Skip to main content
Log in

Are business cycles in emerging market economies alike?

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
International Economics and Economic Policy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper explores the predictions of real business cycle theory on the roles of total factor productivity (TFP) and financial frictions to explain business cycles in emerging market economies (EMEs). I obtain evidence about TFP, price of capital, risk premium, and collateral constraint shocks by estimating structural vector autoregressions (SVARs) on a Brazilian sample from 1999Q1 to 2018Q4 and a Mexican sample from 1997Q1 to 2018Q4. On each sample, two SVARs are estimated. One SVAR identifies shocks by imposing restrictions on their short-run impact. The other SVAR is grounded on restrictions that shocks have long-run effects on business cycles in EMEs. Estimates of the SVARs show the TFP shock is the main driver of business cycle movements in Brazil and Mexico. However, this evidence is produced by the SVAR under the long-run restrictions, which indicates the identification of shocks matters to the explanation of business cycles in EMEs. Next, the Brazilian and Mexican business cycles are markedly different, as the contributions of shocks to aggregate fluctuations vary across the two countries. Hence, findings of this paper suggest although not all business cycles are alike in EMEs, “the cycle is the trend” view on aggregate fluctuations in EMEs remains valid. The empirical results of this paper are in support of the economic policies that aim to robustify the productivity process of EMEs.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The working capital constraint forces firms to borrow internationally to pay for labor in order to produce. As a result, the working capital constraint creates a transmission mechanism in that shocks to international financial markets affect output in a SOE.

  2. See, for example, Itskhok and Moll (2019) and Benguria et al. (2022).

  3. Bianchi and Mendoza (2018) are the representative paper for this macroprudential policy.

  4. This paper had considered including other EMEs. However, there is a availability of data issue for other developing countries that forced them out of the empirical analysis. See Appendix for more details.

  5. Longer Brazilian and Mexican samples are available. However, SVARs estimated on the longer samples produce badly behaved impulse response functions (IRFs) and FEVDs due to non-stationary endogenous variables. Discussions about the sample size are included in the Appendix.

  6. Construction of the world real interest rate follows Neumeyer and Perri (2005) and Uribe and Yue (2006).

  7. See the Appendix for details about the sources and construction of data.

  8. The small sample critical value for the Brazilian trade balance-output ratio equals \(-\)3.160 at the 10% significance level.

  9. The potential of cointegration among the levels of variables is checked by applying the Johansen cointegration tests. The test results show that there are no cointegration among the I(1) variables in the Brazilian and Mexican samples. Refer to the Appendix for more details on cointegration.

  10. For reference, see Akinci (2013); Neumeyer and Perri (2005) and Uribe and Yue (2006).

  11. See, among others, Aguiar and Gopinath (2006); Arellano (2008) and Eaton and Gersovitz (1981).

  12. Mendoza (2010) and Schmitt-Grohè and Uribe (2016) are examples of studying the Kiyotaki and Moore collateral constraint in a SOE-RBC model.

  13. I follow the common practice in the EME empirical literature of estimating SVARs with two lags. See, for example, Akinci (2013); Bruno and Shin (2015) and Kim et al. (2020).

  14. The Appendix details the transformation from real GDP growth, the first difference of the log world real interest rate, the first difference of log Tobin’s Q, and the trade balance-output ratio to real GDP, the world interest rate, Tobin’s Q, and the trade balance.

  15. The remaining IRFs are available in the Appendix.

  16. In their SOE-RBC model, a positive TFP shock loosens the KM collateral constraint that enables a small open economy to borrow more foreign debt. As a result, the demand for capital increases its price.

  17. I interpret point estimates of FEVDs greater than 20% as economically important and confidence bands surrounding the median estimate of a FEVD greater than 40% interval as large uncertainty.

  18. Sensitivity checks using a different lag length, and a different ordering of variables are included in the Appendix. Results from sensitivity checks confirm the robustness of the empirical findings.

References

  • Aguiar M, Gopinath G (2006) Defaultable debt, interest rates and the current account. J Int Econ 69(1):64–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aguiar M, Gopinath G (2007) Emerging market business cycles: the cycle is the trend. J Polit Econ 115(1):69–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akinci, (2013) Global financial conditions, country spreads and macroeconomic fluctuations in emerging countries. J Int Econ 91(2):358–371

  • Arellano C (2008) Default risk and income fluctuations in emerging economies. Am Econ Rev 98(3):690–712

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benguria F, Matsumoto H, Saffie F (2022) Productivity and trade dynamics in sudden stops. J Int Econ 139:103631

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattarai S, Chatterjee A, Park WY (2021) Effects of US quantitative easing on emerging market economies. J Econ Dyn Control 122:104031

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bianchi J, Mendoza EG (2018) Optimal time-consistent macroprudential policy. J Polit Econ 126(2):588–634

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard OJ, Quah D (1989) The dynamic effects of aggregate demand and supply disturbances. Am Econ Rev 79(4):655–673

    Google Scholar 

  • Boz E, Daude C, Bora Durdu C (2011) Emerging market business cycles: learning about the trend. J Monet Econ 58(6):616–631

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruno V, Shin HS (2015) Capital flows and the risk-taking channel of monetary policy. J Monet Econ 71:119–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo GA, Izquierdo A (2006) Sudden stops and phoenix miracles in emerging markets. Am Econ Rev 96(2):405–410

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dickey D, Pantula SG (1987) Determining the ordering of differencing in autoregressive processes. J Bus Econ Stat 5(4):455–61

    Google Scholar 

  • Dieppe A, Francis N, Kindberg-Hanlon G (2021) Technological and non-technological drivers of productivity dynamics in developed and emerging market economies. J Econ Dyn Control 131:104216

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eaton J, Gersovitz M (1981) Debt with potential repudiation: theoretical and empirical analysis. Rev Econ Stud 48(2):289–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • García-Cicco J, Pancrazi R, Uribe M (2010) Real business cycles in emerging countries? Am Econ Rev 100(5):2510–2531

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayashi F (1982) Tobin’s marginal q and average q: a neoclassical interpretation. Econometrica 50(1):213–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Itskhoki O, Moll B (2019) Optimal development policies with financial frictions. Econometrica 87(1):139–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim Y, Lim H, Sohn W (2020) Which external shock matters in small open economies? Global risk aversion vs. US economic policy uncertainty. Jpn World Econ 54:101011

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kiyotaki N, Moore J (1997) Credit cycles. J Polit Econ 105(2):211–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mendoza EG (2010) Sudden stops, financial crises, and leverage. Am Econ Rev 100(5):1941–1966

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neumeyer PA, Perri F (2005) Business cycles in emerging economies: the role of interest rates. J Monet Econ 52(2):345–380

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ng S, Perron P (1995) Unit root tests in ARMA Models with data-dependent methods for the selection of the truncation lag. J Am Stat Assoc 90(429):268–281

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olea JLM, Plagborg-Møller M (2019) Simultaneous confidence bands: theory, implementation, and an application to SVARs. J Appl Econ 34(1):1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reyes-Heroles R, Tenorio G (2019) Regime-switching in emerging market business cycles: interest rate volatility and sudden stops. J Int Money Financ 93:81–100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitt-Grohè S, Uribe M (2016) Adjustment to small, large, and sunspot shocks in open economies with stock collateral constraints. Working paper no. 22971 (December), NBER, Cambridge, MA

  • Tillmann P, Kim G-Y (2019) The spillover effects of U.S. monetary policy on emerging market economies. Int J Financ Econ 24(3):1313–1332

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uribe M, Yue VZ (2006) Country spreads and emerging countries: who drives whom?. J Int Econ 69(1):6–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I am grateful and indebted to Jim Nason for his guidance and support. I extend my gratitude to two anonymous referees, Giuseppe Fiori, Daisoon Kim, and Xiaoyong Zheng, for their thoughtful comments and suggestions. I thank Givi Melkadze, Margaret Jacobson, and participants at the Business Fluctuations session at the 91st Southern Economics Association conference for helpful comments. My thanks also go to Tasha Bigelow for editorial assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bira Zhahadai.

Ethics declarations

My name is Bira Zhahadai. I am a assistant professor from the department of economics at Illinois Wesleyan University. This paper is original and has not been published elsewhere, nor is it currently under consideration for publication elsewhere. I have no conflicts of interest to disclose. Please address all correspondence concerning this paper to me at bzhahada@iwu.edu. All remaining errors are my own.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file 1 (pdf 2597 KB)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Zhahadai, B. Are business cycles in emerging market economies alike?. Int Econ Econ Policy 20, 537–561 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-023-00567-8

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-023-00567-8

Keywords

Navigation