Skip to main content
Log in

Tracking the causes of eurozone external imbalances: new evidence and some policy implications

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
International Economics and Economic Policy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The paper assesses the contribution of key drivers of external imbalances in the Eurozone through the estimation of a panel-data Vector Autoregressive model over 1975–2011. Growth fluctuations, initially associated with demand booms triggered by unusually low interest rates, and later with demand contractions resulting from the crisis and policy adjustments, have played an important role in current account balance fluctuations. Changes in real exchange rates or unit labor costs have played a less important role. Demand shocks have contributed more to current account balance dynamics in the Eurozone periphery than in the core, whereas competitiveness has been a less prominent factor in the periphery but relatively more important in the core. Some broad policy implications of the findings for demand management in a currency union are discussed, including for fiscal policy coordination and macroprudential policies when union members face asymmetric shocks. The role of internal devaluation policies as a means of correcting external imbalances is also reassessed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The “Eurozone periphery” in this paper is defined to include the countries of the monetary union most affected by the sovereign debt crisis: Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal and Spain. These are the largest net debtor countries in the Eurozone, although in some countries, particularly in Italy, the current account deficits have not always been excessive. The “Eurozone core” countries are defined to include: Austria, Belgium, Denmark (member of the European Exchange Rate Mechanism), Finland, France, Germany, The Netherlands and Slovenia. The choice of countries is further explained in section 3.

  2. The Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure (MIP) includes an early warning system based on a scoreboard, which consists of a set of eleven indicators covering what is commonly perceived as major sources of macroeconomic imbalances. The MIP also involves recommendations for corrective action to members experiencing persistent imbalances and, in the event, an enforcement mechanism based on sanctions for members that fail to comply with the recommended corrective actions.

  3. Earlier studies of current account determinants in the same vein include Calderon et al (2002), and Chinn and Prasad (2003).

  4. The literature has also examined other factors affecting the external balance, such as dependency ratios and trade. For example, using a methodology of bilateral trade regressions, Chen et al (2012) found that the Eurozone periphery suffered from asymmetric trade shocks compared to the core. It benefited less from increased demand from China and oil producing countries, while it was affected more from competition by Eastern and Central European countries.

  5. This partly reflects the collapse of tax revenues linked to pre-crisis booming sectors such as construction but also the support provided to ailing banks in some periphery countries. It also partly reflects the fiscal fragilities of those periphery countries which used reduced interest payments on debt and buoyant tax revenues to expand public spending, thus leaving their budgets vulnerable to a loss of revenue as public expenditure was difficult to cut on short notice (see also IMF 2011b).

  6. This view is well epitomized by Sinn (2011): “The euro brought about a convergence in interest rates, lowering all euro members’ borrowing costs down to German levels. But it proved to be a mixed blessing. The competitiveness of these countries was severely eroded in the process, since their wages and prices rose excessively over the period. To come out of the crisis, the GIPS [Eurozone periphery countries] now need to depreciate in real terms, i.e., reduce wages and prices relative to their trading partners, a painful process that requires harsh austerity programs, straining the social fabric and causing significant political strife.”

  7. The competitiveness of tradable goods sectors can even be affected more directly by rising prices of non-tradables to the extent that non-tradable goods and services are used as inputs in the production of tradable goods.

  8. Actual inflation rate is admittedly a crude measure of expected inflation. An alternative would be to use a backward looking approach to compute expected inflation. For instance, MacDonald and Nagayasu (2000) use a one-sided moving average filter consisting of four quarterly lags of actual inflation. Another alternative would be to use indexed-inflation bonds to calculate expected inflation. However, not all the Eurozone countries issue these type bonds.

  9. We use actual growth as a measure of expected growth, despite the limitations of this assumption, in line with previous studies in the empirical literature of external current account determination (Chinn and Prasad 2003; Barnes et al. 2010).

  10. Long term government bonds, the consumer price index series, and the REER series are taken from the IFS database of the IMF. REER series is also complemented with BIS data. YGAP and GR series come from the WDI database of the World Bank. Finally, CA is taken from the BPS database of the IMF.

  11. Slovakia adopted the euro in 2009 so consequently we do not include it in the sample. Luxembourg, Cyprus, and Malta are excluded from the panel because of their relatively small economic size and the large size of their financial sector (implying that the dynamics of the current account can be potentially driven by very different factors than for the other members of the Eurozone).

  12. Using the first-differenced OLS presents an additional advantage since it highly increases the likelihood of obtaining a stable VAR system.

  13. All the robustness results are available upon request.

  14. Not always these three criteria results coincide. However, one lag is always selected by the majority of criteria in the different specifications.

  15. The ULC series are taken from the OECD database.

  16. Actually, the standard deviation for the R shocks in the baseline VAR in the full sample [1975-2011] is higher (1.62) than in the more recent sample [1996-2011] (1.35).

  17. Indeed, the standard deviation for the R shocks is 1.81 for 1996-2011, compared to 2.12 for the entire period [1975-2011].

  18. External demand changes perceived as permanent may lead to reassessments of future income that alter savings, thus offsetting part of the direct impact of external demand changes on the current account balance. The direct impact of external demand shocks on the current account would be unlikely, however, to be reversed by the induced response of domestic demand.

  19. In 2006-07, on average, the overall fiscal balance was in surplus, at 1.5 and 2% of GDP respectively in Ireland and Spain. Gross public debt in proportion to GDP was 25% in Ireland and 38% in Spain. During the same period, the average fiscal deficit in the Eurozone was 1% of GDP while public debt was, on average, 67.5% of GDP (IMF, Fiscal Monitor, October 2012).

  20. Macroprudential measures motivated by systemic risk considerations, such as the dynamic loan provisioning implemented in Spain, can contribute to taming the credit cycle, while counter-cyclical macroprudential measures can reduce the probability of systemic risk by preventing suboptimal fluctuations in capital flows (see Cordella et al. 2014).

  21. In the case of Italy, Portugal, and Spain these extra capital buffers would have absorbed most of the banking system losses resulting from the global financial crisis, although in Ireland and Greece these buffers would have not been enough.

  22. Strictly speaking, a change in the relative price of the two goods would violate the assumption of fixed consumer income in each period, measured in terms of tradable or non-tradable goods. However, this is inconsequential for the point made here. A constant returns technology would be consistent with the assumption of fixed income but this would preclude changes in the relative price of the two goods as a result of changes in current consumption.

  23. This adjustment can, however, be brutal if it is triggered by a sovereign debt crisis, as in the Eurozone in 2009-10, when markets doubt that the accumulated debt is sustainable. This would lead to sharply higher interest rates, a fall in domestic demand, and real exchange rate depreciation that may prove contractionary if resources cannot be easily shifted in the short run from non-tradable to tradable goods sectors.

References

  • Arellano M, Bover O (1995) “Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models”. J Econ 68:29–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano M, Bond S (1991) “Some tests of specification for panel data: monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment Equations”. Rev Econ Stud 58:277–97

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arghyrou M, Chortareas G (2008) “Current account imbalances and real exchange rates in the euro area”. Rev Int Econ 9(5):747–764

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bank for International Settlements (2011) “Macroprudential policy—a literature review”, BIS Working Papers, No 337, February

  • Barnes S, Lawson J, and Radziwill A (2010) “Current account imbalances in the Euro Area: A comparative Perspective” Economics Department Working Paper No. 826

  • Beetsma RX Debrun, and Klaassen F (2001)“Is Fiscal Policy Coordination in the EMU Desirable?”, IMF Working Paper 01/178

  • Beetsma R, Giuliodori M (2011) “The effects of government purchase shocks: review and estimates for the EU”. Econ J 121:F4–F32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belke A, Dreger C (2011) “Current account imbalances in the euro area: catching up or competitiveness?”, discussion paper 1106. Deutsches Institut fur Wirtschaftsforschung, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O, Giavazzi F (2002) “Current account deficits in the euro area: the End of the feldstein-horioka puzzle?”. Brook Pap Econ Act 2:147–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundel R, Bon S (1998) “Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models”. J Econ 87:115–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brzoza-Brzezina M, Kolasa M and Makarski K (2013) “Macroprudential Policy Instruments and Economic imbalances in the Euro Area”, European Central Bank, Working Paper No 1589, September

  • Calderon C, Chong A, Loayza N (2002) “Determinants of current account deficits in developing countries”. The B E J Macroecon 2(1):1–33

    Google Scholar 

  • Caporale GM, Girardi A (2013) “Fiscal spillovers in the Euro area”. J Int Money Financ, Elsevier 38:84.e1–84.e16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen R, Milesi-Ferretti GM, and Tressel T (2012) “External Imbalances in the Euro Area”, IMF WP/12/236

  • Chinn M, Prasad E (2003) Medium-term determinants of current accounts in industrial and developing countries: an empirical exploration. J Int Econ 59(1):47–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cordella T, Federico P, Vegh C, Vuletin G (2014) “Reserve requirements in the brave New macroprudential world”. The World Bank, Washington

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Draghi M (2012) “Competitiveness of the euro area and within the euro area”, Speech at the colloquium “Les défis de la compétitivité”, Paris, 13 March 2012. http://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/key/date/2012/html/sp120313.en.html

  • Eichengreen B (2010) “Imbalances in the euro area”. University of California Berkeley, Mimeo

    Google Scholar 

  • European Parliament (2012) “Macroeconomic Imbalances in the Euro Area”, Note by the Directorate General for Internal Policies, April, Brussels

  • European Central Bank, (2012), “Competitiveness and External Imbalances within the Euro Area”, Occasional Paper Series, No. 139

  • Giavazzi F and Spaventa L (2010) “Why the current account may matter in a monetary union: Lessons from the financial crisis in the Euro area,”CEPR Discussion Papers, No. 8008

  • Gros D (2012) “Macroeconomic Imbalances in the Euro Area: Symptom or Cause of the Crisis?”, CEPS Policy Brief No. 266

  • Hebous S, Zimmerman T (2013) “Estimating the effects of coordinated fiscal actions in the euro area”. Eur Econ Rev 58:110–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houben A and Kakes J (2013) “Financial Imbalances and Macroprudential Regulation in a Currency Union”, The Netherlands Bank, Occasional Sudies, Vol II/No 5

  • International Monetary Fund (2011a) “Macroprudential Policy: An Organizing Framework” Monetary and Capital Markets Department, March

  • International Monetary Fund (2011b) “Regional Economic Outlook: Europe”, Chapter 3, Financial Integration, Growth, and imbalances, May

  • Jaumotte, F. and Sodsriwiboon, P. (2010), “Current Account Imbalances in the Southern Euro Area”, IMF WP/10/139

  • Kilian L (1998) “Small-sample confidence intervals for impulse response functions”. Rev Econ Stat 80(2):218–230

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane PR (2008) “The Macroeconomics of Financial Integration: A European Perspective”, IIIS Discussion Paper No. 265, Trinity College, Dublin

  • Lane PR and Pels B (2012) “Current Account Imbalances in Europe”, IIIS Discussion Paper No. 397, Trinity College, Dublin

  • MacDonald R, Nagayasu J (2000) “The long-Run relationship between real exchange rates and real interest rate differentials: a panel study”. IMF Staff Papers 47(1):116–128

    Google Scholar 

  • Nerlove M (1967) “Experimental evidence on the estimation of dynamic economic relations from a time series of cross-sections”. Econ Studies Quart 18:42–74

    Google Scholar 

  • Nickell S (1981) “Biases in Dynamic Models with Fixed Effects”. Econometrica 49:1417–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld M and Rogoff K (2000) “Perspectives on OECD Economic Integration: Implications for US Current Account Adjustment”, in Global Economic Integration: Opportunities and Challenges, Proceedings of a Symposium Sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, p. 169–208

  • Pesaran H, Shin Y (1998) “Generalized impulse response analysis in linear multivariate models”. Econ Lett 58(1):17–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff K (1985) “Can international monetary policy cooperation be counterproductive?”. J Int Econ 18:199–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz B, von Hagen J (2011) “Current account imbalances and financial integration in the euro area”. J Int Money Financ 30(8):1676–1695

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sinn HW (2013) Austerity, growth and inflation: Remarks on the Eurozone’s unresolved competitiveness problem, CESifo Working Paper No 4086

  • Stock J, Watson W (2001) “Vector autoregressions”. J Econ Perspect 15(4):101–115

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trichet JC (2011) “Competitiveness and the smooth functioning of EMU” Lecture at the University of Liège, 23 February 2011. http://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/key/date/2011/html/sp110223.en.html

  • Wooldridge J (2013) “Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach”, 5th Edition, South-Western

  • World Bank (2012) “Golden Growth: Restoring the lustre of the European economic model”, edited by I.S. Gill and M. Raiser, Washington DC

  • Wyplosz C (2013) “Eurozone Crisis: It’s About Demand, not Competitiveness”, Mimeo

  • Zemanek H, Belke A and Schnabl G (2009) “Current Account Imbalances and Structural Adjustment in the Euro Area: How to Rebalance Competitiveness”, IZA Policy Paper No. 7

Download references

Acknowledgment

Views expressed in this paper are of the authors’ and should not be attributed to the World Bank or its Executive Directors. Helpful comments from Tito Cordella, Hinh Dinh, Poonam Gupta, Sam Ouliaris, and participants in seminars at the World Bank and the IMF Institute are gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Aristomene Varoudakis.

Appendices

ANNEX 1: Impact of income convergence and lower borrowing costs in a simple intertemporal model of an open economy

Consider a rudimentary two-period, small open economy with no investment, where representative consumers are endowed with predetermined income (Y1, Y2) in each period and can borrow from or lend abroad at an exogenous interest rate (r). Consumers have no initial assets or debts so that we can neglect interest payments when looking at the economy’s external current account. They decide present and future consumption by maximizing utility over two periods subject to an inter-temporal budget constraint, with future consumption discounted by a certain rate of time preference (β). Assume that the income endowments, the interest rate, the discount rate, and the inter-temporal rate of substitution of present and future consumption are such that the economy is initially in autarky, with consumption (C1, C2) equal to income in each period and hence a balanced external current account (Fig. 12a, point A).

Consider a metaphor meant to illustrate the change in the environment faced by the Eurozone periphery after the introduction of the common currency. Assume that, as a result of international financial integration, the cost of borrowing is reduced to r’‹ r while the expectation of faster convergence raises future income to Y2’›Y2 with present income remaining unchanged. It is straightforward to establish that, at the new equilibrium (point B), the rudimentary economy will run a current account deficit (Y1-C1’) in the first period as the representative agents will attempt to smooth consumption over time by increasing both future and present consumption. A future current account surplus (Y2’-C2’) will have to match today’s deficit so as to repay the debt incurred to increase present consumption.

Fig. 12
figure 12

A rudimentary inter-temporal model of a small open economy (a) Impact of an increase in future income and a decrease in the interest rate on the current account balance (b) impact of the production of tradables and non-tradables on the real exchange rate

Assume next, for simplicity, that tradable and non-tradable goods are consumed in each period according to a fixed proportion, as illustrated by the radiant in Fig. 12b, regardless of their relative price—this can be derived, for example, from a Cobb-Douglas type utility function for the two goods. We also assume diminishing returns in the production of the two goods so that point A in Fig. 12b illustrates the production of tradable goods (YT) and non-tradable goods (YN) in the present period, before the increase in expected future income and the decline in the interest rate. As the economy is in autarky consumption of both types of goods equals production. The relative price of tradable goods in terms of non-tradables (PT/PN) is measured by the slope of the production possibility frontier at equilibrium and can be interpreted as the equivalent of the real exchange rate. A decline in the relative price of tradable goods (an increase in the relative price of non-tradables) denotes an appreciation of the real exchange rate.Footnote 22

Consider now how the increase in current consumption, induced by the expected growth in future income and the decline in the interest rate, which is reflected in the current account deficit run in the present period, affects the production of tradable and non-tradable goods. The new consumption equilibrium is illustrated by point B (Fig. 12b), indicating higher consumption of both tradables and non-tradables (CT’› CT and CN’› CN). The higher consumption of non-tradables has to be met through a shift of domestic production from the tradable goods sector to non-tradables, such as illustrated by the new production equilibrium at point C. The economy now produces YN’ = CN’› YN and YT’‹ YT. Consumption of tradable goods exceeds their domestic production by an amount (CT’-YT’›0) equal to the economy’s current account deficit measured in terms of tradable goods.

Note that in the new production equilibrium (point C) the relative price of tradable goods in terms of non-tradables must decline in order to induce the required shift of resources to the non-tradable goods sector. This is equivalent to an appreciation of the real exchange rate which underlies the current account deficit in the current period. In the future period, when the economy must turn the deficit into a current account surplus to repay its debt, production will have to shift from non-tradable goods to tradables, with a parallel increase in the price of tradable goods—tantamount to a depreciation of the real exchange rate. Footnote 23

ANNEX 2: Robustness exercise: Italy included in the Eurozone core subsample

Table 8 Forecast error GVD Eurozone core [1975-2011]: percent of variation in CA explained by column variable
Table 9 Forecast error GVD Eurozone periphery [1975-2011]: percent of variation in CA explained by column variable

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Diaz-Sanchez, J.L., Varoudakis, A. Tracking the causes of eurozone external imbalances: new evidence and some policy implications. Int Econ Econ Policy 13, 641–668 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-015-0316-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-015-0316-0

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation