Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

On the heterogeneous trade and welfare effects of GATT/WTO membership

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of World Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We quantify the effects of GATT/WTO membership on trade and welfare. Using an extensive database covering manufacturing trade for 186 countries over the period 1980–2016, we find that the average partial equilibrium impact of GATT/WTO membership on trade among member countries is large, positive, and significant. We contribute to the literature by estimating country-specific estimates and find them to vary widely across the countries in our sample with poorer members benefitting more. Using these estimates, we simulate the general equilibrium effects of GATT/WTO on welfare, which are sizable and heterogeneous across members. We show that countries not experiencing positive trade effects from joining GATT/WTO can still gain in terms of welfare, due to lower import prices and higher export demand.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Source: Direction of Trade Statistics (DOTS), WTO

Fig. 2

Source: Direction of Trade Statistics (DOTS), WTO.

Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In the early years, the GATT represented a club of mostly industrialized countries. Over the years, membership has increasingly covered the entire world; in 1995 the freshly created WTO had 127 members; today it counts 164 member states.

  2. We refer to Esteve-Pérez et al. (2020) for a recent literature survey.

  3. While the methods to obtain the general equilibrium estimates are standard, we are not aware of any study that analyzes the welfare effects of GATT/WTO.

  4. The 23 founding members were: Australia, Belgium, Brazil, Burma, Canada, Ceylon, Chile, China, Cuba, Czechoslovakia, France, India, Lebanon, Luxembourg, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Pakistan, Southern Rhodesia, Syria, South Africa, United Kingdom, and the United States.

  5. A comprehensive overview of applied tariff levels is available in the World Integrated Trade Solution (WITS) database.

  6. Following the first theoretical foundation of gravity in economics by Anderson (1979), a series of prominent papers derive the structural gravity model from alternative micro-foundations, e.g., Anderson and Wincoop (1979) and Eaton and Kortum (2002). The gravity model has also been derived at the sectoral level, on the demand side, e.g., Anderson and Wincoop (2004) and on the supply side, e.g., Costinot et al. (2012), and with intermediate goods, e.g., Caliendo and Parro (2015). Given the purpose of our study to obtain benchmark GE welfare effects of GATT/WTO, we employ the most simple and transparent traditional version of the structural gravity model with one sector and without taking into account intermediates and asset accumulation.

  7. Note that Eq. (4) underscores the importance of domestic trade flows as it is a restatement of the market clearing condition \(Y_i=\sum _i X_{ij}\) which always includes domestic trade flows.

  8. Starting with Cheng and Howard (2005), the literature has debated whether to use interval data instead of data over consecutive years for gravity estimations. We follow Egger and Filip (2022) who recommend using consecutive-year data. This improves estimation efficiency and avoids arbitrary dropping of observations. Moreover, the use of pooled/consecutive-year data better captures the adjustment of trade flows in response to trade policy changes.

  9. Including domestic trade flows has many advantages, ranging from theoretical consistency to econometric identification; see Yotov (2022) for a recent survey.

  10. We refer the reader to Larch et al. (2019) for further details on the dataset. A list of the 186 countries in our sample appears in Table 3 in Web Appendix.

  11. Data on bilateral distance, contiguous borders, colonial ties, and common language were taken from CEPII, c.f., Mayer and Soledad (2011).

  12. As noted earlier Larch et al. (2019) is the single exception, of which we are aware of, that also uses domestic trade flows.

  13. This finding is consistent with the results from Eicher and Henn (2011), who find that the effect of the WTO membership on trade is only positive before the formation of RTAs and among proximate developing countries. However, it is different from the results in Subramanian and Wei (2007) who argue that GATT/WTO increases trade more for developed countries. In addition to differences in the estimating samples, we believe that the different methodology (of including domestic trade flows) is a driving force behind the differences with these studies.

  14. This resulted in the dropping of a total of 40 countries, which are indicated with an ‘*’ in Table 3 in Web Appendix. As can be seen from Table 3 in Web Appendix, the dropped countries are usually very small economies or former Soviet republics. Thus, Fig. 5 presents 107 of the 143 GATT/WTO that we obtain initially.

  15. For Taiwan we use 2006 values, the most recent year with trade data for Taiwan in our dataset.

References

  • Anderson, J. E. (1979). A theoretical foundation for the gravity equation. American Economic Review, 69(1), 106–116.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, J. E., & van Wincoop, E. (1979). Gravity with gravitas: A solution to the border puzzle. American Economic Review, 93(1), 170–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, J. E., & van Wincoop, E. (2004). Trade costs. Journal of Economic Literature, 42(3), 691–751.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, J. E., & Yotov, Y. V. (2010). The changing incidence of geography. American Economic Review, 100(5), 2157–2186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arkolakis, C., Costinot, A., & Rodríguez-Clare, A. (2012). New trade models, same old gains? American Economic Review, 102(1), 94–130. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.102.1.94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baier, S. L., & Bergstrand, J. H. (2007). Do free trade agreements actually increase members’ international trade? Journal of International Economics, 71(1), 72–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrand, J. H., Larch, M., & Yotov, Y. V. (2015). Economic integration agreements, border effects, and distance elasticities in the gravity equation. European Economic Review, 78, 307–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caliendo, L., & Parro, F. (2015). Estimates of the trade and welfare effects of NAFTA. Review of Economic Studies, 82(1), 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, P.-L., & Lee, M.-J. (2011). The WTO trade effect. Journal of International Economics, 85(1), 53–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheng, I.-H., & Wall, H. J. (2005). Controlling for heterogeneity in gravity models of trade and integration. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 87(1), 49–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Costinot, A., Donaldson, D., & Komunjer, I. (2012). What goods do countries trade? A quantitative exploration of Ricardo’s ideas. Review of Economic Studies, 79(2), 581–608.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costinot, A., & Rodríguez-Clare, A. (2014). Trade theory with numbers: Quantifying the consequences of globalization. In G. Gopinath, E. Helpman, & K. S. Rogoff (Eds.), Chapter 4 in the handbook of international economics (Vol. 4, pp. 197–261). Oxford: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dai, M., Yotov, Y. V., & Zylkin, T. (2014). On the trade-diversion effects of free trade agreements. Economics Letters, 122(2), 321–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dekle, R., Eaton, J., & Kortum, S. (2007). Unbalanced trade. American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 97(2), 351–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dekle, R., Eaton, J., & Kortum, S. (2008). Global rebalancing with gravity: Measuring the Burden of adjustment. IMF Staff Papers, 55(3), 511–540.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eaton, J., & Kortum, S. (2002). Technology, geography and trade. Econometrica, 70(5), 1741–1779.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egger, P. H., Larch, M., & Yotov, Y. V. (2022). Gravity-model estimation with time-interval data: Revisiting the impact of free trade agreements. Economica, 89, 44–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egger, P. H., & Nigai, S. (2015). Energy demand and trade in general equilibrium. Environmental and Resource Economics, 60(2), 191–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egger, P. H., & Tarlea, F. (2015). Multi-way clustering estimation of standard errors in gravity models. Economics Letters, 134, 144–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eicher, T., & Henn, C. (2011). In search of WTO trade effects: Preferential trade agreements promote trade strongly, but unevenly. Journal of International Economics, 83(2), 137–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esteve-Pérez, S., Gil-Pareja, S., & Llorca-Vivero, R. (2020). Does the GATT/WTO promote trade? After all, rose was right. Review of World Economics (Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv), 156(2), 377–405.

    Google Scholar 

  • Felbermayr, G., & Kohler, W. (2006). Exploring the intensive and extensive margins of world trade. Review of World Economics, 142(4), 642–674.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Head, K., & Mayer, T. (2014). Gravity equations: Workhorse, toolkit, and cookbook. In G. Gopinath, E. Helpman, & K. S. Rogoff (Eds.), Chapter 3 in the handbook of international economics (Vol. 4, pp. 131–195). Oxford: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Larch, M., Monteiro, J.-A., Piermartini, R., & Yotov, Y. V. (2019). On the effects of GATT/WTO membership on trade: They are positive and large after all (WTO Staff Working Paper No. ERSD-2019-09).

  • Mayer, T., & Zignago, S. (2011). Notes on CEPII’s distances measures: The GeoDist database (CEPII Working Paper 2011-25).

  • Rose, A. K. (2004). Do we really know that the WTO increases trade? American Economic Review, 94(1), 98–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silva, S., João, M. C., & Tenreyro, S. (2006). The log of gravity. Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(4), 641–658.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Subramanian, A., & Wei, S.-J. (2007). The WTO promotes trade, strongly but unevenly. Journal of International Economics, 72(1), 151–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tomz, M., Goldstein, J., & Rivers, D. (2007). Do we really know that the WTO increases trade? Comment. American Economic Review, 97(5), 2005–2018.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yotov, Y. V. (2022). On the role of domestic trade flows for estimating the gravity model of trade. Contemporary Economic Policy, 1, 1. https://doi.org/10.1111/coep.12567

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yotov, Y. V., Piermartini, R., Monteiro, J.-A., & Larch, M. (2016). An advanced guide to trade policy analysis: The structural gravity model, Geneva, Switzerland. United Nations and World Trade Organization. http://vi.unctad.org/tpa/index.html

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank the Bertelsmann Foundation for financial support.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yoto V. Yotov.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no known competing financial interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to influence the work reported in this paper.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file 1 (pdf 345 KB)

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Felbermayr, G., Larch, M., Yalcin, E. et al. On the heterogeneous trade and welfare effects of GATT/WTO membership. Rev World Econ (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-023-00520-6

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-023-00520-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation