as a proportion of the mean (\(\hat{y}_{i,l,f}\)), the average SEMi,l,f was 0.18 and 0.19 for the diversified and non-diversified cattle farms, compared to 0.12 for the crop-based farms. In our model, increasingly equal land-use shares at higher values of \(f_{U}\) is the result of a statistical averaging effect to buffer against uncertainty (Knoke et al. 2016). Higher \(f_{U}\) values enlarge the unfavourable deviations in land-use performance considered in the uncertainty scenarios (Eq. S3), and the model selects a more diversified land-use portfolio to protect against potential underachievement of a given indicator. A high SEMi,l,f enhances this effect, and hence the trend towards greater diversification at higher uncertainty levels is more pronounced in the optimised portfolios of the two cattle-based farm types.

The differences in the type and share of agroforestry included in the optimal portfolios may therefore relate to (a) differences in farmers’ perceptions of the land-uses, or (b) diversification effects driven by the smaller sample size and relatively large SEMi,l,f for the cattle-based farms. To check that our results were not predominantly driven by differences in the sample sizes, we reran the optimisation for each farm type, using the same land-use scores \(\hat{y}_{i,l,f}\), but a relative standard error, \(SEM_{i,l,f}^{relative} ,\) derived from the SEMi,l of all farms combined, which on average was 10% of the mean land-use scores (Eq. S12). This ensured that the size of the standard error as a proportion of the mean land-use score remained constant between farm types.

Using a relative standard error led to minimal changes in the optimal land-use portfolio for the crop-based farms (compare Fig. 4a and 6a). Using the \(SEM_{i,l,f}^{relative}\) did, however, alter the ideal portfolios of the two cattle-based farm types; both became less diversified. For instance, alley cropping no longer appears in the optimal land-use portfolio of the diversified cattle farms under high uncertainty levels (compare Fig. 4b and 6b). Similarly, teak plantation and cropland are no longer included in the optimal portfolio of non-diversified cattle farms at moderately-high uncertainty levels, and the share of alley cropping reduces by five percentage points.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Optimised farm composition (share of land allocated to each land-use) for balancing the achievement of the 10 indicators under increasing uncertainty, \(f_{U}\), based on the mean land-use scores the three farm types (\(\hat{y}_{i,l,f}\)): a crop-based farms, b diversified cattle farms and c non-diversified cattle farms, using a relative standard error \((SEM_{i,l,f}^{relative} )\)

Nevertheless, after adjusting the standard error, differences remain in the type and share of agroforestry included in the optimal land-use portfolios of each farm type. The portfolio for crop-based farms still contains the largest share of agroforestry (e.g. 47% at \(f_{U}\) = 2) and the portfolio for diversified cattle farms the smallest (13% at \(f_{U}\) = 2). Alley cropping is only included in the optimal portfolio of the non-diversified cattle farms. This demonstrates that the selection of agroforestry systems is not only driven by diversification effects from small samples.

Portfolios optimised for individual objectives (Fig. S1) help to understand factors that may promote or hinder agroforestry adoption. We found that agroforestry was only selected in optimised portfolios for a small set of indicators (long-term income, household needs, economic stability and general preferences), which diverged strongly between farm types. For crop-based farms, agroforestry only appears in the optimised portfolios for economic stability and general preferences, where silvopasture comprises more than 70% of the land-use. The perceived superior performance of silvopasture for these two indicators contributes to its dominance in the multi-indicator portfolio for crop-based farms, i.e. in the portfolio that consider all 10 objectives simultaneously. For the cattle-based farm types, silvopasture appears in lower shares (< 37%) in portfolios optimised for these two indicators, as well as in the portfolio optimised for long-term income for the diversified farms and in the portfolio optimised for meeting household needs for the non-diversified farms. Alley cropping is also selected for two indicators for the non-diversified cattle farms; it dominates (90% share) the portfolio optimised for long-term income and contributes 14% to the general preference portfolio. The favourable rating for long-term income (and to a lesser extent general preferences) is therefore likely to contribute to the selection of alley cropping in the multi-indicator portfolio of non-diversified cattle farmers.

Importantly, the inclusion of agroforestry (predominately silvopasture) within the general preference portfolio of each farm type suggests that the farmers’ cultural preferences are compatible with (rather than posing a barrier to) agroforestry adoption. Similarly, the inclusion of silvopasture in the optimal portfolio for economic stability suggests that this indicator could be a potential driver of agroforestry adoption across all farm types.

Agroforestry was not selected in portfolios optimised for the remaining six indicators. These portfolios were very similar across the farm types, dominated by either pasture (for maintaining liquidity) or forest (for reducing labour demand, investment costs and management complexity, and protecting soil and water resources). The superior performance of forest for the latter indicators explains its consistently large share in the multi-indicator portfolios for each farm type. The absence of agroforestry in single-indicator portfolios suggest that these indicators may represent barriers to agroforestry adoption.

Discussion

Insights from the empiric and normative approaches

Within our sample we found only moderate differences in farmers’ perceptions of the two agroforestry systems. Across all farm types, farmers tended to evaluate silvopasture more favourably than alley cropping against the 10 indicators. This aligns with the ‘cattle culture’ of pioneer areas in Central and South America, where owning cattle awards prestigious social status. Cattle also represent a way of accumulating wealth as a form of private insurance, which is especially important in regions with weak healthcare, loan and pension systems (Connelly and Shapiro 2006; Perz et al. 2006). Empiric rankings suggest differences in how the farm types perceived agroforestry in terms of investment costs, management complexity and long-term profitability, as well as in their general preferences towards the systems. Although based on a limited dataset, our findings represent a new contribution to agroforestry research, because previous studies on farmers’ perceptions have not compared the views of farmers with different land-use and income characteristics (e.g. Frey et al. 2012; Garen et al. 2009; Hand and Tyndall 2018). The ranking of mutually exclusive land-use options alone, however, often does not reflect the farmer’s reality. Decisions are usually taken at the farm level, including multiple land-use options that serve multiple needs of the farm/household. These complexities can hardly be incorporated into empiric rankings, but they may constitute important barriers to agroforestry adoption. Our approach therefore couples empiric data with farm-level optimisation, capable of considering uncertainty as well as multiple land-use options and farm-level objectives simultaneously.

Despite the moderate difference in the perception data of the empiric analysis, we found substantial differences in the type and share of agroforestry selected in the optimised land-use compositions of each farm type. This reveals that an overall positive ranking of agroforestry may alone be a misleading indicator of farmers’ acceptance of agroforestry, if farm-level considerations are not sufficiently accounted for. Here, optimisation approaches may be a helpful methodological complement. Assuming that farmers strive to reduce underperformance of the 10 pre-selected indicators, the optimal portfolios suggest that crop-based farms would benefit from allocating a larger share of their land to silvopasture, while for cattle-based farms diversifying their farm with more land-uses (including alley cropping) may be advantageous. Differences in the optimal portfolios of farms with similar land-use and income patterns are plausible, given the many empiric studies that link farm and household characteristics with farmers’ land-use decisions, including the degree of agricultural diversification (Ochoa et al. 2019; Torres et al. 2018), and adoption of agroforestry (Pattanayak et al. 2003; Zabala et al. 2013).

Differences in the optimised land-use portfolios provide us with important information, because it suggests that farmers belonging to each farm type may respond differently to agroforestry. Understanding these differences may help to design better policies to achieve agroforestry adoption by tailoring recommendations and extension programs to different groups of farmers (Köbrich et al. 2003). For our study region, agricultural extension staff could emphasise the long-term profitability of alley cropping systems (as evidenced by bio-economic modelling by Paul et al. (2017) based on local trials) when working with farmers with diversified farm income sources. We also found that farmers who derive most of their farm income from cattle may perceive management complexity and investment costs as a greater barrier to agroforestry adoption. Promoting agroforestry among these farmers may benefit, for example, from skill-sharing and training programs to enhance farmers’ capacity to manage the systems, as well as financial incentives (e.g. subsidising the cost of tree seedlings and fencing material) to reduce up-front capital costs.

Critical appraisal of the modelling approach

The normative approach allows us to go beyond current land-use patterns to explore the potential of agroforestry to be part of diversified farm portfolios that meet multiple farm-level goals. Divergence between the optimised and existing land-use portfolios may signal a conflict between the land-use practices that farmers wish to have, and those that they can implement given their available resources and household needs. For example, the optimal portfolios derived from farmers’ stated land-use preferences all contain agroforestry although it was absent on their own farms. To more realistically capture individual farm constraints within the optimised portfolios, it might be necessary to include calculated economic indicators in the optimisation. Such indicators could be derived from more intensive farm surveys, for example to determine expected costs and cash flows to better reflect hard economic constraints not reflected in farmer preferences. Other studies in Eastern Panama have also suggested a conflict between the forest-friendly farming practices that farmers deem desirable and those that are possible with their economic constraints (Tschakert et al. 2007). Our modelling approach revealed that individual goals such as reducing investment costs and management complexity as well as maintaining liquidity may impede agroforestry adoption. However, the approach also shows that diversified land-use portfolios can help buffer these constraints. For example, leaving land as forest can reduce overall investment costs and management complexity of a farm portfolio, while the inclusion of pasture helps maintain liquidity. This speaks for promoting agroforestry not as a stand alone land-use option, but as a potential complement to other land-use systems as part of a diversified farm portfolio.

The optimal farm compositions derived from our modelling approach assumes that the 10 socio-economic and ecological objectives are equally important for farmers’ decision-making. While this is unlikely to be the case for an individual farmer, the assumption is appropriate for modelling the decision-making of a whole group of farmers, whose individual preferences and constraints are uncertain. This is a situation policy-makers often face. We account for potential variation in farmers’ priorities by including a broader set of plausible objectives in the optimisation, which we weigh equally. The similarity between the existing and optimised land-use portfolios when excluding agroforestry vouches for the plausibility of model results, supporting our decision to weigh objectives equally.

Despite its normative nature, we found the model allows for a plausible representation of land-use trends, which Knoke et al. (2020) also demonstrated in a recent Ecuadorian case study. For instance, the expansion of forest cover in the optimised portfolios relative to the existing forest cover in our study area is consistent with forest transition theory, which has already been observed in Panama (Wright and Samaniego 2008). We also obtained more diversified land-use portfolios at higher levels of uncertainty, consistent with other applications of the model in Latin America (Knoke et al. 2016; Uhde et al. 2017). Finally, we obtained more diversified land compositions when considering multiple criteria in the optimisation compared to a single objective only, a trend which van der Plas et al. (2016) have shown empirically at the landscape scale.

We recognise that our results stem from a small dataset, where not all farmers had prior knowledge of the agroforestry systems in question. We tried to ensure a common understanding among all farmers by discussing each land-use before starting the evaluation task, but some farmer responses may still be “guesstimates”. Other authors promote similar ranking and scoring methods for collecting high quality data from local people (Mayoux and Chambers 2005; Riley and Fielding 2001), but we also acknowledge the inherent uncertainty around the degree to which data accurately and consistently capture farmers’ opinions (Gosling and Reith 2019). This, however, highlights a strength of our modelling approach which actively integrates uncertainty around farmer judgement and preferences in the optimisation. The measure of uncertainty used in the model (SEMi,l,f) reflects variation in farmer opinion. We would expect this variation to increase when farmers are less sure of their responses, but also when sample sizes are small (Eqs. 2 and 4). The model accounts for this potential variation via the uncertainty scenarios, searching for solutions that are satisfactory for a wide range of land-use scores (Knoke et al. 2016). This results in a land-use composition that caters for a range of farmer opinions, and hence should be acceptable to all farmers comprising a farm type. Nevertheless, if sample sizes are too small (or reliability of the data too poor) the strong diversification effects resulting from high standard errors may mask potential differences between groups. We addressed this issue by using a relative standard error, but future research could investigate minimum sample sizes needed to achieve stable land-use portfolios.

Potential applications

Our data collection method represents a rapid appraisal tool (Riley and Fielding 2001), and when faced with small or uncertain datasets the model actively accounts for potential variation in farmer opinion. We therefore see it as a pragmatic approach to guide land-use planning and agroforestry policy decisions in regions where it may not be possible to carry out large-scale household surveys. In this context the optimisation approach is not designed to prescribe exact “ideal” farm compositions to be implemented by different groups of farmers, but instead to explore the conditions under which agroforestry might be a desirable complement to meet farmers’ goals.

As an example application, practitioners could use our survey method to capture farmers’ knowledge and perceptions of agroforestry during the development of incentive schemes and extension programs. We used cluster analysis to identify farms with similar land-use and income patterns, but farmers could also be grouped using much simpler methods (e.g. based on farm size, income level or the main farm enterprise). Understanding if and how perceptions deviate between different farmer groups could help policy-makers to prioritise further data collection and farmer collaboration. For instance, the inclusion of agroforestry systems in the optimal portfolio of a particular group of farmers suggests that the systems could be of interest to those farmers. More data could then be collected from such groups to better understand their constraints and the support needed to adopt agroforestry.

Our modelling approach could also be relevant for participatory land-use planning as a discussion tool to support strategic thinking about sustainable land-use compositions (Le Gal et al. 2013). Stakeholders could evaluate the pros and cons of different land-use compositions and generate a range of solutions by modifying the importance (weight) placed on each objective (Stewart et al. 2004). Ezquerro et al. (2019), for example, have shown how a similar modelling method can be used for stakeholder interaction in forest management. Our model is well suited to user interaction because it works off-line with open source software and short calculation times (for our problem less than 2 s per optimisation). This makes it possible to re-run the optimisation with altered parameters in situ, to facilitate a co-learning feedback loop between the researcher and farmer. In such a process the approach could be extended by including individual farm constraints that are not yet captured in the optimisation model.

Finally, the optimisation method can easily accommodate diverse data types, including measured, modelled and interview data (Knoke et al. 2016; Uhde et al. 2017). This creates an opportunity to bring together different sources of knowledge in land-use planning. For example, farmers’ experienced-based knowledge (Turnhout et al. 2012), could be coupled with scientific data on ecological functions of different systems, such as their contribution to biodiversity and other ecosystem services. An optimisation incorporating these different perspectives could determine the ideal land-use composition at the landscape level. Such an approach could be used to investigate the role of agroforestry in multi-functional landscapes that enhance ecosystem services while accounting for farmers’ needs and preferences.

Conclusions

By coupling empiric interview data of farmers in Eastern Panama with a mechanistic optimisation model, we demonstrate a new approach for investigating the potential of agroforestry to meet the multiple needs of different groups of farmers. We found that the type and share of agroforestry included in theoretically optimal land-use portfolios differed for farms with different land-use and income characteristics. Such differences can provide valuable information about the possible acceptability of different agroforestry systems among different groups of farmers. In our case study, for example, we found that farmers who derive most of their farm income from crops may be more willing to adopt silvopasture, whereas farmers who are more economically dependent on cattle may benefit from diversifying their land-use with alley cropping. We found that in our study region agroforestry (especially silvopasture) does not appear to conflict with farmers’ general land-use preferences, but divergence between the optimal and current land-use portfolios suggest that hidden constraints not reflected in these preferences may hinder agroforestry adoption. Single-objective optimisations reveal that aspects such as reducing investment costs and management complexity and the need to maintain liquidity may be among these constraints. This speaks for the importance of promoting agroforestry as part of a diversified land-use portfolio to help buffer farm-level constraints. Such insights were revealed with comparably low measurement effort, and thus the coupled empiric-normative approach may be an important starting point for policy-makers and scientists to set priorities for follow-up research on policy design. We test the modelling approach in Eastern Panama, but think it could be easily transferred to other regions to better understand the socio-economic conditions under which agroforestry may be a desirable land-use alternative to meet farmers’ needs.