Skip to main content
Log in

IPO activity and information in secondary market prices

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Annals of Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper explores the link between IPO underpricing and financial markets. In my model the IPO is a mean for a capital constrained initial investor to exit and thereby to raise funds for a new investment opportunity. This investor is privately informed vis-a-vis outside investors about the profitability of the new opportunity and the quality of the firm to be offered in the IPO. He can then use the offer price and the fraction of shares sold as signals of his private information. The model shows that underpricing is not only linked to firm’s characteristics, i.e. firm value, but to elements external to the firm, i.e. new investment profitability and financial markets characteristics. In particular higher market efficiency reduces the cost of listing. This results in lower underpricing and the listing of more valuable firm. Similarly, a higher lower bound of the new investment’s profitability reduces the information asymmetry and hence reduces underpricing and widens the range of firms listed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The results can easily be extended to the case where the owner holds a fraction of the firm.

  2. No agency problems between the initial owner and manager are considered. Rossetto (2008) deals with this case in a simplified framework.

  3. There is also a large difference between the cost of obtaining listing across exchanges, which can have an indirect effect on the size of firms that may wish to list on a given exchange.

  4. Fu (2002) and Gilson et al (2001) find, for example, that the higher the amount of shares floated during a carve out, the higher is the analyst coverage and the lower is the information asymmetry.

  5. The concavity of the relationship is plausible, for example, when trading profits are linear in the size of the float, but information production costs convex in information precision. The precise functional form would, of course, depend on the specific microstructure model. Fully endogenizing this relationship goes beyond the scope of this paper.

  6. This result is not driven by the assumption that \(\tau \) is concave in \(\beta \). It is due to the effect of the endogenous concave effect of the probability on the cost of signalling. In fact the results hold when the probability of firm value’s revelation with the shares tendered is linear, i.e. \(n=1\).

References

  • Allen, F., Faulhaber, G.R.: Signalling by underpricing in the ipo market. J Financial Econ 23(2), 303–323 (1989)

    Google Scholar 

  • Benveniste, L.M., Spindt, P.A.: How investment bankers determine the offer price and allocation of new issues. J Financial Econ 24(2), 343–361 (1989)

    Google Scholar 

  • Benveniste, L.M., Ljungqvist, A.P., Wilhelm, W.J., Yu, X.: Evidence of information spillovers in the production of investment banking services. J Finance 58(2), 577–608 (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Biais, B., Mariotti, T.: Strategic liquidity supply and security design. Rev Econ Stud 72(3), 615–649 (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Biais, B., Glosten, L., Spatt, C.: Market microstructure: a survey of microfoundations, empirical results, and policy implications. J Financial Mark 8(2), 217–264 (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, B.S., Gilson, R.J.: Venture capital and the structure of capital markets: bank versus stock market. J Financial Econ 47(3), 243–277 (1998)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, P., von Thadden, E.L.: Blocks, liquidity, and corporate control. J Finance 53(1), 1–25 (1998)

    Google Scholar 

  • van Bommel, J.: Messages from market to management: the case of ipos. J Corp Finance 8(2), 123–138 (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  • Choe, H., Masulis, R., Nanda, V.: Common stock offerings across the business cycle: theory and evidence. J Empir Finance 1(1), 3–31 (1993)

    Google Scholar 

  • DeMarzo, P., Duffie, D.: A liquidity-based model of security design. Econometrica 67(1), 65–99 (1999)

    Google Scholar 

  • Engers, M.: Signalling with many signals. Econometrica 55(3), 663–674 (1987)

    Google Scholar 

  • Fu H (2002) Information asymmetry and the market reaction to equity carve-outs, unpublished manuscript.

  • Gilson, S.C., Healy, P.M., Noe, C.F., Palepu, K.G.: Analyst specialization and conglomerate stock breakups. J Acc Res 39(3), 565–582 (2001)

    Google Scholar 

  • Grinblatt, M., Hwang, C.H.: Signalling and the pricing of new issues. J Finance 44(2), 393–420 (1989)

    Google Scholar 

  • Helwege, J., Liang, N.: Initial public offerings in hot and cold markets. J Financial Quant Anal 39(3), 541–569 (2004)

    Google Scholar 

  • Ibbotson, R., Ritter, J.R.: Initial public offerings. In: Jarrow, R., Maksimovic, V., Ziemba, W. (eds.) Handbooks of Operations Research and Management Science. North-Holland, Amsterdam (1995)

    Google Scholar 

  • Jenkinson, T., Ljungqvist, A.: Going Public: The Theory and Evidence on How Companies Raise Equity Finance. Oxford University Press, Oxford (2001)

    Google Scholar 

  • Leland, H.E., Pyle, D.H.: Informational asymmetries, financial structure, and financial intermediation. J Finance 32(2), 371–387 (1977). Papers and Proceedings of the Thirty-Fifth Annual Meeting of the American Finance Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ljungqvist, A.: IPO Underpricing: A Survey. Handbook of Corporate Finance. New York: Elsevier (2007)

  • Ljungqvist, A.P., Nanda, V., Singh, R.: Hot markets, investor sentiment, and ipo pricing. J Bus 79(4), 1667–1703 (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  • Loughran, T., Ritter, J.R.: Why don’t issuers get upset about leaving money on the table in ipos. Rev Financial Stud 15(2), 413–443 (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  • Lowry, M.: Why does ipo volume fluctuate so much? J Financial Econ 67(1), 3–40 (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Milne, F., Ritzberger, K.: Strategic pricing of equity issues. Econ Theory 20(2), 271–294 (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  • Pagano, M.: Endogenous market thinness and stock price volatility. Rev Econ Stud 56(2), 269–287 (1989)

    Google Scholar 

  • Pagano, M., Panetta, F., Zingales, L.: Why do companies go public? an empirical analysis. J Finance 53(1), 27–64 (1998)

    Google Scholar 

  • Pástor, Veronesi P.: Rational ipo waves. J Finance 60(4), 1713–1757 (2005)

    Google Scholar 

  • Quinzii, M., Rochet, J.C.: Multidimensional signalling. J Math Econ 14(3), 261–284 (1985)

    Google Scholar 

  • Rajan, R., Servaes, H.: Analyst following of initial public offerings. J Finance 52(2), 507–529 (1997)

    Google Scholar 

  • Riley, J.G.: Informational equilibrium. Econometrica 47(2), 331–360 (1979)

    Google Scholar 

  • Ritter, J.R.: The hot issue market of 1980. J Bus 57(2), 215–240 (1984)

    Google Scholar 

  • Rock, K.: Why new issues are underpriced. J Financial Econ 15(1–2), 187–212 (1986)

    Google Scholar 

  • Rossetto, S.: The price of rapid exit in venture-backed IPOs. Ann Finance 4(1), 29–53 (2008)

    Google Scholar 

  • Subrahmanyam, A., Titman, S.: The going-public decision and the development of financial markets. J Finance 54(3), 1045–1082 (1999)

    Google Scholar 

  • Welch, I.: Seasoned offerings, imitation costs, and the underpricing of initial public offerings. J Finance 44(2), 421–449 (1989)

    Google Scholar 

  • Welch, I., Ritter, J.: A review of ipo activity, pricing, and allocations. J Finance 57(4), 1795–1828 (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  • Zingales, L.: Insider ownership and the decision to go public. Rev Econ Stud 62(212), 425–448 (1995)

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I am grateful to Alexander Gümbel, Dimitrios Tsomocos and Lucy White for helpful comments and discussions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Silvia Rossetto.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Proposition 1

Proof

The proof proceeds in three steps: \((a)\quad \pi \equiv \pi _L;\;(b)\quad \pi \ge \pi _L;\;(c)\) The verification of the conditions under which a unique Pareto dominant reactive equilibrium exists

Part 1: \(\pi =\pi _{L}\). The initial owner has no reason to incur any underpricing since the investors cannot form a belief over \(\pi \) worse than the true \(\pi =\pi _{L}\). The problem reduces then to a one-dimensional signalling problem. Hence, the initial owner signals the firm value by limiting the amount of shares sold. Define with \(V_{\pi _{L}}\left(\beta \right)\) the signalling schedule, that is the investors’ beliefs on firm value, observing \(\beta \) and knowing that \(\pi =\pi _{L}\).

The owner chooses \(\beta \) to maximize his objective function (1) taking into consideration how \(\beta \) affects outside investors’ beliefs. The first order condition is

$$\begin{aligned} -\tau V+(\pi _{L}-1+\tau )V_{\pi _{L}}\left(\beta \right) +(\beta (\pi _{L}-1)+1-\tau (1-\beta ))V^{\prime }_{\pi _{L}}\left(\beta \right)=0 \end{aligned}$$
(15)

Imposing the self-fulfilling belief condition \(V_{\pi =\pi _{L}}\left(\beta \right) =V\) gives a family of informationally consistent signalling sets. Imposing the condition that \(V\left[1\left|\pi =\pi _{L}\right.\right]=L\) gives the Pareto optimal set. This can be seen noticing that schedules where \(V_{\pi =\pi _{L}}\left(1\right) >L\) allow for arbitrage for the owner: the owner who owns a firm whose value is \(L\), could sell all his shares for \(V_{\pi =\pi _{L}}\left(1\right)\) and make a profit for \(V_{\pi =\pi _{L}}\left(1\right)-L\). Those where \(V_{\pi =\pi _{L}}\left(1\right)<L\) are Pareto dominated by \(V_{\pi =\pi _{L}}\left(1\right)=L\) as in this case the investor receives higher proceeds to reinvest. This gives Eq. () which is the informationally consistent Pareto-dominant signalling set.

Part 2: \(\pi \ge \pi _{L}\). The owner chooses the underpricing such that his wealth is maximized taking into account that \(\pi \) is not known to outside investors. So he chooses \(P\) taking into account the effect on the beliefs about firm value, \(V[P,\beta ]\):

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{P}\beta \pi P+\left(1-\beta \right)\left(\tau V+\left(1-\tau \right)V\left[P,\beta \right]\right) \end{aligned}$$
(16)

again \(V\left[V,\beta \right]=V_{\pi _{L}}\left(\beta \right)\) is required in order to have the Pareto dominant schedule. As in Part 1 if \(V\left[V,\beta \right]>V_{\pi _{L}}\left(\beta \right)\) there are arbitrage opportunities for the owner, while the schedule \(V\left[V,\beta \right]<V_{\pi _{L}}\left(\beta \right)\) is Pareto dominated. This gives:

$$\begin{aligned} V[P,\beta ]=\frac{1}{1-A}V_{\pi _{L}}\left(\beta \right)+ \frac{A}{1-A}P \end{aligned}$$
(17)

where

$$\begin{aligned} A=\frac{\beta \pi }{\left(1-\tau \right)\left(1-\beta \right)+\beta \pi } \le 1 \end{aligned}$$

Second, \(\beta \) is chosen such that wealth is maximized given Eq. () and such that the resulting schedule is both informationally consistent and Pareto efficient, i.e. \(V[P,\beta ]=V\) and \(P=V\) when \(\pi =\pi _{L}\). This gives:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi =\pi _{L}+\tau \left(\frac{V}{V_{\pi _{L}}(\beta )}-1\right) \end{aligned}$$
(18)

Solving the system of Eqs. (17) and (18) for \(\beta \) and \(P\), yields (5) and (6).

The second order condition is satisfied as it is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} 2(\pi _{L}-1)V^{\prime }_{\pi _{L}}(\beta )+(1-r-\beta +\beta \pi _{L}) V^{\prime \prime }_{\pi _{L}}(\beta ) \end{aligned}$$

Part 3. Engers (1987) has shown that a sufficient condition of uniqueness is that the marginal cost of the signal is decreasing and convex in the value of the firm. Since this is the case here, we have that the above set is the only separating equilibrium set.

The signalling schedule (5) and (6) is Pareto dominant among all the separating equilibria. When \(\pi =\pi _{L}\), there is no underpricing and hence \(P=V\) and the optimal schedule is given by (9). When \(\pi >\pi _{L}\) the price, and hence the underpricing, is chosen such that it maximizes the objective function of the investor.

As \(\beta >0\) this equilibrium exists only when condition (7) is satisfied. When \(\beta \le 0\), the owner does not take the firm public. When \(P=L\) a pooling equilibrium exists. Note that given the signalling schedule \(\beta \le 1\) and \(P\le V(\beta )\). \(\square \)

1.2 Proof of Corollary 1

Proof

The derivatives of Eqs. (5) and (6) with respect to \(V\) and \(\pi \), shows how \(P\) and \(\beta \) change with \(V\) and \(\pi \). \(\square \)

1.3 Proof of Proposition 2

Proof

As \(\delta =\frac{V-P}{P}\)

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\delta }{d\tau }=-\frac{V}{P^2}\frac{dP}{d\tau } \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dP}{d\tau }=\frac{dV_{\pi _{L}}(\beta )}{d\tau }\left(1+\frac{(1-\tau )(1-\beta )}{\beta \tau }\right)+ \left(V-V_{\pi _{L}}(\beta )\right)\frac{1-\beta }{\beta \pi } \end{aligned}$$

Hence, the derivative is negative if \(\frac{\partial V_{\pi _{L}}(\beta )}{\partial \tau }>0\). This occurs when:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{L}+(\tau (\beta -1)+\beta (\pi _{L}-1)+1)\left(\ln \left(\frac{\tau (\beta -1)+\beta (\pi _{L}-1)+1}{\pi _{L}}\right)-1\right)>0 \end{aligned}$$

Define \(B=(1-\tau )(1-\beta )+\pi _{L}\beta \). Hence the above inequality can be rewritten as:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{L}+B\ln B-B\ln \pi _{L}-B>0 \end{aligned}$$

Rearranging:

$$\begin{aligned} -B\left(\ln \frac{\pi _{L}}{B}\right)+\left(\pi _{L}-B\right)>0 \end{aligned}$$

Because \(B=(1-\tau )(1-\beta )+\pi _{L}\beta <\pi _{L}\), the above inequality is always true. \(\square \)

1.4 Proof of Corollary 2

Proof

The derivative of the right hand side of condition (7) in respect to \(\tau \) is positive. \(\square \)

1.5 Proof of Corollary 3

Proof

Direct consequence of the study of the first derivative of conditions (7) and (8). \(\square \)

1.6 Proof of Proposition 3

Proof

The proof is structured in the following way. I show (1)\(\frac{d \beta }{d \pi _L}>0\); (2) \(\frac{d V_{\pi _{L}}(\beta )}{d \pi _L}>0\); (3) \(\frac{d \delta }{d \pi _L}>0\); (4) I analyze the effect of \(\pi _l\) on conditions (7) and (8).

Part 1: \(\frac{d \beta }{d \pi _L}<0\).

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d \beta }{d \pi _L}=\frac{-1+\tau -\pi _L (\pi _L-\tau +1) z^{\prime }(\pi _L)+(\tau -1) z(\pi _L)}{(\pi _L-\tau +1)^2}<0 \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} z(\pi _L)=h(\pi _{L})^k(\pi _{L}), \quad h(\pi _{L})=\frac{\tau }{\pi -\pi _{L}+\tau }\frac{V}{L} \quad k(\pi _{L})\frac{\pi _{L}-1+\tau }{\pi _{L}-1}{1-\tau +\pi _{L}} \end{aligned}$$

It can be easily seen that because \(z^{\prime }(\pi _L)>0\), \(\frac{d \beta }{d \pi _L}<0\).

Part 2: \(\frac{d V_{\pi _{L}}(\beta )}{d \pi _L}>0\).

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d V_{\pi _{L}}(\beta )}{d \pi _L}=\frac{\delta V_{\pi _{L}}(\beta )}{\delta \pi _L}+\frac{\delta V_{\pi _{L}}(\beta )}{\delta \beta }\frac{\delta \beta }{\delta \pi _L} \end{aligned}$$

From above I know that \(\frac{\delta V_{\pi _{L}}(\beta )}{\delta \beta }\frac{\delta \beta }{<}0\) and \(\frac{\delta \beta }{\delta \pi _L}>0\). I now look at \(\frac{\delta V_{\pi _{L}}(\beta )}{\delta \pi _L}\):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\delta V_{\pi =\pi _{L}}(\beta )}{\delta \pi _L}=V_{\pi =\pi _{L}}(\beta )\left[\frac{g(\pi _L) }{f(\pi _L)}f^{\prime }(\pi _L)+\log (f(\pi _L)) g^{\prime }(\pi _L)\right] \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} f(\pi _L)=\frac{\pi _{L}}{\left(1-\beta \right)\left(1-\tau \right)+\beta \pi _{L}}L\quad \text{ and} \quad g(\pi _L)=\frac{\pi _{L}-1}{\pi _{L}-1+\tau } \end{aligned}$$

It can be easily be seen that \(V_{\pi =\pi _{L}}(\beta )>0\), \(g(\pi _L)>0\), \(f(\pi _L)>1\) and \(g^{\prime }(\pi _L)>0\).

Part 3: \(\frac{d \delta }{d \pi _L}<0\).

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d \beta }{d \pi _L}=-\frac{V}{P^2} \frac{d P}{d \pi _L} \end{aligned}$$

where \(P\) is given by Eq. (6) and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d P}{d \pi _L}= \frac{d P}{d V_{\pi _{L}}(\beta )}\frac{d V_{\pi _{L}}(\beta )}{d \pi _L} \end{aligned}$$

From Part 1 \(\frac{d V_{\pi _{L}}(\beta )}{d \pi _L}\) and it can be easily seen that \(\frac{d P}{d V_{\pi _{L}}(\beta )}>0\).

Part 4: The boundary conditions.

I first study condition (7). The right hand side of this condition can be written as:

$$\begin{aligned} z(\pi _L)f(\pi _l)^{g(\pi _L)} \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} z(\pi _L)=\frac{\pi -\pi _L+\tau }{\tau }, \quad f(\pi _l)=\frac{1-\tau }{\pi _L} \quad \text{ and} \quad g(\pi _L)=\frac{\pi _L-1}{\pi _L-1+\tau }. \end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dz(\pi _L)f(\pi _l)^{g(\pi _L)}}{d \pi _L}&= z(\pi _L) f(\pi _L)^{g(\pi _L)} \left(\frac{g(\pi _L) f^{\prime }(\pi _L)}{f(\pi _L)}+\log (f(\pi _L)) g^{\prime }(\pi _L)\right)\\&+f(\pi _L)^{g(\pi _L)} z^{\prime }(\pi _L) \end{aligned}$$

As \(z(\pi _L)>0\), \(0<f(\pi _L)<1\), \(g(\pi _L)>0\), \(z^{\prime }(\pi _L)<0\), \(f^{\prime }(\pi _L)<0\) and \(g^{\prime }(\pi _L)>0\), \(\frac{dz(\pi _L)f(\pi _l)^{g(\pi _L)}}{d \pi _L}<0\).

I know study condition (8). Defining \(\iota (\pi _L)\) the right hand side of the condition we have that:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\iota (\pi _L)}{d \pi _L}=\frac{d\iota (\pi _L)}{d V_{\pi _{L}}(\beta )}\frac{V_{\pi _{L}}(\beta )}{d \pi _L}= -\frac{(1-\tau )(1-\beta )}{\beta }\frac{V-L}{(V_{\pi _{L}} (\beta )-L)^2}\frac{V_{\pi _{L}}(\beta )}{d \pi _L}<0 \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

1.7 Proof of Proposition 4

Proof

The proof follows the same steps as the proof of Proposition 1. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Rossetto, S. IPO activity and information in secondary market prices. Ann Finance 9, 667–687 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10436-012-0213-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10436-012-0213-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation