1 Introduction

The labour market effects of production relocation are still being debated. Offshoring, understood as ‘the process of changing the geographic assignment of the mix of tasks needed to produce a single final good or service’ (Hummels et al. 2018: 983) has traditionally been seen as a threat to domestic workers (job losses, declining wages, heightened inequality). The topic has become a media phenomenon, an issue in the political debate and one of the main themes in current economic literature. The theoretical literature on the distributional consequences of offshoring and global value chains (GVCs), recently reviewed by Frassen (2019), is abundant but ambiguous, particularly when it comes to predicting the combined effect of the various, often conflicting mechanisms at play.Footnote 1 In the empirical literature as well, despite the impressive development of measurements and methods the debate on the labour market consequences of importing foreign inputs is still unresolved, due to the gap between concepts and what can be feasibly demonstrated given the data (Hummels et al. 2018).

This paper uses rich individual-level data on workers in 28 European countries in the period from 2005 to 2014 to produce a multidimensional cross-country evaluation of the factors that determine wages in labour markets characterised by strong links to GVCs and task-related specificity of jobs. The core of our empirical analysis relates to the way we quantify dependence on foreign inputs and the role of cross-border production relations in generating labour market outcomes. The standard measures of fragmentation are based on the ratio of imported intermediates in a given industry to its output or value added (Feenstra and Hanson 1999). That is, the focus is on the last stage of production only, as if the use of foreign inputs were independent from the previous stages (whether performed domestically or abroad). Instead we employ the latest release of the WIOD input–output dataFootnote 2 and methodology proposed by Timmer et al. (2016), proxying fragmentation by a newly devised index of global import intensity of production (GII), which counts imports of goods and services required in any stage of production, including trade with third countries.Footnote 3 GII measures the extent to which a given industry depends on imported intermediates to attain its total production value (direct exposure) and previous international and cross-industry links (indirect exposure). Our approach is thus closer to the framework of sequential production and national interdependence driven by vertical specialisation and GVCs (Antràs and Chor 2013; Kohler 2004; Costinot et al. 2013) than to the ‘classic’ offshoring literature, which considers the last tier only (see Hummels et al. 2018, Sect. 2 for a review).

To illustrate this point, we refer to the statistics on GVC involvement (Table 1). Between 2000 and 2014 the import intensity of European production (ratio to total output) increased from 15.9% to 20.2%.Footnote 4 According to the monetary interpretation of GII proposed by Timmer et al. (2016), this means that in 2014 one dollar of goods and services finished in Europe generated about 20 cents worth of imports worldwide. Conventionally measured offshoring—the inputs used in the last stage of production—accounts for a bit less than half the increase that occurred over this period. The rest of the imported intermediates were used in earlier tiers and can be traced back in the GVC framework. The United States is less dependent on imported intermediates, but there was an increase in GII there as well (from 7.9% in 2000 to 8.8% in 2014). Worldwide, the ratio of GVC imports (i.e. imports by the country where the last stage of production occurred and by all other countries involved in earlier stages of production) to the output of the final products was approximately 16% in 2014 (12% in 2000).Footnote 5 And only a third of it can be ascribed to the final stage of production, so proper measurement of dependence on foreign inputs in earlier stages is essential. To date, however, the literature on the labour market effects of production fragmentation has neglected this aspect.

Table 1 Global import intensity of production, as % of final output (World, Europe, USA).

The studies of the effects of fragmentation on the European labour market that have considered the task content of jobs suffer another severe limitation, namely limited coverage: these inquiries have involved only a few Western European countries,Footnote 6 not the other, less highly developed economies of Southern or Central and Eastern Europe (CEECs).Footnote 7 Furthermore, often only the impact on manufacturing workers is analysed (as in Geishecker et al. 2010; Baumgarten et al. 2013; Hummels et al. 2014; Geishecker and Görg 2013).Footnote 8 The dependence on foreign production is sector-specific and non-negligible in non-manufacturing activities (Geishecker and Görg 2013),Footnote 9 so we do not limit our study to manufacturing alone.

Our central question is thus: are wages in Europe affected by globally measured dependence on foreign inputs, including direct and indirect exposure, given all the other dimensions of the wage determination process?Footnote 10 To answer, we construct a rich dataset: individual-level information on wages, occupational task profiles, personal and job characteristics on 1.3 million workers in 28 European countries over the period 2005–2014. We match our microdata with input–output measures of sectoral dependence on foreign inputs, other sector characteristics, and information on national labour market institutions and wage bargaining schemes. In addition to considering all the pre-final tiers of production, we compare the effects of dependence on foreign inputs measured globally, regardless of country of origin, with the effects of dependence on inputs from less developed countries only. Further, given our cross-country approach, we consider the task profiles of workers, which are occupation- and country-specific (Lewandowski et al. 2019).

The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 briefly describes the theoretical background and some essential contributions on production fragmentation and wages in Europe, which our paper expands on. Section 3 presents the data and methodology and the measurement of global dependence on foreign inputs and of wages in Europe. The empirical strategy and the results of the estimations for various subsamples are presented in Sect. 4. The last section concludes. Numerous robustness checks are included in the additional material and available in the online appendix.

2 The literature

2.1 Theoretical background

On the theoretical plane our paper is at the crossroads between the literature on the effects of offshoring on domestic workers and that on sequential production, which can be adopted to GVC analysis.Footnote 11 As recently described by Franssen (2019), the theoretical literature on the distributional effects of GVC is abundant but ambiguous, and ‘the hypothesized effects are highly dependent on the microeconomic foundations of the model chosen’ (Feenstra 2010, p. 3).

The conceptualisation of offshoring through trade-in-tasks has become a widely accepted reference point in the literature on production fragmentation. Theoretical models have addressed the ambiguity of the effects on domestic labour by studying how the overall outcome (wage loss or wage gain, say) is generated by the interplay of the contrasting forces in play in offshoring. According to Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg (2008), the wage impact of the growing dependence on foreign inputs due to falling offshoring costs operates indirectly through three main channels: the influence on relative productivity, the price effect and the labour supply effect.Footnote 12 Paradoxically, if the productivity gains from production relocation are sufficiently large, when tasks are offshored the ultimate result may actually be a wage gain that includes workers performing less demanding tasks.Footnote 13 However, other models suggest that offshoring may engender wage decline because of the pressure on domestic workers to accept lower wages for fear of job offshoring (Jeon and Kwon 2019) or the reallocation of workers from high- to low-productivity firms, with lower wages (Egger et al. 2015). A whole range of wage effects is possible, depending on the global engagement of firms (Amiti and Davis 2011): a decrease in output tariffs lowers wages in import-competing firms and raises them in exporting firms; a decrease in input tariffs, by contrast, will raise wages at import-using firms relative to those paid by firms that rely on local inputs.

Models of sequential, multistage production and the theories of interdependence driven by vertical specialisation (Costinot et al. 2012, 2013; Antràs and Chor 2013; Kohler 2004) have also produced ambiguous theoretical predictions on how the production chain will affect factor prices (including, especially, wages). But they also confirm that in a world of globally integrated production, the outcomes (wages, say) observed at any one stage (e.g. final) should not be analysed separately from what happens at the previous stages. Kohler (2004) argued that the ambiguity of the response of wages to production fragmentation is deepened by cross-industry links in a multistage production setting. Costinot et al. (2013) developed a simple theory of trade with sequential production to show how global supply chains affect international interdependence and Costinot et al. (2012) provide a multifactor version to study the implications for wage inequality. In such a model, with sequential production, wages respond to changes in the prices of the intermediate goods used in the industry. Hence, efficiency gains thanks to cheaper foreign inputs upstream can affect downstream productivity indirectly, and with it the wages of the workers. This is the perspective that motivates our empirical approach: earlier production tiers, performed offshore, can affect the wages of workers employed domestically in the later stages of GVC, closer to final demand.

2.2 Production fragmentation, GVC, and wages in Europe—the empirical evidence

The recent empirical literature on the fragmentation–wage nexus generally follows the influential theoretical models of trade-in-tasks (Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg 2008, 2012; Baldwin and Robert-Nicoud 2014). This literature consists of several different strands: the sets of studies using respectively industry-level data, firm-level data, worker-level data, and matched worker-firm data (see Hummels et al. 2018 for an excellent review). The crude division of workers into skilled and unskilled in a cross-section of industries that marked the first wave of studies on the labour market consequences of production fragmentation for different workers is no longer sufficient. In particular, tasks clearly differ from skills, especially when the objective is to gauge the potential offshorability of certain occupations (Blinder 2006; Blinder and Krueger 2013).Footnote 14 Consequently, to evaluate the consequences of globalisation for heterogeneous groups of workers, empirical research on international trade has adopted the task setting, originally developed to analyse variation in skill requirements within occupations and the changing task composition of labour markets owing to technological progress (among others: Spitz-Oener 2006; Autor et al. 2003; Acemoglu and Autor 2011; Autor and Handel 2013).

Much of the task-based work on the labour market implications of production fragmentation (offshoring) refers to the United States (Acemoglu and Autor 2011; Ebenstein et al. 2014; Autor et al. 2014). And a good share of this literature focuses on the so-called ‘China syndrome’ or ‘China shock’ (among others: Autor et al. 2014; Shen and Silva 2018; Feenstra and Sasahara 2018).Footnote 15

Not many papers are closely related to our research, with its focus on Europe, microdata and task-profile (we exclude the literature using industry-level data, such as Polgár and Wörz 2010; Parteka and Wolszczak-Derlacz 2015; Wolszczak-Derlacz and Parteka 2018). The more detailed evidence, which considers the heterogeneity of workers in terms of individual characteristics, is strongly dependent on the availability of microdata, which is why just a handful of countries (and principally Germany) have dominated the debate.

Of the European countries, Germany is by far the most intensively studied. Becker and Muendler (2015) documented significant trade-task changes in the German economy over three decades (1979–2006): imports of intermediates grew, and the German workforce increasingly specialised in non-offshorable activities Baumgarten et al. (2013). demonstrated an adverse effect of offshoring on wages, depending on the task profile of the occupations involved (higher non-routine content effectively protects workers from the wage repercussions of production relocation). Becker et al. (2013) used plant level data for German multinationals to examine the relationship between offshoring and the composition of skills and tasks in Germany. Their results suggested positive relationships between offshore employment and the shares of non-routine and interactive tasks in the total wage bill. But they also found that in any case the economic impact of offshoring on the composition of the labour force is modest and concluded that much of the variation in wage shares is explained by other factors.

The evidence on other countries confirms that offshoring has uneven effects on workers, depending on skill/task type. Hummels et al. (2014), on matched worker-firm data from Denmark, demonstrated that offshoring increases the wages of the skilled and decreases those of the low-skilled. However, considering that skills do not overlap perfectly with tasks, the wage effects vary according to tasks (that is, workers performing routine tasks suffer the most). Geishecker and Görg (2013) merged industry-level data on offshoring for the United Kingdom with individual-level data on wages (their setting thus resembles ours) and showed that the offshoring of services affects the wages of low- and medium-skilled workers negatively and leads to a wider earnings gap between skilled and unskilled. Finally, Geishecker et al. (2010), combined data for Germany, the United Kingdom, and Denmark to determine whether differences in labour market institutions may have produced differences in the wage impact of outsourcing. Surprisingly, they found that the estimated effects are actually quite similar across the three countries and fairly small.

In our study we also check whether the impact of GII on wages in Europe depends on the source of the imported inputs. The literature has confirmed that the provenance of inputs is indeed critical. Becker et al. (2013) showed that offshoring by German multinationals to low-income countries (except Central and Eastern Europe) produces a stronger employment response in Germany. Wolszczak-Derlacz and Parteka (2018) examined a 40-country worldwide sample. Using industry-level wage data and breaking the input–output offshoring measure down according to source country, they found a negative (but small) wage impact of offshoring to low-wage countries.Footnote 16

As far as task evaluation is concerned, to date most task-based labour market studies have focused on a single country for which the classification of tasks is available: the U.S. (Autor and Handel 2013; Autor et al. 2014; Ebenstein et al. 2014) or Germany (Baumgarten 2015; Becker et al. 2013). Alternatively, they simply assume that the task profile of workers in the countries they want to analyse is the same as in the United States (based on O*NET data), which Lewandowski et al. (2019) have shown to be a considerable simplification. For works along these lines, see Goos et al. (2014), Arias et al. (2014), Lewandowski et al. (2017), and Hardy et al. (2018), applying O*NET to LFS data in the European Union and/or OECD countries; or the World Development Report (2016), which utilises the typology of occupations developed by Autor (2014), based on U.S. data, to analyse changes in employment shares in developing countries.

Few studies have explicitly addressed the GVC-wage nexus merging industry-level data on GVC with individual data on workers’ wages. Shen and Silva (2018) studied the relationship between the value added of exports from China and wages in the United States, demonstrating that the effects depend on the position of the Chinese industry in the GVC (its degree of downstreamness). Similarly, Szymczak et al. (2019) use the CEECs sample to show how the position of industries in the production chain affects wages. Parteka and Wolszczak-Derlacz (2019), constructing a cross-sectional dataset on nine European countries and the United States, is the work most resembling the present paper in terms of data and methodology. Those results suggested that growing cross-border industrial interdependence (measured as the foreign share in the industry’s value added) decreases the wages of some workers, namely those who perform more routine tasks and are less well educated. But effects detected empirically are quite modest. In any event, that study did not cover the entire European labour market; it used a fairly crude classification of workers by task content of jobs; and it failed to explore the role of backward production linkages in multistage GVCs. The subsequent analysis addresses these shortcomings.

3 Empirical setting

In our study we consider workers from 28 European countries including Western Europe—W (AT, BE, CH, DE, DK, FI, FR, IE, IT, NL, NO, SE, UK); Southern Europe—S (CY, ES, EL, PT) and Central and Eastern Europe—CEECs (BG, CZ, EE, HU, LT, LU, LV, PL, RO, SI, SK). We match micro-level information (from EU-SILC) with sector-level statistics on countries’ dependence on foreign inputs based on WIOD (release November 2016), described below.

3.1 The measurement of GII

In order to measure countries’ and industries’ global dependence on imported inputs we draw on Timmer et al. (2016) new accounting framework which they use to explain the global trade slowdown.Footnote 17 Following them, we employ the newest available release of industry-level data from WIOD (November 2016) and use global import intensity of production’ (GII) index.Footnote 18GII is a backward measure which takes into account ‘the imports by the country in which the last stage of production takes place, as well as imports by other countries that are involved in earlier stages of production. Moreover, it includes imports of intermediate goods as well as intermediate services (such as supporting business services).’ (Timmer et al. 2016, p.4). It thus noticeably differs from offshoring intensity measured (in the spirit of Feenstra and Hanson 1999) at one stage of production only as a ratio of imported inputs to the industrial output value. GII measures all imports of intermediates by all countries in the value chain induced by a dollar of output of a final product. Consequently, its interpretation in terms of total contribution of foreign inputs into the domestic production is also straightforward—contrary to the measures based on export decomposition (vertical specialisation, VS—domestic value added in exports: Hummels et al. 2001; Koopman et al. 2014 or the VAX ratio—value added exports: Johnson and Noguera 2012).Footnote 19

We adopt a sequential approach to measure the dependence on foreign inputs, in other words we use the information on imported inputs employed in the last stage of production and on imported inputs employed in all the previous production stages (backward movement along the GVC). Formally, GII is computed as follows (Timmer et al. 2016, p. 10–12).Footnote 20 Let a(t,j)(u,k) be the value of inputs from industry t in country j required by industry u in country k to produce one dollar of its gross output. Good z is finalised in (s,i). All imports needed in each stage (tier) of production of good z are defined as:

$$h_{z}^{tier0} = \mathop \sum \limits_{u}^{{}} \mathop \sum \limits_{k \ne i}^{{}} a\left( {u,k} \right)\left( {s,i} \right)$$
$$h_{z}^{tier1} = \mathop \sum \limits_{t}^{{}} \mathop \sum \limits_{j \ne k}^{{}} \mathop \sum \limits_{u}^{{}} \mathop \sum \limits_{k}^{{}} [a\left( {t,j} \right)\left( {u,k} \right)\left] \right[a\left( {u,k} \right)\left( {s,i} \right)]$$

\(h_{z}^{tier2} = \ldots\) and so on, so the GII of z is equal to:

$$GII = h_{z}^{{}} = h_{z}^{tier0} + h_{z}^{tier1} + h_{z}^{tier2} + \ldots = \mathop \sum \limits_{t}^{{}} \mathop \sum \limits_{j \ne k}^{{}} \widehat{{a_{z} }} \left( {t,j} \right)\left( {u,k} \right)$$
(1)

where \(\widehat{{a_{z} }}\left( {t,j} \right)\left( {u,k} \right)\) is the delivery of inputs from (t,j) to (u,k) induces by the production of good z.

The production of intermediate inputs provided by the first-tier suppliers involves intermediates from second-tier suppliers and so on, summing up to all tiers of production given by GII. GII takes the values between 0 and 1 where zero means that finalizing country does not need to import intermediates in any stage of production of product z while the value of 1 indicates a complete dependence on foreign inputs along the value chain.Footnote 21

Figure 1 shows average values of GII in our sample of 28 European countries in 2014 (being the last year of input–output data in WIOD, as well as the last year of our analysis; values are weighted by the industry value added). GII (expressed as an index 0–1,where the value of 1 corresponds to a total, 100% dependence of the final production on imported inputs, calculated along all the backward stages of production) range between 13% of final output in Greece to 55% in Luxembourg. European countries are generally more dependent on foreign inputs than big economies like US or China, where GII equals to (respectively) 0.08 and 0.13 (8 and 13%). In almost all of the countries less than half of GII is driven by imports by the country in which the last stage of production took place (in black), while the other half depends on inputs imported in earlier stages of production which involve third-country trade. It means that conventionally measured offshoring (which accounts for imported intermediates employed in the last stage of production) can severely underestimate the importance of global sourcing and its indirect effects on domestic labour markets.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Source: own calculations based on WIOD (release Nov 2016) and Timmer et al. (2016) methodology

Global import intensity of production (GII, index 0–1)—28 European countries versus the U.S. and China. Notes: Average values calculated across 56 industries and weighted by industrial value added (VAijt). GII calculated as in Eq. 1. GII is a sum of the values for the last stage of production only and of all the remaining tiers of production. 28 European countries (Europe 28) included in the sample: W—Western Europe (AT, BE, CH, DE, DK, FI, FR, IE, IT, NL, NO, SE, UK); S— Southern Europe (CY, ES, EL, PT); CEECs—Central and Eastern European Countries (BG, CZ, EE, HU, LT, LU, LV, PL, RO, SI, SK).

Some of the industries are much more dependent on foreign inputs than the others—global import intensity of services production tends to be much lower than for goods (Timmer et al. 2016: 4). Table 2 reports values of GII for the whole economy (all industries) and by sectors, for comparison we show the data typical for Europe 28 and the three subgroups of European countries, split into Western (W), Southern (S) and Central and Eastern (CEECs) European countries in 2014. It is clear that GII is the highest in manufacturing industries (for instance, in Western Europe GVC imports account for 42% of final manufacturing production), but the ratio of imported intermediates to the final output is also considerable in services. In Europe, value chains finalised in CEECs countries are more dependent on imported inputs than in the case of Western or Southern European countries. This is a sign of significant involvement of CEECs into GVCs.

Table 2 Global import intensity of production (GII, index 0–1), 2014—by sectors.

Our further input is to compute the variants of GII which measure the reliance of the value chain linked to the production of z on intermediates coming from different subgroups of countries. At every backward stage of production, we use the information on the source (country) of intermediates, and sum them over those coming from: high income countries only (GIIHIC) and from selected developing countries only (GIIDEV), encompassing China and India.Footnote 22 In particular, using the latter measure we will assess direct and indirect effects of production dependence on the South countries characterised by lower labour costs. According to the values reported in Table 3 (Panel B) GVC imports coming from these developing countries account for a small share of final output—in the word it is only 3% while in Europe even less (2%). In manufacturing it is 6%, so still not much. At the same time, values of GIIHIC are considerably higher than GIIDEV: in Europe, on average, the value of imported intermediates employed along the value chain and coming from other well developed economies accounts for 14% of final output (31% in manufacturing).Footnote 23 It means that given the magnitude of the dependence on developing countries inputs, the negative consequences of imports coming from these countries are likely to be overvalued.

Table 3 Global import intensity of production (GII), 2014—split by the source of intermediate inputs along the value chain (GIIHICand GIIDEV).

Cross-country variability in GII, as well as the changes over time (2005–2014, the years of our analysis) are shown in Table 4. Additionally, to show the importance of the proper backward measurement of foreign inputs, we report the values of GII_tier1 encompassing imports from first-tier suppliers only and vertical specialization. The interpretation of the GII’s values is as follows: for instance, one dollar of goods and services finalized in Germany (DE) generated around 16 dollar cent of imports worldwide in 2005 increasing to 20 dollar cent in 2014. At the same time, imported intermediates used in the last stage of production only, accounted for 7 cents in 2005 and 9 cents in 2014 per each one dollar of final German production. For most of the countries (the only exceptions are Sweden, SE and Spain, ES) the change in the measures has been positive, which is a clear sign of increasing GVC involvement. It can be either due to the imports rise in any stage of production, or due to new stages of production (with similar import requirements) added to GVC causing its lengthening.

Table 4 Import intensity of production based on first tier imports only (GII_tier1) and including all imports in the GVC (GII), vertical specialization—by country (Europe28).

3.2 Microdata and descriptive statistics on wages

The micro-level data for our empirical analysis comes from EU-SILC database (Statistics on Income and Living Conditions) obtainable from Eurostat.Footnote 24 The EU-SILC provides comparable cross-sectional and longitudinal multidimensional microdata on income, poverty, social exclusion and living conditions, and is thus suitable for cross-country comparisons.Footnote 25 In this study we use cross-sectional type of data provided by EU-SILC (optionally, longitudinal data is available but it lacks some crucial variables needed in our empirical analysis, such as the sector of employment used to merge micro-data with sector-level data on GII). Data are gathered in two types of files depending on the level of response: individual and household ones. We combine individual files (personal data and personal register) with household information (household data and household register) on the basis of the following matching variables: year, country, individual id and household id. Our analysis is performed on the pooled waves of EU-SILC data covering the years 2005–2014Footnote 26 and 28 European countries.Footnote 27

The key variable of interest (our dependent variable)—hourly wage—is computed on the basis of variables from EU-SILC data files. Using the information on gross annual employee income,Footnote 28 the number of months worked during the income reference year and the average number of hours worked per week we are able to calculate hourly earnings (gross hourly wages) with the assumption of the average number of 4.2 weeks per one worked month.Footnote 29 Alternatively (we will use this variable for the robustness checks), we have run additional estimations using another way of calculating the dependent variable. Instead of hourly wages we used total annual income, i.e. employees’ gross cash or quasi-cash income (monetary compensation of employees in cash payable by the employer).Footnote 30 Wages are expressed in EUR with the use of conversion rate provided in EU-SILC. Additionally, we use HICP from Eurostat to report wages in real terms (HICP 2015 = 100).

For the purpose of our analysis we employ other micro-level variables from EU-SILC which are important for the determination of wages. The set of individual characteristics consist of: sex, age, marital status, education (based on the highest ISCED level attained and reclassified into groups with high education: ISCED level 6, 7 and 8 or less than high education: ISCED from 0 to 4).Footnote 31 Labour characteristics include: the information on the size of the company an employee is working for (micro firm if less than 11 persons are employed, medium: 11–49 employees and big—50 or more employees), the type of contract (permanent versus temporal, including work contract of limited duration), managerial position (if the work includes supervisory responsibilities), the sector of employment (NACE Rev 1.1 for 2004–2007 and NACE Rev.2 for 2008 onwards) and occupation (following 2 digit ISCO-88 classification till 2011 and ISCO-08 afterwards).Footnote 32

We restrict our sample to full time workers within working age population 18–65 for whom we have the data allowing us to compute wage measure as well as the information about their occupation and sector of employment. Additionally, we do not take into account armed force occupations. In order to eliminate outlier values in our sample, we correct top and bottom distribution of wages. At the bottom we trim the distribution at the 1/100 of country-specific mean and at the bottom wages greater than ten times the national median are set to ten times the national median. The trimming is performed for each year and each country separately.Footnote 33 In Table 1A in the online appendix we report summary statistics of all the micro-level variables. Average worker in our sample is 41 years old with 19 years of work experience and earns 14 euro per hour; 60% of workers are males and 32% have tertiary education; 56% are married, almost half of the workers are employed in a big firm, 89% have permanent contract while 11% work with a temporary job contract, 28% hold managerial position which includes formal responsibility for supervising a group of other employees also only during some times and doing some of the work.Footnote 34

An important feature of our data is that we are able to quantify the routine content of jobs of particular workers. For this purpose we use country-specific routine task intensity indices (RTIs) which not only reflect the differences in routinisation between particular occupations, but also between countries (Lewandowski et al. 2019).Footnote 35 RTIs are based on survey data from OECD’s PIAAC, the World Bank’s Skills Toward Employment and Productivity (STEP), plus the China Urban Labor Survey (CULS), which closely mirrors the occupational task measurements in Acemoglu and Autor (2011) based on the U.S. O*NET data. Lewandowski et al. (2019) document that the relative importance of various tasks differs between countries for workers performing seemingly similar jobs. Given that they find substantial cross-country differences in the content of work, also within occupations, we use RTIs that are country-occupation-specific and accordingly measure differences in routinisation between countries and between occupations.Footnote 36

Given that we are primarily interested in the evolution of wages, in Fig. 2 we show boxplots of wages by task quartile and, additionally, by skill group. For this purpose, we compute country-specific quartiles of RTI indices which allows us to divide workers into four categories where the bottom category contains workers with the lowest degree of job routinisation (1st quartile of RTI) while the top category refers to workers with the highest degree of job routinisation (4st quartile of RTI). Importantly, thanks to the use of country-specific routinisation indices, the job routinisation of each worker is assessed here with respect to the national distribution of tasks. Skill groups (1–4 where 1 is the lowest and 4 the highest) are defined on the basis of ILO (2012) methodology mapping major ISCO groups to skill levels. Unsurprisingly, higher wages are paid to workers performing occupations which require high skills and are less routine. The box plotsFootnote 37 also show noticeable dispersion of wages within each category.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Source: Own calculations based on EU-SILC. RTI quartiles based on country-specific indices of job routinisation from Lewandowski et al. (2019), skill categories based on mapping main ISCO groups into skill groups according to ILO (2012)

Wages by job routinisation intensity and by skill intensity (Europe 28, 2014).

There are of course noticeable cross-country differences in wages. In Table 5 we show average wages, by RTI quartile, in the three groups of European countries (in Table 11A in the online Appendix we show analogous country-specific values). Unsurprisingly, the highest wages are reported for those performing low routine occupations, meaning the first quartile of RTI (e.g. in Western Europe the average wage in such occupations equals almost 24 euro per hour, while in CEECs only 5 euro). Workers employed in the most routine intensive jobs earn considerably less. This tendency is stable across countries.

Is this a sign that major GII is among significant determinants of wages, once all the other factors influencing wage determination process are accounted for? We will address this question in the next section.

4 Empirical model and estimation results

4.1 The results

Our empirical strategy is based on the estimation of individual wage regression augmented with the measure of the dependence of domestic production on foreign inputs—GII—typical for sector in which a given person is employed. Similar approach has been adopted (among others) by Baumgarten et al. (2013), Geishecker et al. (2010) and Ebenstein et al. (2014) who merged micro-level data on labor market outcomes with sectoral observation on offshoring intensity or Parteka and Wolszczak-Derlacz (2019) who combined individual wage data with statistics on sectoral foreign value added share.

First, we estimate the following model:

$$ln{\text{wage}}_{ijoct} = \alpha + {\upbeta }X_{it} + \gamma Job_{it} + \delta RTI_{oc} + \theta GII_{jct} + \mu lnProd_{jct} + D_{t} + D_{j} + D_{c} + \varepsilon_{ijoct}$$
(2)

where i denotes a worker employed in sector j in occupation o in country c at time t. We regress the log of the gross hourly wage (lnwage) on a set of personal characteristics X (sex, age, age2, marital status, education), job characteristics Job (firm size, type of the contract, managerial position) and information on the routine content of occupation RTI (routine task intensity index). We augment the model with the information on global import intensity (GII where GII = [0—1]) so coefficient θ represents the elasticity of wages with respect to globally measured dependence on foreign inputs. As more productive sectors are likely to pay higher wages, in some specifications we also include productivity (Prod), measured as the ratio of real sectoral value added to the total number of hours worked by employees, as an additional industry-level control. Additionally we include time effects Dt (controlling for time specific economic fluctuations, e.g. 2008/2009 crisis), industry dummies Dj (allowing for all the remaining industry-specific characteristics or wage regulations) and country dummies Dc (picking up all country-specific conditions, including labour market institutions and wage-setting mechanisms).Footnote 38

Equation (2) is estimated with the use of weighted regression (with normalized weights based on original personal weights provided by EU-SILC and normalized by the number of observations per country to sum up to 10,000 within each country) and robust standard errors which are clustered at the country-industry level. Given the potential endogeneity between the use of foreign inputs (and thus offshoring activity) and wages, we adopt instrumental variables estimation.Footnote 39 We instrument the global import intensity of a country by the contemporaneous composition of global imports of other countries related to the lagged value of their final product, which is close in spirit to the approach of Autor et al. (2013). Indeed, we find that instruments are correlated with GII and orthogonal to changes of individual workers’ wages. The choice of the instruments is confirmed by under- and weak identification tests.

The first two columns of Table 6 present estimation results of the basic specification (Eq. 2) based on pooled OLS, they differ in a set of explanatory variables (information on contract type and managerial position are not available for all workers). In columns 3 and 4 we report analogous IV estimations. On average, male, older, married workers with higher education earn more. Additionally, higher wages are characteristic for employees working in medium and big companies (in relation to small firms), having a permanent contact and holding managerial position which requires supervisory responsibilities (columns 2 and 4). Hence, in all specifications, the obtained coefficients concerning workers’ individual and job characteristic are in line with the microeconomic theory of wage determination (the Mincerian model)—to save space, in the subsequent tables we will not report them. Unsurprisingly, the degree of routinisation, measured by RTI, is a significant and negative determinant of wage level.

When it comes to industry-level characteristics, employment in more productive sectors is associated with higher wages while sectors with more intensive process of international production fragmentation (higher GII) offer lower wages. Additionally, in Table 7 (and in the subsequent tables) we present the regression with plain GII and RTI and also with the interaction between GII and RTI. In the augmented specifications (with interaction) the marginal effect of a change in GII on wages also depends on the value of RTI. Thus the interaction could help to clarify whether the negative relationship between GII and log wage is attenuated or magnified in countries and industries where occupations are typically more routine. The results suggest that in general the degree of routinisation is a highly robust determinant of wages (clearly the more routine the job, the lower the wage). The interaction between GII and RTI is not statistically significant, so we conclude that wages are determined by a set of microlevel variables (Mincerian framework), the type of tasks performed on the job, and GII (independent of routinisation). As reported in Table 7, the negative relationships between hourly wage and job routines and between GII and wages are not sensitive to the set of other control variables included into the model as wage determinants. The magnitude of the wage effect of GII is higher when the endogeneity is taken into account, from now on we will concentrate on IV estimations. To save space, we will report coefficients for GII, the routinisation and interaction GIIxRTI only, but all the models include personal and employment controls, industry characteristics (productivity), time, country and industry dummies.Footnote 40

Table 5 Wages by job routinisation intensity (Western Europe, Southern Europe and CEECs, 2014).

The basic specification was estimated on the full sample of countries, sectors and GII independently of the source country of imports. In order to understand what drives the effect of GII on wages we re-run the estimations taking into account GII computed on the base of information of inputs employed in the value chain and coming exclusively from high income countries (HIC), from developing countries (DEV) included in WIOD and from the RoW (in fact including mainly the aggregate for the developing world—see the note under Table 3). According to the results reported in Table 8, the negative impact of import intensity on wages is much higher when inputs employed along the production chain come from the developing countries and/or RoW (columns 4 and 6), than when GII is measured with GVC imports from high income countries (columns 1 and 2). Such a result indicates that the process of transferring production to low income (thus low wage) countries, which are characterised by lower cost of production, and then importing inputs from them along the sequential production chain force native workers to accept lower wages. Such a result is much weaker when we consider only GVC imports coming from less competitive high income countries (columns 1 and 2).

Given that our sample consists of workers from different countries and sectors, we also explore these sources of results’ heterogeneity (these results are reported in online appendix B). According to the estimations of Eq. 2 conducted on sample splits, the negative and statistically significant effect of GII on wages concerns mainly workers from Western and Southern European countries (Table 1B in online appendix B) and the effect is much more pronounced for workers employed in manufacturing then in services (Table 2B in online appendix B). Additionally, in a model focusing on workers in Western Europe, the interaction between GII and RTI is negative and statistically significant, which indicates that GII is connected with a sharper decline in the wages of workers doing more routine labour (the opposite is true for workers from Central and Eastern Europe (Table 1B in online appendix B). It is plausible, that this is the effect of offshoring between Western and Eastern Europe, as routine tasks are ‘moved’ to Eastern Europe, where the demand for workers performing them increases.Further, we simultaneously consider diverse sources of heterogeneity. Table 3B reports the results for workers from Western European countries and when GII is differentiated according to the source of inputs along the value chain. The negative association between GII and wages is confirmed for workers from Western Europe and its magnitude is the highest when GVC inputs are imported from developing countries. Additionally, as reported in Table 4B, this negative effect is felt by Western European workers employed in manufacturing.

As our study seems to be the first to employ GII to measure global dependence on foreign inputs, it is thus interesting to compare our results to the ones obtained with conventional measures of value added trade and offshoring (Johnson and Noguera 2012; Koopman et al. 2014; Wang et al. 2013; Feenstra and Hanson 1999), as they may differ. To do so, we have computed: OFF- imports of intermediate inputs in proportion to the value added of a given sector (traditional offshoring measure as in Feenstra and Hanson 1999); FVA/EXP−foreign value added in exports (derived from export decomposition following Wang et al. (2013); FVA_FIN/EXP—foreign value added used in final goods exports (Wang et al 2013); FVA_INT/EXP—foreign value added used in intermediate exports over total exports (Wang et al. (2013); VS/EXP—vertical specialisation measured as the ratio of foreign value added (FVA) and pure double counting from foreign sources (FDC) to exports (Koopman et al. 2014); VS1/EXP—vertical specialisation measured as the ratio of foreign value added (FVA) plus total pure double counting (PDC) to exports (Wang et al. 2013).

As expected, our measure (GII) is closely correlated with the other measures of value added trade/offshoring (high pairwise correlation coefficients, reported in Table R2Footnote 41). To show how alternative measures of value added trade and offshoring work in the framework of Mincer regressions, Table 9 reports the results where these alternative measures have been included in the set of regressors, instead of GII. Additionally, in column 2 we report the results taking into account only import intensity of production measured at the last stage (GII_tier1) while GII_except_tier1 (column 3) takes into account previous cross-country and cross-industry links along the entire production sequence but except the last stage (indirect exposure). The coefficients are always negative and statistically significant. In order to assess the relative strength of each of the different measures of GVC, we provide standardized regression coefficients that show the effect on wages of a one-standard-deviation increase in any given GVC measure. Comparing the results obtained with GII, GII_tier1 and GII_except_tier1, the strongest effect is for total GII while the weakest for direct exposure (GII_tier1). The differences in the magnitudes of standardised coefficients for the last stage of production and all stages except the last are not as significant, which could be due to the nature of sequential production and the interplay between various stages of the chain. However, the coefficients should be put in the perspective of the actual value of GII measures (see Table 4): the value of imported inputs used in the last stage (GII_tier1) is less than when all the backward stages of production are taken into account (GII).

4.2 Economic significance of the results

Based on the above results, one would conclude that the involvement of domestic industries into production fragmentation, measured globally along all the chain of production, impacts negatively mainly wages of Western European workers (once all other—individual, job, country and sectoral characteristics are controlled for).

How strong are the estimated effects in economic terms? In other words, how much wages in Europe changed due to increased GII? First of all, let’s remind that GII index ranges between 0 and 1. Hence, the estimates of log-linear model (2) indicate that and increase in GII by one unit (hence by 1, which is equivalent to a rise of GII by 100%) is associated with a change in hourly wage by \(\theta\)%. Taking into account the results for all sample (Europe28) the biggest estimated coefficient \(\theta\) is equal to − 0.316 (Table 7, column 4). We shall put it in the perspective of registered rise in GVC imports and data on wages in Europe. Table 10 shows the economic significance of the results (based on statistically significant estimates only reported in Tables 7, 8 and Table 3B in online appendix B) where we compare the results, split by the source of imports along the GVC, for all the sample and for Western European workers only, typically perceived in the literature as negatively exposed to the effects of production fragmentation.

Table 6 Estimation results (1)—GII among other determinants of wages in Europe.
Table 7 Estimation results (2)—GII as wage determinant in Europe (interaction with job routinisation, RTI and the inclusion of extended set of control variables).
Table 8 Estimation results (3)—GII as wage determinant in Europe, split according to the source of imports along the value chain.
Table 9 Estimations with different measures of GVC/ production fragmentation—standardized coefficients.
Table 10 Economic significance calculations.

According to our data, over the sample period GII (averaged over all industries) in the whole EU28 sample rose from 0.166 (= 16.6% of final output) in 2005 to 0.202 (= 20.2%) in 2014, hence GII rose by 0.0354 (= 3.54p.p.). Combining it with the coefficient estimate from Table 7 (column 4) and with the data on average hourly wage in the initial year (15.75 eur per hour), we find that the change in GVC imports in the period 2005–2014 resulted in average cumulated wage decrease by only 0.176 eur [= 3.54/100*(− 0.316)*15.75 eur]. Assuming 1564 of working hours per year (source: EUKLEMS 2018, EU28_output_17ii) this is equivalent to an annual earnings ‘loss’ of 30.6 euro. In other words, if the use of inputs along the GVC had remained unchanged with respect to year 2005, hourly wage of European workers would have been higher by 18 cents in 2014. This effect is not large. As reported in Table 10, the magnitude of the effect estimated for Europe 28 is, however, almost twice higher if we consider the impact of GVC imports coming from developing countries.

The picture changes a bit if we consider only workers from Western Europe and developments in GII therein. The counterfactual calculations for Western European workers result in cumulative hourly wage ‘decline’ by 0.16 euro which is equivalent to 27.45 euro less of annual earning. This effect is higher when we take into account stronger effect exhibited by GVC imports from developing countries (and measured by GIIDEV). If the use of inputs along the GVC coming from developing countries had remained unchanged with respect to year 2005, hourly wage of European workers in 2014 would have been higher by 0.7 euro (annual loss of 122 euro). Hence, the effect of global import intensity of production on wages in Western Europe is economically small.

4.3 Extensions and robustness checks

We considered numerous robustness checks and extensions of the basic model estimated for workers from 28 European countries. The general result of the negative effect of GII on wages of all European workers is robust to: the way we measure our dependent variable (Table 2A in the online appendix) and changes in the weighting scheme adopted in the regression (Table 3A in the online appendix) None of these changes alters in a considerable way our main result: negative influence of global import intensity of production on wages of European workers.

Then, even though our model incorporates sector and country specific fixed effects, and thus should capture all the other wage determinants not explicitly included into the model, we considered the extended estimations including additional control variables. Following Geishecker et al. (2010) and Schäfer and Gottschall (2015) we considered differences in labour market institutions and country-specific wage bargaining schemes (Table 4A in online appendix A). We also included variables related to country-level and industry-level trade openness (Table A in online appendix A). Confirming other studies (e.g. Hummels et al. 2014), sectors which are more export oriented (with higher share of export to value added) are characterised by higher wages. In line with the literature on the role of technology in wage determination process (Autor et al. 2003; Acemoglu and Autor 2011; Goos et al. 2014), we also took into account the potential role played by technology and R&D (we employed industry-level variables on computing, communications and R&D equipment, expressed either as capital formation or stock—Table 6A in the online appendix). The inclusion of additional country-specific or sector specific variables do not change our main results and interestingly those additional variables are hardly statistical significant. Finally, our results are also not driven by any specific country or industry (we checked it by eliminating, one-by-one, countries or industries from the sample—the results over such limited subsamples showing mean, minimum and maximum coefficients are reported in Table 7A and Table 8A in online appendix A). We also split time of our analysis into pre and post crises; respectively we run regressions for two time periods: 2005–2008 and 2009–2014. As indicated in Table 9A, indeed in the years before the crisis, when the growth of GII was more intensive then afterwards, the effect on wages was two times higher than in the years after 2009 when the slowdown of GII growth was observed (Timmer et al. 2016).

Finally, to check the average industry position in GVCs we introduced in our regression the upstreamness measure (UP) developed by Fally (2011) and Antràs et al. (2012). The index is based on forward linkages and measures an industry’s average distance from the final stage of production.Footnote 42 The results of an augmented estimation of the wage model are reported in Table R1: neither UP nor its interaction with GII is statistically significant. The other explanatory variables (microlevel Mincerian determinants of wages, routinisation of occupation, degree of GVC dependency measured by GII) explain up to three quarters of wage variability in our sample.

5 Conclusions

In this paper we have attempted to contribute to the empirical literature on microeconomic consequences of cross-border production links for European workers. We have addressed several limits of single-country studies on offshoring/production fragmentation and wages. We have used comparable worker-level data from 28 European countries matched with industrial statistics in a methodologically uniform and generally accepted (Mincerian) framework, which should provide a robust set of facts concerning the effects of GVC on wages in Europe. We considered differences in countries level of development or labour market institutions, sectoral specificity, the heterogeneity of foreign inputs according to source countries’ characteristics; we took into account country-specific task content of jobs affecting wage levels. The way we measured fragmentation within GVCs (global import intensity of production, GII, computed with newest 2016 World Input–Output Database) allowed us to trace back the involvement of sectors into the global structure of production. This measure, contrary to conventional measures of offshoring, captures imports of goods and services needed in any backward stage of the production of the final product and involves third-country trade. Such a view is more coherent with the key feature of GVC seen as cross-country multistage production network which results in cross-country industrial interdependence. Consequently, we believe it is the broadest European perspective adopted so far to the study of wage response to global production links and our conclusions are not country specific as in many related papers.

Our empirical analysis in the whole sample of 28 European countries shows a negative correlation between the wages of domestic labour and involvement in GVCs (importantly, not only when GVCs are measured by GII but also by other measures).Footnote 43 However, we find significant heterogeneity with respect to subsamples of European countries and with respect to the source of imports along the value chain. The downward pressure on wages concerns mainly workers in Western Europe and is driven by production links with developing countries.

Our results also confirm that the degree of occupation routinisation is a particularly robust determinant of wages (the more routine the job, the lower the wage), regardless of GVC participation. Additionally, in a model focusing on workers employed in Western European countries, GII is connected with the lower wages of workers doing more routine tasks. Hence, in line with our empirical data, Western European workers with more routine jobs may feel more threatened, especially when they have to compete with cheap labor in developing countries (or with the product of their labour, e.g. intermediate inputs produced by routine workers in developing countries), while their counterparts in Central and Eastern Europe may benefit from involvement in GVCs, thanks to greater demand for their labour (owing to the shift of more routine tasks to low-wage countries). Still, this negative wage effect of GII is rather modest and not strong in economic terms.

On the theoretical plane the relationship between wages and GVC involvement is far from straightforward, with insights from various models. The empirical results should be thus interpreted taking into account the intertwined relationship between GII, the level of surpluses, productivity, and wages in industries. Our general results (the negative correlation between GVC and wages) have at least a threefold explanation. One interpretation highlights the pressure on domestic workers to accept lower wages in fear of job displacement; the recent paper of Jeon and Kwon (2019), for instance, develops a theoretical model to show that the threat of offshoring can impact on wages even when there is no actual offshoring. The first interpretation can also be seen as a situation in which the fear of displacement offsets the potential productivity gains from involvement in GVC. Another explanation could be that country-industries with low surpluses, hence low wages, and that share it under bargaining, tend to use more GII in order to increase their surplus. Finally, our results might represent the effect of reallocation of labour between firms/sectors of differing productivity as in equilibrium model by Egger et al. (2015) in which offshoring, unlike international trade in final goods, may reallocate production workers from high- to low-productivity firms. The mechanism is quite simple: falling trade costs, starting from an excessively high level, cause international production fragmentation among the more productive firms, which frees some domestic labour and drives down wages.

An interesting extension of our work could be to separate, for each European downstream country, the parts of GVCs that fall into upstream European countries in the sample. For those GVCs, one could then relate upstream GVCs to downstream wages but also downstream wages to upstream wages in a separate Mincer regression.Footnote 44