Skip to main content
Log in

Domestic product standards, harmonization, and free trade agreements

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of World Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study considers endogenous domestic standards on products to control negative consumption externalities using a three-country model of international oligopoly with a possible free trade agreement (FTA). The authors examine how the level of product standards and welfare are affected under an FTA and how the harmonization of standards affects the impact of the FTA. They find that if asymmetries in preferences or transboundary externalities are not too strong, an FTA makes product standards more stringent. In such a case, the FTA may or may not make the member countries better off, but it does make the non-member country better off. They also demonstrate that harmonizing the standards across the FTA members makes an FTA more favorable.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. As of 17 January 2020, 483 RTA notifications (counting goods, services, and accessions separately) had been received by the WTO, and, among them, 303 were in force (from the WTO website: http://www.wto.org/).

  2. Sturm (2006) mentions this concept by focusing on the “beef hormone” dispute between the European Union (EU) and the United States.

  3. Sturm (2006) shows that there exists a political equilibrium in which exporting and importing countries set different levels of product standards that cause trade disputes between them.

  4. For example, according to (Piermartini and Budetta 2009, pp.271–278), 58 of the 70 RTAs, including the EU, the North American Free Trade Agreement, and the Mercado Común del Sur include provisions regarding TBTs.

  5. An exception is Limão (2007), who also deals with standards and RTAs simultaneously, but the focus of his study is different from ours. He focuses on preferential trade agreements derived by the cooperation on non-trade issues, including product standards, and examines these agreements’ implications for global free trade. Meanwhile, our focus is on RTAs that include articles on product standards, but these RTAs are not necessarily derived by the cooperation on product standards.

  6. Harmonization is one of the approaches for removing impediments caused by differences between national standards. The other approaches are (i) using the existing international standards set by international standard bodies, such as the International Organization for Standardization, and (ii) mutual recognition (MR), by which a country can recognize standards imposed by other countries as equivalent to its own standards even if they differ. The EU has adopted the MR principle among the EU member countries.

  7. Given that most existing RTA arrangements take the form of FTAs and fewer than 10% can be considered to be fully fledged customs unions, Facchini et al. (2013) develop a political economy model of trade policy under imperfect competition to provide a positive explanation for the prevalence of FTAs.

  8. To examine how domestic standards should be handled by the WTO, Bagwell and Staiger (2001) and Staiger and Sykes (2011) develop a general equilibrium model of two-country trade with negative externalities in which governments decide their domestic standards that control the externalities and their trade policies. The introduction of negative externalities is intended to capture the issue of national standards; in addition to tariffs, governments may wish to impose product standards for various kinds of issues, possibly reflecting “social concerns.” We follow this basic idea and introduce negative externalities as a basis for setting standards.

  9. Taxation on consumption can also be used to control negative externalities. Gulati and Roy (2008) point out that it is often difficult to employ an emissions tax. For example, according to Fullerton and West (2002), the technology for applying a tax per unit of automobile emissions is currently unfeasible, as it is not possible to measure each car’s emissions in a reliable and cost-effective manner. Effectively measuring and regulating emissions is generally difficult for most consumption-generated pollutants, mainly because the technology to do so does not justify the costs. In the absence of an emissions tax, the government’s next best alternative is to tax consumption instead. However, unlike an emissions tax, a consumption tax does not encourage consumers to value goods with a higher environmental standard. Thus, under a consumption tax, the market fails to deliver the optimal environmental standard, and the government has to regulate both the standard and the consumption tax to achieve the first best outcome.

  10. In this study, we focus on consumption rather than production externalities. As we mentioned in the Introduction, negative externalities that call for product standards include vehicle emissions, food additives, and safety of electrical standards. These externalities reveal when consumers use or consume the products, no matter where those products are produced. These specific types of externalities are the focus of the current study.

  11. The numeraire good is assumed to be freely traded and generates no externalities.

  12. For each consumer, \(b_i(s_i){\bar{Q}}_i\) is taken as given in the utility maximization problem, so the first-order condition of the utility maximization problem is thus given by \(p_i=u_i'(Q_i)\).

  13. We limit our analysis to the case of linear demand to derive explicit solutions for equilibrium tariffs and standards, and thereby directly compare national welfare under different policy regimes. With linear demand, each firm’s output reaction function is downward sloping, and if the second-order conditions for profit maximization are globally satisfied, stability and uniqueness of the Cournot equilibrium are guaranteed. It is also well-known that even in the case with nonlinear demand, various comparative static properties of the Cournot model are “well-behaved” if demand is not too convex (Dixit 1986; Brander 1995). Thus, qualitative results regarding optimal tariffs and standards can be maintained under a more general, “not too convex” demand structure.

  14. For example, if the use of certain food additives is legally prohibited in a country, the firms supplying food products in that country’s market should avoid using that material in their production process.

  15. The assumption of no fixed cost implies that firms can produce goods by using different technologies when they supply goods to different markets. If there were fixed cost to choose a specific technology, firms might not choose different technologies at the same time.

  16. The national welfare defined here is consistent with the aggregation of individual welfare. See the Online Appendix for details. Note that since we assume a continuum of consumers on a unit interval, \({\bar{Q}}_i=Q_i\) holds in equilibrium.

  17. In the following analysis, we derive equilibrium solutions as if the governments first determine the standards and then choose the tariffs, taking the standard as given. This is for tractability of the analysis, and the same solutions can be obtained if we explicitly consider the situation in which the governments determine these policy instruments simultaneously. See the Online Appendix for details.

  18. That is, the additive-separability of the welfare function indicates that a country’s optimal standard is strategically independent of the other countries’ standards.

  19. Substituting (5) into the equation for export outputs, we obtain \(q_{ij}=q_{ik}=[a_i(s_i)-2b_i(s_i)]/10\), which becomes positive if \(\alpha _i>2\theta \beta _i+\gamma\) (in the case of a stringent standard) and \(\alpha _i>2\beta _i\) (in the case of a lax standard).

  20. Thus, our specification about marginal costs and externalities are similar to that of Costinot (2008).

  21. As noted in footnote 19, positive levels of exports can be guaranteed if \(\gamma <\alpha _i\) and \(\beta _i<\alpha _i/2\); in other words, the tariffs are below the prohibitive level. We focus on the situation in which the parameters satisfy these inequalities.

  22. Proposition 1 can be obtained under more general environment in which s is a continuous variable rather than the variable with binary choice. See the Online Appendix for details.

  23. The nonmember country always chooses the MFN tariff and does not change its standard after the formation of the FTA.

  24. In this symmetric countries case, we omit the subscript indicating the country index in the functions \(\gamma ^M\) and \(\gamma ^F\).

  25. As shown in its proof, Proposition 3 remains valid even if the member countries have different values of \(\alpha\) and \(\beta\).

  26. Similarly to Proposition 1, we can obtain Proposition 4 under more general environment in which s is a continuous variable. See the Online Appendix for details.

  27. A similar intuition and result hold in a more general economic environment, as demonstrated by Takarada et al. (2020), assuming free trade in goods.

  28. Since \({\bar{\gamma }}^M(\alpha /2)=\alpha (1-\sqrt{5}/4)\), \(\beta _*\) is explicitly solved as \(\beta _*=\alpha (60-\sqrt{3435})/4\approx 0.3478\alpha\).

  29. From Lemma 2 and (11), it holds that \(t_i^M(s_L)>t_i^F(s_L)=(3\alpha +4\beta _i)/21>(\alpha -\gamma )/7=t_i^F(s_H)\).

  30. See also the right-hand side panel of Fig. 5 as a reference to each member’s choice of standards under the MFN and the FTA in cases (i) to (iv).

  31. Note that the outcomes when the member countries’ externality parameters are sufficiently close to each other are consistent with those in the symmetric case demonstrated in Proposition 2.

  32. Because of the symmetry assumption, we omit the subscripts in the subutility function u and the per-unit externality function b.

  33. As demonstrated in the Online Appendix, there exists a cut-off value \(\bar{{\bar{\gamma }}}^F(\beta ,\delta )\) such that the member countries jointly choose \(s_L\) if \(\gamma >\bar{{\bar{\gamma }}}^F(\beta ,\delta )\), while they choose \(s_H\) if \(\gamma <\bar{{\bar{\gamma }}}^F(\beta ,\delta )\). It is also shown that \(\bar{{\bar{\gamma }}}^F(\beta ,\delta )\) is increasing in \(\delta\) and \({\bar{\gamma }}^F(\beta )-\bar{{\bar{\gamma }}}^F(\beta ,\delta )<0\) may hold for sufficiently large \(\delta\). This means that transboundary externalities can render an FTA welfare-decreasing for members when it was welfare-increasing for them when the externalities were purely local.

  34. In this paper, we have considered a trade model in which the source of trade is international oligopolistic competition. Alternatively, we can consider a trade model based on comparative advantage. In the theoretical literature of RTAs, this type of trade structure can be analyzed by using either a “competing exporters” model, in which each country imports one good from the other two countries, or a “competing importers” model, in which each country exports one good to the other two countries (Lake et al. 2020). Analysis of standards in trading economies where trade is driven by comparative advantage could be made by extending these models, and this is another topic for future research.

  35. It holds that \({\bar{\gamma }}^F(423 \alpha /1256)\approx 0.4221\alpha <{\bar{\gamma }}^M(\alpha /2)\).

  36. The conditions for \(s=s_H\) to be chosen are \(\omega _A(s_H)\ge {\tilde{\omega }}_A(s_L,s_L)\), \(\omega _B(s_H)\ge {\tilde{\omega }}_B(s_L,s_L)\), and \(\left[ \omega _A(s_H)-{\tilde{\omega }}_A(s_L,s_L)\right] \left[ \omega _B(s_H)-{\tilde{\omega }}_B(s_L,s_L)\right] > \left[ \omega _A(s_L)-{\tilde{\omega }}_A(s_L,s_L)\right] \left[ \omega _B(s_L)-{\tilde{\omega }}_B(s_L,s_L)\right]\). Since \(\omega _i(s_L)-{\tilde{\omega }}_i(s_L,s_L)=0\) for \(i=A,B\), the above three conditions hold if the sign of (A5) is positive.

References

  • Bagwell, K., & Staiger, R. W. (1999). Regionalism and multilateral tariff co-operation. In: Piggott, J. & Woodland, A. (Eds.), International Trade Policy and the Pacific Rim (pp. 157–190). Palgrave Macmillan UK.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Bagwell, K., & Staiger, R. W. (2001). Domestic policies, national sovereignty, and international economic institutions. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(2), 519–562.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brander, J., & Krugman, P. (1983). A ‘reciprocal dumping‘ model of international trade. Journal of International Economics, 15(3), 313–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brander, J.A. (1995). Strategic trade policy. In: Grossman, G., & Rogoff, K. (Eds.), Handbook of International Economics, (Volume 3, pp. 1395–1455). Elsevier.

  • Chen, M. X., & Mattoo, A. (2008). Regionalism in standards: Good or bad for trade? Canadian Journal of Economics, 41(3), 838–863.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costinot, A. (2008). A comparative institutional analysis of agreements on product standards. Journal of International Economics, 75(1), 197–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Disdier, A. C., Fontagné, L., & Cadot, O. (2015). North-South standards harmonization and international trade. The World Bank Economic Review, 29(2), 327–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. (1986). Comparative statics for oligopoly. International Economic Review, 27(1), 107–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Facchini, G., Silva, P., & Willmann, G. (2013). The customs union issue: Why do we observe so few of them? Journal of International Economics, 90(1), 136–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, R., & Serra, P. (2000). Standards and protection. Journal of International Economics, 52(2), 377–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freund, C. (2000). Multilateralism and the endogenous formation of preferential trade agreements. Journal of International Economics, 52(2), 359–376.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fullerton, D., & West, S. E. (2002). Can taxes on cars and on gasoline mimic an unavailable tax on emissions? Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 43(1), 135–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gulati, S., & Roy, D. (2008). National treatment and the optimal regulation of environmental externalities. Canadian Journal of Economics, 41(4), 1445–1471.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krishna, P. (1998). Regionalism and multilateralism: A political economy approach. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(1), 227–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lake, J., Nken, M., & Yildiz, H. M. (2020). Tariff bindings and the dynamic formation of preferential trade agreements. Journal of International Economics, 122, 103279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Limão, N. (2007). Are preferential trade agreements with non-trade objectives a stumbling block for multilateral liberalization? The Review of Economic Studies, 74(3), 821–855.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maggi, G. (2016). Issue linkage, In: Bagwell, K., & Staiger, R.W. (eds.), Handbook of Commercial Policy, (Volume 1, pp. 513–564). North-Holland.

  • Marette, S., & Beghin, J. (2010). Are standards always protectionist? Review of International Economics, 18(1), 179–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ornelas, E. (2005). Endogenous free trade agreements and the multilateral trading system. Journal of International Economics, 67(2), 471–497.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ornelas, E. (2005). Trade creating free trade areas and the undermining of multilateralism. European Economic Review, 49(7), 1717–1735.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piermartini, R., & Budetta, M. (2009). A mapping of regional rules on technical barriers to trade. In: Estevadeordal, A., Suominen, K., & Teh, R. (Eds.), Regional Rules on the Global Trading System (pp. 250–315). Geneva: WTO.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saggi, K. (2006). Preferential trade agreements and multilateral tariff cooperation. International Economic Review, 47(1), 29–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Staiger, R. W., & Sykes, A. O. (2011). International trade, national treatment, and domestic regulation. The Journal of Legal Studies, 40(1), 149–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stoler, A.L. (2011). TBT and SPS measures, in practice. In: Chauffour, J.P., & Maur, J.C. (Eds.), Preferential Trade Agreement Policies for Development (pp. 217–233). World Bank.

  • Sturm, D. M. (2006). Product standards, trade disputes, and protectionism. Canadian Journal of Economics, 39(2), 564–581.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Takarada, Y., Kawabata, Y., Yanase, A., & Kurata, H. (2020). Standards policy and international trade: Multilateralism versus regionalism. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 22(5), 1420–1441.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tudela-Marco, L., Garcia-Alvarez-Coque, J. M., & Martí-Selva, L. (2017). Do EU member states apply food standards uniformly? A look at fruit and vegetable safety notifications. Journal of Common Market Studies, 55(2), 387–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yi, S. S. (1996). Endogenous formation of customs unions under imperfect competition: Open regionalism is good. Journal of International Economics, 41(1), 153–177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yi, S. S. (2000). Free-trade areas and welfare: An equilibrium analysis. Review of International Economics, 8(2), 336–347.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like thank Kristy Buzard, Nicola Coniglio, Jadish Dean, Kazunobu Hayakawa, Keisaku Higashida, Toshihiro Ichida, Naoto Jinji, Minoru Kunizaki, Yan Ma, Marco Martorana, Noritsugu Nakanishi, Cheng-Hau Peng, Qiang Wu, Morihiro Yomogida, Taiyo Yoshimi, Laixun Zhao, and anonymous referees of this journal for their comments on earlier drafts. This work has been financially supported by the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science (JSPS) Grant-in-Aid for Scientific Research (B) (No.25285079; No.16H03612; No.20H01492) and (C) (No.19K01609).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Akihiko Yanase.

Ethics declarations

Conflicts of interest

The authors declare no potential confict of interest regarding the publication of this work.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material (pdf 308 KB)

Appendix A. Proofs

Appendix A. Proofs

1.1 Proof of Lemma 4

Comparing the slopes at the origin, we have \(d{\bar{\gamma }}_i^M(0)/d\beta _i=3/4<1=d{\bar{\gamma }}_i^F(0)/d\beta _i\). In addition, it holds that \({\bar{\gamma }}_i^F(\alpha _i/2)=(1-\sqrt{15}/30)\alpha _i\approx 0.8709\alpha _i>{\bar{\gamma }}_i^M(\alpha _i/2)\). Since both \({\bar{\gamma }}_i^M(\beta _i)\) and \({\bar{\gamma }}_i^F(\beta _i)\) are increasing and convex in \(\beta _i\), the statement of the lemma holds. \(\square\)

1.2 Proof of Proposition 2

From (7), (8), (12), and (13), we have

$$\begin{aligned} W_i^M-W_i^F&=w_i^M(s_i)+\pi _{ji}^M(s_j)-[w_i^F(s_i)+\pi _{ji}^F(s_j)] \nonumber \\&=\frac{4a_i(s_i)^2-6a_i(s_i)b_i(s_i)+b_i(s_i)^2}{10}+\frac{[a_h(s_h)-2b_h(s_h)]^2}{100} \nonumber \\&\quad -\frac{15a_i(s_i)^2-30a_i(s_i)b_i(s_i)+b_i(s_i)^2}{42}-\frac{[6a_j(s_j)+b_j(s_j)]^2}{441}. \end{aligned}$$
(A1)

If the member countries are symmetric, only cases (i), (iv), and (ix) in Table 1 are possible. In case (i), (A1) can be rewritten as

$$\begin{aligned} W_i^M-W_i^F =-\frac{(423\alpha -1256\beta )(3\alpha +4\beta )}{44100}. \end{aligned}$$
(A2)

Then, \(W_i^M>W_i^F\) (\(W_i^M<W_i^F\)) if and only if \(\beta >(<) \;423\alpha /1256 \approx 0.3368\alpha\).Footnote 35 In case (iv), (A1) can be rewritten as

$$\begin{aligned} W_i^M-W_i^F =\frac{-141\alpha ^2-3136\alpha \beta +686\beta ^2+4300\alpha \gamma -2150\gamma ^2}{4900}. \end{aligned}$$
(A3)

Given the parameter restrictions \(\alpha >\gamma\) and \(\alpha >2\beta\), it can be verified that \(W_i^M>W_i^F\) (\(W_i^M<W_i^F\)) holds if and only if

$$\begin{aligned} \gamma > (<) \; {\tilde{\gamma }}(\beta )\equiv \alpha -\frac{7}{5}\sqrt{\frac{41}{86}\alpha ^2-\frac{32}{43} \alpha \beta +\frac{7}{43}\beta ^2}. \end{aligned}$$

It also holds that \({\tilde{\gamma }}(0)\approx 0.0333\alpha\) and \({\tilde{\gamma }}(\alpha /2)\approx 0.4663\alpha \in \left( {\bar{\gamma }}^M(\alpha /2),{\bar{\gamma }}^F(\alpha /2)\right)\). Finally, in case (ix), (A1) can be rewritten as

$$\begin{aligned} W_i^M-W_i^F =-\frac{141(\alpha -\gamma )^2}{4900}<0. \end{aligned}$$
(A4)

Therefore, the FTA achieves higher welfare for the member countries than the MFN tariff does.\(\square\)

1.3 Proof of Proposition 3

If the pair of parameters \((\beta _i,\gamma )\) for each member country is in either region I or region III in Fig. 1, \(W_C^M<W_C^F\) holds because \(\pi _{iC}^M(s_L)-\pi _{iC}^F(s_L)=-(17\alpha _i-24\beta _i)(3\alpha _i+4\beta _i)/4900<0\) and \(\pi _{iC}^M(s_H)-\pi _{iC}^F(s_H)=-51(\alpha _i-\gamma )^2/4900<0\). If \((\beta _i,\gamma )\) is in region II, where member country i chooses \(s_L\) under the MFN regime and \(s_H\) under the FTA, it holds that

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{iC}^M(s_L)-\pi _{iC}^F(s_H) =-\frac{(17\alpha _i-14\beta _i-10\gamma )(3\alpha _i+14\beta _i-10\gamma )}{4900}. \end{aligned}$$

Since \(\alpha _i>2\beta _i\), it holds that \(17\alpha _i-14\beta _i-10\gamma>10(\alpha _i-\gamma )>0\). Therefore, the sign of the above expression is positive (negative) if and only if \(\gamma >(<)\;(3\alpha _i+14\beta _i)/10\) holds. Since Region II is contained in the set \(\left\{ (\beta _i,\gamma )\in \mathbb {R}_+^2 \mid \gamma <(3\alpha _i+14\beta _i)/10, \; \alpha _i>2\beta _i\right\}\), \(\pi _{iC}^M(s_L)<\pi _{iC}^F(s_H)\) holds, which means that \(W_C^M<W_C^F\) holds as well. \(\square\)

1.4 Proof of Lemma 5

Since the countries are assumed to be symmetric, either \((s_A^F,s_B^F)=(s_L,s_L)\) or \((s_A^F,s_B^F)=(s_H,s_H)\) holds under national standards. Suppose that \((\beta ,\gamma )\) is in region I in Fig. 1. In this case, the threat point in the bargaining problem is \((s_A^F,s_B^F)=(s_L,s_L)\). In light of (11), (12), and (13), it follows that the member countries jointly choose \(s=s_H\) if

$$\begin{aligned} \omega _i(s_H)- \omega _i(s_L)= \frac{387\gamma ^2-774\alpha \gamma +606\alpha \beta -23\beta ^2}{882} \end{aligned}$$
(A5)

is positive for \(i=A,B\).Footnote 36 We can verify that \(\omega (s_H)>\omega (s_L)\) holds if and only if \(387\gamma ^2-774\alpha \gamma +606\alpha \beta -23\beta ^2>0\), or equivalently, \(\gamma <\bar{{\bar{\gamma }}}^F(\beta )\). However, this contradicts the assumption that \((\beta ,\gamma )\) is in region I, which satisfies \(\gamma >{\bar{\gamma }}^F(\beta )\). This is because \(d\bar{{\bar{\gamma }}}^F(0)/d\beta =101\alpha /129\approx 0.7829\alpha\) and \(\bar{{\bar{\gamma }}}^F(\alpha /2)=(1-\sqrt{359}/6\sqrt{43})\alpha \approx 0.5184\alpha\), and thus, it follows that \(\bar{{\bar{\gamma }}}^F(\beta )<{\bar{\gamma }}^F(\beta )\) for all \(\beta \in (0,\alpha /2)\). Therefore, the member countries must jointly choose \(s_L\) if \((\beta ,\gamma )\) is in region I. Suppose next that \((\beta ,\gamma )\) is in region II or III. In this case, the threat point is \((s_A^F,s_B^F)=(s_H,s_H)\), and the member countries jointly choose \(s=s_L\) if \(\omega (s_H)<\omega (s_L)\). In light of (A5), the condition is satisfied if and only if \(\gamma \in \left( \bar{{\bar{\gamma }}}^F(\beta ), {\bar{\gamma }}^F(\beta )\right)\). If \(\gamma <\bar{{\bar{\gamma }}}^F(\beta )\), by contrast, the member countries jointly choose \(s=s_H\). \(\square\)

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Yanase, A., Kurata, H. Domestic product standards, harmonization, and free trade agreements. Rev World Econ 158, 855–885 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-021-00446-x

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-021-00446-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation