Skip to main content
Log in

Bounds for path-dependent options

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Annals of Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We develop new semiparametric bounds on the expected payoffs and prices of European call options and a wide range of path-dependent contingent claims. We first focus on the trinomial financial market model in which, as is well-known, an exact calculation of derivative prices based on no-arbitrage arguments is impossible. We show that the expected payoff of a European call option in the trinomial model with martingale-difference log-returns is bounded from above by the expected payoff of a call option written on an asset with i.i.d. symmetric two-valued log-returns. We further show that the expected payoff of a European call option in the multiperiod trinomial option pricing model is bounded by the expected payoff of a call option in the two-period model with a log-normal asset price. We also obtain bounds on the possible prices of call options in the (incomplete) trinomial model in terms of the parameters of the asset’s distribution. Similar bounds also hold for many other contingent claims in the trinomial option pricing model, including those with an arbitrary convex increasing payoff function as well as for path-dependent ones such as Asian options. We further obtain a wide range of new semiparametric moment bounds on the expected payoffs and prices of path-dependent Asian options with an arbitrary distribution of the underlying asset’s price. These results are based on recently obtained sharp moment inequalities for sums of multilinear forms and U-statistics and provide their first financial and economic applications in the literature. Similar bounds also hold for many other path-dependent contingent claims.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In fact, Grundy (1991) notes that the problem can be inverted and estimates bounds on the parameters of the assumed distribution can be inferred from the bounds using observed prices.

  2. The expectation is taken with respect to the true probability measure P.

  3. As discussed in Jagannathan (1984) and Rodriguez (2003), this result depends critically on the Rothschild and Stiglitz (1970) definition of risk orderings. Grundy (1991) provides an example in which the expected return on the option is less than the risk-free rate; however the condition \(dC(S)/dS<0\) in his example conflicts with theoretical models and empirical findings, see Rodriguez (2003).

  4. The analysis of preferences over payoff distributions and the effects of skewness and other higher moments (e.g., kurtosis) in this framework may also relate to applications of majorization theory (see Marshall et al. 2011) and heavy-tailed distributions (see, among others Embrechts et al. 1997; Gabaix 2008; Ibragimov 2009; Ibragimov et al. 2015; Ibragimov and Prokhorov 2016).

References

  • Barberis, N., Huang, M.: Stocks as lotteries: the implications of probability weighting for security prices. Am. Econ. Rev. 98, 2006–2100 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyle, P.B., Lin, X.S.: Bounds on contingent claims based on several assets. J. Financ. Econ. 46, 383–400 (1997)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyle, P.P.: A lattice framework for option pricing wuth two state variables. J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 23, 1–12 (1988)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broadie, M., Detemple, J.: American option valuation: new bounds, approximations, and a comparison of existing methods. Rev. Finan. Stud. 9, 1211–1250 (1996)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broadie, M., Detemple, J.B.: Option pricing: valuation models and applications. Manag. Sci. 50, 1145–1177 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Constantinides, G., Zariphopoulou, T.: Bounds on derivative prices in an intertemporal setting with proportional transaction costs and multiple securities. Math. Finance 11, 331–346 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, J., Ross, S., Rubinstein, M.: Option pricing: a simplified approach. J. Financ. Econ. 7, 229–263 (1979)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de la Peña, V.H., Giné, E.: Decoupling: From Dependence to Independence, Probability and its Applications. Springer, New York (1999)

  • de la Peña, V.H., Ibragimov, R., Jordan, S.: Option bounds. J. Appl. Probab. 41A, 145–156 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de la Peña, V.H., Ibragimov, R. , Sharakhmetov, S.: Characterizations of joint distributions, copulas, information, dependence and decoupling, with applications to time series. In: Rojo, J. (ed.) 2nd Erich L. Lehmann Symposium—Optimality, IMS Lecture Notes, Monograph Series’, vol. 49, pp. 183–209. Institute of Mathematical Statistics, Beachwood, Ohio (2006)

  • de la Peña, V.P., Ibragimov, R., Sharakhmetov, S.: On sharp Burkholder–Rosenthal-type inequalities for infinite-degree \(U\)-statistics. Annales de l’Institute H. Poincaré-Probabilités et Statistiques 38, 973–990 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de la Peña, V.P., Ibragimov, R., Sharakhmetov, S.: On extremal distributions and sharp \(L_p-\)bounds for sums of multilinear forms. Ann. Probab. 31, 630–675 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eaton, M.L.: A probability inequality for linear combinations of bounded random variables. Ann. Stat. 2, 609–614 (1974)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edelman, D.: An inequality of optimal order for the tail probabilities of the \(T\) statistic under symmetry. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 85, 120–122 (1990)

    Google Scholar 

  • Embrechts, P., Klüuppelberg, C., Mikosch, T.: Modelling Extremal Events for Insurance and Finance. Springer, New York (1997)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, R., Sin, C.: Bounds on European option prices under stochastic volatility. Math. Finance 9, 97–116 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gabaix, X.: Power laws. In: Durlauf, S.N., Blume, L.E. (eds.) The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd edn. Palgrave Macmillan, London (2008)

    Google Scholar 

  • Grundy, B.D.: Option prices and the underlying asset’s return distribution. J. Finance 46, 1045–1069 (1991)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoeffding, W.: The extrema of the expected value of a function of independent random variables. Ann. Math. Stat. 26, 268–276 (1955)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ibragimov, M., Ibragimov, R., Walden, J.: Heavy-tailed distributions and robustness in economics and finance. Lecture Notes in Statistics, vol. 214. Springer (2015)

  • Ibragimov, R.: Heavy-tailed densities. In: Durlauf, S.N., Blume, L.E. (eds.) The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online. Palgrave Macmillan. (2009). http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2009_H000191

  • Ibragimov, R., Prokhorov, A.: Topics on Stochastic Ordering, Majorization and Dependence Modelling in Economics and Finance. World Scientific Publishing & Imperial College Press, Singapore. Forthcoming (2016)

  • Ibragimov, R., Sharakhmetov, S., Cecen, A.: Exact estimates for moments of random bilinear forms. J. Theor. Probab. 14, 21–37 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jagannathan, R.: Call options and the risk of underlying securities. J. Financ. Econ. 13, 425–434 (1984)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamrad, B., Ritchken, P.: Multinomial approximating models for options with \(k\) state variables. Manag. Sci. 37, 1640–1652 (1991)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karr, A.: Extreme points of certain sets of probability measures, with applications. Math. Oper. Res. 8, 74–85 (1983)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lo, A.W.: Semi-parametric upper bounds for option prices and expected payoffs. J. Financ. Econ. 19, 373–387 (1987)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A.W., Olkin, I., Arnold, B.C.: Inequalities: Theory of Majorization and its Applications, 2nd edn. Springer, New York (2011)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R.C.: Theory of rational option pricing. Bell J. Econ. 4, 141–183 (1973)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parkinson, M.: Option pricing: American put. J. Bus. 50, 21–36 (1977)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perrakis, S.: Option bounds in discrete time: extensions and the price of the American put. J. Bus. 59, 119–142 (1986)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perrakis, S., Ryan, P.J.: Option pricing bounds in discrete time. J. Finance 39, 519–525 (1984)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ritchken, P., Trevor, R.: Pricing options under generalized GARCH and stochastic volatility processes. J. Finance 54, 377–402 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodriguez, R.J.: Option pricing bounds: synthesis and extension. J. Financ. Res. 26, 149–164 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothschild, M., Stiglitz, J.E.: Increasing risk: I. A definition. J. Econ. Theory 2, 225–243 (1970)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scarf, H.: A min-max solution of an inventory problem. In: Arrow, K.J., Karlin, S., Scarf, H. (eds.) Studies in the Mathematical Theory of Inventory and Production. Stanford University Press, California (1958)

    Google Scholar 

  • Scarf, H.: Inventory theory. Oper. Res. 50, 186–191 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sharakhmetov, S., Ibragimov, R.: A characterization of joint distribution of two-valued random variables and its applications. J. Multivar. Anal. 83, 389–408 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, S., Goovaerts, M.J., Dhaene, J.: An easy computable upper bound for the price of an arithmetic Asian option. Insur. Math. Econ. 26, 175–183 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rustam Ibragimov.

Additional information

We thank the Risk Management Institute at the National University of Singapore and the International Center for Finance (ICF) at the School of Management (SOM) at Yale University for support. Ibragimov’s work on the final version of the paper was completed when he was visiting Innopolis University and Kazan Federal University-KFU (Kazan, Russia). He gratefully acknowledges partial support from the Russian Ministry of Education and Science (Innopolis University) and the Russian Government Program of Competitive Growth of Kazan Federal University (Higher Institute of Information Technologies and Information Systems, KFU).

Appendix: Probabilistic foundations for the analysis

Appendix: Probabilistic foundations for the analysis

Let \((\Omega , \mathfrak {I}, P)\) be a probability space equipped with a filtration \(\mathfrak {I}_0=(\Omega , \emptyset )\subseteq \mathfrak {I}_1\subseteq \ldots \mathfrak {I}_t\subseteq \ldots \subseteq \mathfrak {I}.\) Further, let \((a_t)_{t=1}^{\infty }\) and \((b_t)_{t=1}^{\infty }\) be arbitrary sequences of real numbers such that \(a_t\ne b_t\) for all t.

The key to the analysis in Sects. 2 and 3 is provided by the following theorems. These theorems are consequences of more general results obtained in Sharakhmetov and Ibragimov (2002) that show that r.v.’s taking \(k+1\) values form a multiplicative system of order k if and only if they are jointly independent (see also de la Peña et al. 2006). These results imply, in particular, that r.v.’s each taking two values form a martingale-difference sequence if and only if they are jointly independent.

To illustrate the main ideas of the proof, we first consider the case of r.v.’s taking values \(\pm 1\).

Theorem 6.1

If r.v.’s \(U_t\), \(t=1, 2, \ldots ,\) form a martingale-difference sequence with respect to a filtration \((\mathfrak {I}_t)_t\) and are such that \(P(U_t=1)=P(U_t=-1)=\frac{1}{2}\) for all t,  then they are jointly independent.

For completeness, the proof of the theorem is provided below.

Proof

It is easy to see that, under the assumptions of the theorem, one has that, for all \(1\le l_1<l_2<\cdots <l_k\), \(k=2, 3, \ldots ,\)

$$\begin{aligned} EU_{l_1}\ldots U_{l_{k-1}}U_{l_k}=E\left( U_{l_1}\ldots U_{l_{k-1}}E(U_{l_k}|\mathfrak {I}_{l_k-1})\right) =E\left( U_{l_1}\ldots U_{l_{k-1}}\times 0\right) =0.\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(6.1)

It is easy to see that, for \(x_t\in \{-1, 1\}\), \(I(X_t=x_t)=(1+x_tU_t)/2.\) Consequently, for all \(1\le j_1<j_2<\cdots <j_m\), \(m=2, 3, \ldots ,\) and any \(x_{j_k}\in \{-1, 1\}\), \(k=1, 2, \ldots , m,\) we have

$$\begin{aligned}&P(U_{j_1}=x_{j_1}, U_{j_2}=x_{j_2}, \ldots , U_{j_m}=x_{j_m})\\\\&\quad = EI(U_{j_1}=x_{j_1})I(U_{j_2}=x_{j_2})\ldots I( U_{j_m}=x_{j_m}) \\&\quad =\frac{1}{2^m} E(1+x_{j_1}U_{j_1})(1+x_{j_2}U_{j_2})\ldots (1+x_{j_m}U_{j_m})\\&\quad =\frac{1}{2^m} \left( 1+\sum _{c=2}^m \sum _{i_1<\cdots <i_c\in \{j_1, j_2, \ldots , j_m\}} EU_{i_1}\ldots U_{i_c}\right) = \frac{1}{2^m}\\&\quad =P(U_{j_1}=x_{j_1})P(U_{j_2}=x_{j_2}) \ldots P(U_{j_m}=x_{j_m}) \end{aligned}$$

by (6.1). \(\square \)

The proof of the analogue of the result in the case of r.v.’s each of which takes arbitrary two values is completely similar and the following more general result holds.

Theorem 6.2

If r.v.’s \(X_t\), \(t=1, 2, \ldots ,\) form a martingale-difference sequence with respect to a filtration \((\mathfrak {I}_t)_t\) and each of them takes two (not necessarily the same for all t) values \(\{a_t, b_t\}\), then they are jointly independent.

Proof

Let the r.v. \(X_t\) take the values \(a_t\) and \(b_t\), \(a_t\ne b_t,\) with probabilities \(P(X_t=a_t)=p_t\) and \(P(X_t=b_t)=q_t,\) respectively. It not difficult to check that, for \(x_t\in \{a_t, b_t\},\)

$$\begin{aligned} I(X_t=x_t)= & {} P(X_t=x_t)\left( 1+\frac{(X_t-a_tp_t-b_tq_t)(x_t-a_tp_t-b_tq_t)}{(a_t-b_t)^2p_tq_t}\right) \\= & {} P(X_t=x_t)\left( 1+\frac{(X_t-EX_t)(x_t-EX_t)}{(a_t-b_t)^2p_tq_t}\right) \\= & {} P(X_t=x_t)\left( 1+\frac{X_tx_t}{(a_t-b_t)^2p_tq_t}\right) =P(X_t=x_t)\left( 1+\frac{X_tx_t}{Var(X_t)}\right) , \end{aligned}$$

where \(EX_t=a_tp_t+b_tq_t=0\) and \(Var(X_t)=(b_t-a_t)^2p_tq_t\) are the mean and the variance of \(X_t.\) Since the r.v.’s \(X_t\) satisfy property (6.1) with \(U_{l_j}\) replaced by \(X_{l_j}\), \(j=1, \ldots , k\), similar to the proof of Theorem 6.1 we have that, for all \(1\le j_1<j_2<\cdots <j_m\), \(m=2, 3, \ldots ,\) and any \(x_{j_k}\in \{a_{j_k}, b_{j_k}\}\), \(k=1, 2, \ldots , m,\)

$$\begin{aligned}&P(X_{j_1}=x_{j_1}, X_{j_2}=x_{j_2}, \ldots , X_{j_m}=x_{j_m})\\&\quad = EI(X_{j_1}=x_{j_1})I(X_{j_2}=x_{j_2})\ldots I( X_{j_m}=x_{j_m})\\&\quad =\prod _{s=1}^m P(X_{j_s}=x_{j_s}) E\left( 1+\frac{X_{j_1}x_{j_1}}{Var(X_{j_1 })}\right) \ldots \left( 1+\frac{X_{j_m}x_{j_m}}{Var(X_{j_m})}\right) \\&\quad =\prod _{s=1}^m P(X_{j_s}=x_{j_s})\\&\qquad \times \left( 1+\sum _{c=2}^m \sum _{i_1<\cdots <i_c\in \{j_1, j_2, \ldots , j_m\}} EX_{i_1}\ldots X_{i_c}x_{i_1} \ldots x_{i_c}/(Var(X_{i_1})\ldots Var(X_{i_c})) \right) \\&\quad = P(X_{j_1}=x_{j_1})P(X_{j_2}=x_{j_2}) \ldots P(X_{j_m}=x_{j_m}). \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Let \(X_t\), \(t=1, 2, \ldots ,\) be an \((\mathfrak {I}_t)\)-martingale-difference sequence consisting of r.v.’s each of which takes three values \(\{-a_t, 0, a_t\}.\) Denote by \(\epsilon _t\), \(t=1, 2, \ldots ,\) a sequence of i.i.d. symmetric Bernoulli r.v.’s independent of \((X_t)_{t=1}^{\infty }.\) The following theorem provides an upper bound for the expectation of arbitrary convex function of \(X_t\) in terms of the expectation of the same function of the r.v.’s \(\epsilon _t.\)

Theorem 6.3

If \(f:\mathbf{R}^n\rightarrow \mathbf{R}\) is a function convex in each of its arguments, then the following inequality holds:

$$\begin{aligned} Ef(X_1, \ldots , X_n)\le Ef(a_1\epsilon _1, \ldots , a_n\epsilon _n). \end{aligned}$$
(6.2)

Proof

Let \({\tilde{\mathfrak {I}}}_0=\mathfrak {I}_n.\) For \(t=1, 2, \ldots , n,\) denote by \({\tilde{\mathfrak {I}}}_t\) the \(\sigma \)-algebra spanned by the r.v.’s \(X_1, X_2, \ldots , X_n\), \( \epsilon _1, \ldots , \epsilon _t.\) Further, let, for \(t=0, 1, \ldots , n\), \(E_{t}\) stand for the conditional expectation operator \(E(\cdot |{\tilde{\mathfrak {I}}}_t)\) and let \(\eta _t\), \(t=1, \ldots , n,\) denote the r.v.’s \(\eta _t=X_t+\epsilon _tI(X_t=0).\)

Using conditional Jensen’s inequality, we have

$$\begin{aligned} Ef(X_1, X_2, \ldots , X_n)= & {} Ef(X_1+E_0[\epsilon _1I(X_1=0)], X_2, \ldots , X_n)\nonumber \\\le & {} E[E_0f(X_1+\epsilon _1I(X_1=0), X_2, \ldots , X_n)]\nonumber \\= & {} Ef(\eta _1, X_2, \ldots , X_n). \end{aligned}$$
(6.3)

Similarly, for \(t=2, \ldots , n,\)

$$\begin{aligned}&Ef(\eta _1, \eta _2, \ldots , \eta _{t-1}, X_t, X_{t+1}, \ldots , X_n) \nonumber \\&\quad =Ef(\eta _1, \eta _2, \ldots , \eta _{t-1}, X_t+E_{t-1}[\epsilon _tI(X_t=0)], X_{t+1}, \ldots , X_n) \nonumber \\&\quad \le E[E_{t-1}f(\eta _1, \eta _2, \ldots , \eta _{t-1}, X_t+\epsilon _tI(X_t=0), X_{t+1}, \ldots , X_n)]\nonumber \\&\quad =Ef(\eta _1, \eta _2, \ldots , \eta _{t-1}, \eta _t, X_{t+1}, \ldots , X_n). \end{aligned}$$
(6.4)

From equations (6.3) and (6.4) by induction it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} Ef(X_1, X_2, \ldots , X_n)\le Ef(\eta _1, \eta _2, \ldots , \eta _n). \end{aligned}$$
(6.5)

It is easy to see that the r.v.’s \(\eta _t\), \(t=1, 2, \ldots , n,\) form a martingale-difference sequence with respect to the sequence of \(\sigma \)-algebras \({\tilde{\mathfrak {I}}}_0\subseteq {\tilde{\mathfrak {I}}}_1\subseteq \cdots \subseteq {\tilde{\mathfrak {I}}}_t \subseteq \cdots ,\) and each of them takes two values \(\{-a_t, a_t\}.\) Therefore, from Theorems 6.1 and 6.2 we get that \(\eta _t\), \(t=1, 2, \ldots , n,\) are jointly independent and, therefore, the random vector \((\eta _1, \eta _2, \ldots , \eta _n)\) has the same distribution as \((a_1\epsilon _1, a_2\epsilon _2, \ldots , a_n\epsilon _n).\) This and (6.5) implies estimate (6.2). \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Brown, D.J., Ibragimov, R. & Walden, J. Bounds for path-dependent options. Ann Finance 11, 433–451 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10436-015-0265-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10436-015-0265-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation