Skip to main content
Log in

How do social capabilities shape a country’s comparative advantages? Unpacking industries’ relatedness

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of World Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study elaborates on a methodology that combines industry-level data (exports, HS 4-digits) with country-level indicators to determine which social capabilities are important when explaining patterns of comparative advantage (or structural transformation). The indicators used to characterize these capabilities are associated with different dimensions: economic, institutional, and cultural. Through the product space, we estimate a density measure identifying the proximity between non-competitive products and a country’s current export profile, and then unpack the contribution of different relatedness channels to changes in comparative advantage by redefining densities in terms of social affinities between industries. We find that (i) countries can be competitive in certain industries, even if some of these capabilities are not high; (ii) all dimensions, but not all their components, matter in predicting changes in countries’ comparative advantages; (iii) structural transformations take some time to materialize; and (iv) the inclusion of social affinities diminishes the influence of a density variable measuring overall relatedness to predict product takeoff.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability

On request.

Code availability

Stata do-files on request.

Notes

  1. See, for example, Romalis (2004), Costinot et al. (2012), and other references cited in Bahar et al. (2019).

  2. As stated in Nunn & Trefler (2014) the relationship between the countries’ culture and their comparative advantages has received scant attention in the literature. Two of the few cases are Tabellini (2008) and Costinovis et al. (2017).

  3. As suggested in the literature review of Nunn & Trefler (2014), institutions impinge on comparative advantages through channels that differ from those of endowments. For instance, by dealing with hold-up and underinvestment problems in input–output relationships, by making possible incentive-compatible arrangements for promoting work effort, and by reducing the financing costs in imperfect credit markets when fixed investments are large.

  4. Other papers that attempt unpacking relatedness to identify different mechanisms in specialization or diversification processes (e.g., comparative advantage, regional development, path-breaking development, geographical job locations, bilateral trade) are the following: Boschma & Capone (2015), Zhu et al. (2017), Jara-Figueroa, et al. (2018), Farinha et al. (2019), Jun et al. (2019), Huang & Zhu (2020).

  5. A more detailed description of the concept of social capabilities is presented in Abramovitz (1986, 1995).

  6. This density metric was originally formulated for a background paper of the 2017 World Development Report. ‘Governance and the Law’ (Castañeda & Chávez-Juárez, 2016). Interaction terms between a plain density metric and a country’s socioeconomic indicator (R&D, FDI, etc.), like in Huang & Zhu (2020) and Cortinovis et al. (2017), are used to identify specific factors that mitigate or enhance the effect of relatedness on a specialization process (Hidalgo, 2021). In other words, these terms help to discover mechanisms of path-breaking development and unrelated diversification. In contrast, our approach allows for comparisons between the imputed values of specific social capabilities in pairs of nodes and, thus, we can explore if social affinities—either because the level of the imputed values are low or high in both industries—are conducive to the transmission of other forms of productive capabilities.

  7. The revival of the cultural perspective on development is due to a large extent on the conceptualization and measurement of social capital (e.g., Knack & Keefer, 1997, Tabellini, 2010) and the increase in the number of countries included in recent waves of the World Value Survey (e.g., Petrakis, 2014). Recently, the literature on experimental and behavioral games has also shown that individuals’ culture has an impact on decision-making (e.g., Beugelsdijk & Maseland, 2011). Likewise, at the theoretical level, the influence of social norms and beliefs on behavior is thoroughly explained with different conduits: preferences, cognitive mechanisms, and social coordination (e.g., Basu, 2010 and Castañeda, 2020).

  8. The idea behind averaging the values of RCAc,p, and Ik,p for each period is to avoid noisy information that comes from fluctuating export data. Accordingly, a good p is said to be produced competitively by country c only when its 3-year average has an RCA ≥ 1.

  9. In a few cases of highly skewed distributions, we use the percentile 1 or 99 instead of the minimum and the maximum, respectively. This allows us to avoid collapsed distributions with little useful information. Then, we set observations above the percentile 99 and below the percentile 1 to 1 and 0, respectively.

  10. Note that this adjustment factor varies depending on which one is the incoming node of the edge described in the denominator in Eq. (6). Hence, Eq. (7) generates a directed network.

  11. The reader should be aware that, in this paper, the productive structure and the economic dimension are not the same concepts. The former refers to the country’s export profile (or comparative advantage), while the latter refers to the type of social capability that supports any production process through economic mechanisms: human capital, infrastructure, financing, etc.

  12. Beyond this cut-off point, the proximity coefficients have negligible values, so they are discarded to improve the model’s computational tractability.

  13. As stated above, the proximity and the RCA coefficients in period t are measured with 3-year averages to diminish the effects of noisy information. This implies that the density variables are also measured in periods of three years.

  14. The convention is to remove the remaining cases (RCAc,i,t < 0.5 and \(RCA_{c, i, t + \tau}\) ≤ 1) si they are inconclusive.

  15. Two papers using this type of regressions are the following: Bahar et al. (2014), and Hausmann et al. (2013).

  16. Product opportunity gain is an index that measures the contribution of a certain industry to the complexity of the economy. Therefore, it measures the new capabilities acquired by a country when it can develop a comparative advantage in said industry.

  17. Prepared by The Growth Lab at Harvard University. The Atlas of Economic Complexity. http://www.atlas.cid.harvard.edu.

  18. The Atlas of Economic Complexity uses export statistics from the United Nations COMTRADE database. The data are cleaned by Growth Lab using the Bustos-Yildrim Method. Likewise, the harmonization procedure allows increasing the number of countries for which trade data are available.

  19. Prepared by The World Bank, and available at http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators.

  20. Prepared by The World Bank, and available at http://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/index.aspx#home

  21. Available at http://www.worldvaluessurvey.org/wvs.jsp

  22. Available at http://www.systemicpeace.org/inscrdata.html

  23. BACI also uses export statistics from the United Nations COMTRADE database.

  24. A similar IVI has already been used in the literature on economic development, the so-called PRODY (Hausmann et al., 2006).

  25. Data on ‘Health expenditure’ (either as % of GDP or % of government expenditure), and ‘Improved sanitation facilities’ are not reported in the World Development Indicators after 2013. Therefore, to include them in our analysis, we use a non-linear Gaussian process to impute values for all the observations in each of the variables. Refer to Liu et al. (2018) for an explanation of the methodology. We only impute values to country-indicator series that had at least 70% of the data available in the original dataset.

  26. Available at http://www.researchgate.net/publication/269992832_Online_Appendix_to_Welzel’s_CUP_monograph_Freedom_Rising

  27. In an alternative causal interpretation, the attached level of a social capability in a node could be the result of a set of conditions shared by the set of countries that are competitive in the said industry (e.g., having a similar productive structure).

  28. In these box-and-whisker plots, the white line describes the median, the filled-in boxes denote the interquartile range (i.e. between the lower and the upper quartile), and the whiskers extend to cover most of the data. Dots outside the whiskers are considered outliers.

  29. The products with the lowest values for this indicator include ‘lac; gums, resins’, ‘vegetable production’, ‘cotton’, and ‘coffee and tea’, while the highest IVIs are observed in ‘pharmaceutical products’, ‘albuminoidal subs.; modified starches’, and ‘cork and articles of cork’.

  30. However, in this paper we stick to a causal narrative that goes from culture to export specialization when stating that specific cultural values are required for production in complex industries.

  31. In other words, these types of transitions will not be common in countries lacking ‘government effectiveness’ since the social affinity between non-competitive nodes requiring this social capability and their export profile is low.

  32. Although we do not provide a thorough causality analysis, the use of lagged density variables—even with a period of 20 years-– indicates that the social affinities of the past exert an influence on the current evolution of the country’s comparative advantage.

  33. A caveat is in order. With these regressions, we are only formally testing whether social capabilities contribute to the countries’ ‘local development’. Thus, our results do not discard, for example, that government effectiveness can be a relevant factor in other types of structural transformations.

References

  • Abadie, A., Diamond, A., & Hainmueller, J. (2010). Synthetic control methods for comparative case studies: estimating the effect of California’s tobacco control program. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 105(490), 493–505.

    Article  MathSciNet  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Abramovitz, M. (1995). The Elements of Social Capability. In: Koo, B.H., Perkins, D.H. (eds) Social Capability and Long-Term Economic Growth. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-13512-7_3

  • Abramovitz, M. (1986). Catching up, forging ahead and falling behind. Journal of Economic History, 46(2), 385–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abramovitz, M. (1989). Thinking About Growth. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2012). Why nations fail. The origins of power, prosperity, and poverty. Asean Economic Bulletin, 29(2), 168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bahar, D., Hausmann, R., & Hidalgo, C. A. (2014). Neighbors and the evolution of the comparative advantage of nations: evidence of international knowledge diffusion? Journal of International Economics, 92(1), 111–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bahar, D., Rosenow, S., Stein, E., & Wagner, R. (2019). Export take-offs and acceleration: unpacking cross-sector linkages in the evolution of comparative advantage. World Development, 117, 48–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basu, K. (2010). Beyond the invisible hand: groundwork for a new economics. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2011). Pillars of prosperity. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Beugelsdijk, S., & Maseland, R. (2011). Culture in economics. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boschma, R., & Capone, G. (2015). Institutions and diversification: related versus unrelated diversification in a varieties of capitalism framework. Research Policy, 44, 1902–1914.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castañeda, Gonzalo, and Florian Chávez-Juárez, (2016). The Incidence of Culture, Governance, and Economics on the Countries Development through an Analysis of Coupled Networks World Bank working paper Open Knowledge Repository, World Bank Washington DC

  • Castañeda, G. (2020). The Paradigm of Social Complexity: An Alternative Way of Understanding Societies and their Economies (Vol. 1). CEEY.

  • Cortinovis, N., Xiao, J., Boschma, R., & van Oort, F. G. (2017). Quality of government and social capital as drivers of regional diversification in Europe. Journal of Economic Geography, 17(6), 1179–1208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costinot, A., Donaldson, D., & Komunjer, I. (2012). What goods do countries trade? A quantitative exploration of Ricardo’s Ideas. Review of Economic Studies, 79, 581–608.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farinha, T., Balland, P.-A., Morrison, A., & Boschma, R. (2019). What Drives the Geography of Jobs in the US? Unpacking Relatedness. Industry and Innovation, 26(9), 988–1022.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fukuyama, F. (2014). Political Order and Political Decay. Farrar Strauss and Giroux, New York NY: From the Industrial Revolution to the Globalization of Democracy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hartmann, D., Guevara, M. R., Jara-Figueroa, C., Aristarán, M., & Hidalgo, C. A. (2017). Linking economic complexity, institutions, and income inequality. World Development, 93, 75–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann, Ricardo, and Bailey Klinger. (2006), Structural Transformation and Patterns of Comparative Advantage in the Product Space, CID at Harvard University, Working Paper No. 128, August.

  • Hausmann, R., Hidalgo, C. A., Bustos, S., Coscia, M., & Simoes, A. (2014). The atlas of economic complexity: Mapping paths to prosperity. Mit Press.

  • Hausmann, R., & Hidalgo, C. A. (2011). The network structure of economic output. Journal of Economic Growth, 16, 309–342.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann, R., Hidalgo, C. A., Stock, D. P., & Yildrim M. A. (2019). Implied comparative advantage. In HKS Working Paper No. RWP14–003.

  • Hidalgo, C. A. (2021). Economic complexity theory and applications. Nature Reviews Physics, 3(2), 92–113.

    Article  ADS  Google Scholar 

  • Hidalgo, C. A., Balland, P.-A., Boschma, R., Delgado, M., et al. (2018). The principle of relatedness. In A. J. Morales, et al. (Eds.), International conference on complex systems (pp. 451–457). Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hidalgo, C. A., & Hausmann, R. (2009). The building blocks of economic complexity. PNAS, 106(26), 10570–10575.

    Article  ADS  CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Hidalgo, C. A., Klinger, B., Barabási, A.-L., & Hausmann, R. (2007). The product space conditions the development of nations. Science, 317(5837), 482–487.

    Article  ADS  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A. O. (1958). The strategy of economic development. Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang, Y., & Zhu, S. (2020). Regional industrial dynamics under the environmental pressures in China. Journal of Cleaner Production, 265, 121917.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inglehart, R., & Welzel, C. (2005). Modernization, cultural change, and democracy. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jara-Figueroa, C., Bogang Jun, B., Glaeser, E. L., & Hidalgo, C. A. (2018). The role of industry-specific, occupation-specific, and location-specific knowledge in the growth and survival of new firms. PNAS, 115(50), 12646–12653.

    Article  ADS  CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Jun, B., Alshamsi, A., Jian Gao, J., & Hidalgo, C. A. (2019). Bilateral relatedness: knowledge diffusion and the evolution of bilateral trade. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 30, 247–277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1997). Does social capital have an economic payoff? A cross country investigation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4), 1251–1288.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lal, Deepak. (1999). Culture Democracy and Development: The Impact of Formal and Informal Institutions on Development, IMF Conference on Second Generation Reforms, Washington, USA

  • Levchenko, A. (2007). Institutional quality and international trade. Review of Economic Studies, 74(3), 791–819.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, T., Wei, H., & Zhang, K. (2018). Wind power prediction with missing data using Gaussian process regression and multiple imputation. Applied Soft Computing, 71, 905–916.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myrdal, G. (1957). Economic theory and underdeveloped regions. Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nunn, N. (2007). Relationship-specificity, incomplete contracts, and the pattern of trade. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(2), 569–600.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nunn, N., & Trefler, D. (2014). Domestic institutions as a source of comparative advantage. Handbook of International Economics, 4, 263–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Petrakis, P. E. (2014). Culture. Spriger-Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prebisch, R. (1950). The Economic Development of Latin America and its Principal Problems. New York, NY: ECLA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ricardo, H., Hwang, J., & Rodrik, D. (2007). What your export matters. Journal of Economic Growth, 12(1), 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romalis, J. (2004). Factor proportions and the structure of commodity trade. American Economic Review, 94(1), 67–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenstein-Rodan, P. N. (1943). Problems of industrialization of Eastern and South-Eastern Europe. The Economic Journal, 53(210–211), 202–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwab, Klaus. (2014). The Global Competitiveness Report 2014–2015. Full data Edition, Geneva: World Economic Forum. Available at http://www.weforum.org/reports/global-competitiveness-report-2014-2015

  • Shorrocks, A. (1982). Inequality decomposition by factor components. Econometrica, 50(1), 193–211.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Tabellini, G. (2008). Institutions and culture. Journal of the European Economic Association, 6(2–3), 255–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tabellini, G. (2010). Culture and institutions: economic development in the regions of Europe. Journal of the European Economic Association, 8(4), 677–716.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tacchella, A., Cristelli, M., Caldarelli, G., Gabrielli, A., & Pietronero, L. (2012). A new metrics for countries’ fitness and products’ complexity. Scientific Reports, 2(1), 723.

    Article  ADS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • The Growth Lab at Harvard University, 2019, “International Trade Data (HS, 92)”

  • Weber, M. (1930). The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. London, UK: George Allen & Unwin Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Welzel, C. (2013). Freedom Rising. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Zaccaria, A., Cristelli, M., Tacchella, A., & Pietronero, L. (2014). How the taxonomy of products drives the economic development of countries. PLoS ONE, 9(12), e113770. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0113770

    Article  ADS  CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Zhu, S., He, C., & Zhou, Yi. (2017). How to jump further and catch up? Path-breaking in an uneven industry space. Journal of Economic Geography, 17, 521–545.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Funding

This work was supported by a research grant of The World Bank for producing a previous version of this article: Background paper of the World Development Report 2017. Governance and the Law. UPI Number 248827.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gonzalo Castañeda.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors confirm that there is no potential conflict of interest in this paper.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file1 (DOCX 415 KB)

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Castañeda, G., Castro Peñarrieta, L., Guerrero, O.A. et al. How do social capabilities shape a country’s comparative advantages? Unpacking industries’ relatedness. Rev World Econ (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-024-00524-w

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-024-00524-w

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation