Skip to main content
Log in

Markups and export-pricing strategies

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of World Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We analyze empirically export-price strategies across export destinations using detailed firm-product data. Most recent studies using disaggregated data to investigate why firms charge different prices for the same product on different markets focus on the cost component of prices and neglect the markup component. In this paper, we concentrate on the markup component and examine how variations in firms’ export prices may reflect price discrimination by comparing the markup of firms with different pricing strategies. We make use of detailed firm-level data for exporting firms in the Swedish food sector consisting of both manufacturing and intermediary trading firms. The paper documents the export-price variations within the two sub-sectors and explores how different price strategies correlate with markups. The results offer new information beyond the fact that exporters tend to have a higher markup. In particular, we find that firms in the food-processing sector with a greater ability to discriminate across markets mark their products up even more. This result points to the importance of underlying firm decisions in order to explain differences in export premiums across firms. In addition, the results reveal that markups are a complex function of firm and destination characteristics, and that the relationship between markups and pricing strategies in the manufacturing sector is not necessarily observed in other sectors of the supply chain.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The pricing-to-market literature stemming from Krugman (1987) typically deals with international price discrimination that is induced by exchange rate fluctuations.

  2. See, e.g., Engel and Rogers (1996) and Verboven (1996).

  3. See, e.g., Goldberg and Knetter (1996) and Tybout (2003).

  4. See the discussion in Martin (2012).

  5. Also related are papers following the tradition on spatial price discrimination developed by Hoover (1937). See, e.g., Greenhut et al. (1985) on reverse dumping.

  6. An early paper on price discrimination and markups in export markets is provided by Aw (1993). See also Aw et al. (2001) that investigates price variations across domestic and export markets.

  7. Several empirical studies have identified a positive correlation between average export prices and distance. In international-trade models with heterogeneous producers, this observation is consistent with product quality differences across export destinations. In particular, Baldwin and Harrigan (2007) explain this in a model where higher-quality products are more costly to produce but also more profitable and therefore better at penetrating distant markets. Similarly, Johnson (2012) shows that prices increase with distance and the difficulty of entering a market. In addition, he finds that more productive firms produce higher-quality goods and consequently can charge higher prices.

  8. In order to explain the positive correlation between export prices and distance, he proposes additive trade costs instead of iceberg trade costs, which also makes it possible to maintain the monopolistic-competition setting with CES preferences. Additive trade costs are also considered in Hummels and Skiba (2004).

  9. The argument in Görg et al. (2010) is that when the firm has found an export destination, it buys transport services and adds these to export prices. Thus, in reality f.o.b. prices may contain transport costs.

  10. Also, Alessandria and Kaboski (2011) propose a model where high-income consumers have higher search costs allowing firms to set higher prices for identical goods in rich countries.

  11. The food chain also contains agricultural and retail. These sectors are not included in the analysis since there are very few exporting firms in these sectors.

  12. Only wholesalers concentrating on agricultural products and food products are included in the analysis. All estimations control for time effects so that the longer time period for the food-processing sector only adds precision to the estimates. Restricting the period for food processors to 2003–2006 provides similar results to the ones discussed.

  13. These figures stem from LivsmedelsSverige (a joint platform for the industry, consumer groups and academia) and can be found on the following web page (downloaded 28th June 2011) http://www.livsmedelssverige.se/hem/statistik/livsmedelskedjan.html.

  14. In accordance with the standard Swedish industry classification, the food-processing industry includes production of beverages.

  15. McCorriston (2002) argues that the European food chain market consists of a multi-stage oligopoly where one “oligopolistic sector sells its output to another oligopolistic sector”.

  16. The food sector may be considered particularly well-suited for the purpose of this study since the scope for product differentiation within a given firm probably is more limited than in other manufacturing sectors. For instance, in our data material products with the CN-code 09102090 and 04031039 are described as crushed or ground saffron and yogurt (excl. flavored or with added fruit, nuts or cocoa), with added sugar or other sweetening matter, of a fat content, by weight, of >6.0 %, respectively. These categories are also examples of products that display high export-price variation at the firm level.

  17. In this section, we do not differentiate between firms in the food-processing industry and in wholesale.

  18. Only firms that exist for at least three consecutive years in our data are considered.

  19. Considering the production function \( Q_{ft} = F\left( {X_{ft} ,K_{ft} } \right) \) with variable inputs, \( X_{ft} \), and fixed capital, \( K_{ft} \), note that the marginal cost \( c_{ft} \) will be equal to \( \frac{{P_{ft}^{X} \delta X_{ft} }}{{\delta Q_{ft} }} \).

  20. International trade studies using the Roeger method are, e.g., Konings and Vandenbussche (2005) and Badinger (2007).

References

  • Alessandria, G., & Kaboski, J. P. (2011). Pricing to market and the failure of the absolute PPP. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 3(1), 91–127.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aw, B. Y. (1993). Price discrimination and markups in export markets. Journal of Development Economics, 42(2), 315–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aw, B. Y., Baatra, G., & Roberts, M. J. (2001). Firm heterogeneity and export–domestic price differentials: A study of Taiwanese electronics products. Journal of International Economics, 54(1), 149–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aw, B. Y., Chung, S., & Roberts, M. (2003). Productivity, output, and failure: A comparison of Taiwanese and South Korean manufacturers. Economic Journal, 113(491), 485–510.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Badinger, H. (2007). Has the EU’s single markup programme fostered competition? Testing for a decrease in mark-up ratios in EU industries. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 69(4), 497–519.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R., & Harrigan, J. (2007). Zeros, quality and space: Trade theory and trade evidence. (NBER Working Paper No. 13214).

  • Bastos, P., & Silva, J. (2010). The quality of a firm’s exports: Where you export matters. Journal of International Economics, 82(2), 99–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernard, A., Eaton, J., Jensen, J. B., & Kortum, S. (2003). Plants and productivity in international trade. American Economic Review, 93(4), 1268–1290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernard, A., Grazzi, M., & Tomasi, C. (2010). Intermediaries in international trade: Direct versus indirect modes of export. (Working Paper No. 199). National Bank of Belgium.

  • Brander, J. (1981). Intra-industry trade in identical commodities. Journal of International Economics, 11(1), 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brander, J., & Krugman, P. (1983). A “reciprocal dumping” model of international trade. Journal of International Economics, 15(3–4), 313–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Loecker, J. (2011). Recovering markups from production data. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 29(3), 350–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Loecker, J., & Warzynski, F. (2012). Markups and firm-level export status. American Economic Review, 102(6), 2437–2471.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engel, C., & Rogers, J. (1996). How wide is the border? American Economic Review, 86(5), 1112–1125.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fabiani, S., Druant, M., Hernando, I., Kwapil, C., Landau, B., Loupias, C., Martins, F., Mathä, T., Sabbatini, R., Stahl, H., & Stokman, A. (2005). The pricing behavior of firms in the euro area: New survey evidence. (ECB Working Paper No. 535).

  • Goldberg, P. K., & Knetter, M. M. (1996). Goods prices and exchange rates: What have we learned? (NBER Working Paper No. 01238).

  • Goldberg, P. K., & Knetter, M. M. (1999). Measuring the intensity of competition in export markets. Journal of International Economics, 47, 27–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Görg, H., Halpern, L., & Muraközy, B. (2010). Why do within firm-product export prices differ across markets? (Kiel Working Papers No. 1596). Kiel Institute for the World Economy.

  • Greenaway, D., Gullstrand, J., & Kneller, R. (2010). Firm heterogeneity and the geography of international trade. (GEP Discussion Papers No. 08/41). University of Nottingham.

  • Greenhut, M. L., Ohta, H., & Sailors, J. (1985). Reverse dumping: A form of spatial discrimination. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 34(2), 176–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gullstrand, J. (2011). Firm and destination-specific export costs: The case of the Swedish food sector. Food Policy, 36(2), 204–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, R. E. (1988). The relation between price and marginal costs in U.S. industry. Journal of Political Economy, 96(5), 921–947.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrigan, J., Ma, X., & Shlychkov, V. (2011). Export prices of U.S. firms. (NBER Working Paper No. 17706).

  • Hoover, E. (1937). Spatial price discrimination. The Review of Economic Studies, 4(3), 182–191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hummels, D., & Skiba, A. (2004). Shipping the good apples out? An empirical confirmation of the Alchian-Allen conjecture. Journal of Political Economy, 112(6), 1384–1402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, R. C. (2012). Trade and prices with heterogeneous firms. Journal of International Economics, 86(1), 43–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konings, J., & Vandenbussche, H. (2005). Antidumping protection and markups of domestic firms. Journal of International Economics, 65(1), 151–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. (1987). Pricing to market when the exchange rate changes. In S. W. Arndt & J. D. Richardson (Eds.), Real financial linkages among open economies. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lall, S. (2000). The technological structure and performance of developing country manufactured exports, 1985–1998. (QEH Working Paper Series, No. QEHWPS44).

  • Levinsohn, J., & Petrin, A. (2003). Estimating production functions using inputs to control for unobservables. Review of Economic Studies, 70(2), 317–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manova, K., & Zhang, Z. (2012). Export prices across firms and destinations. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127(1), 379–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, J. (2012). Markups, quality and transport costs. European Economic Review, 56(4), 777–791.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCorriston, S. (2002). Why should imperfect competition matter to agricultural economists? European Review of Agricultural Economics, 29(3), 349–371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melitz, M. J., & Ottaviano, G. I. (2008). Market size, trade, and productivity. Review of Economic Studies, 75(1), 295–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olley, S. G., & Pakes, A. (1996). The dynamics of productivity in the telecommunications equipment industry. Econometrica, 64(4), 1263–1297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rauch, J. E. (1999). Networks versus markets in international trade. Journal of International Economics, 48(1), 7–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roeger, W. (1995). Can imperfect competition explain the difference between primal and dual productivity measures? Estimates for U.S. manufacturing. Journal of Political Economy, 103(2), 316–330.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simonovska, I. (2011). Income differences and prices of tradables. (UCDavis Working Paper Series No. 10–15).

  • Tan, Q., & Sousa, C. (2011). Research on export pricing: Still moving toward maturity. Journal of International Marketing, 19(3), 1–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tybout, J. R. (2003). Plant and firm-level evidence on “new” trade theories. In K. Choi & J. Harrigan (Eds.), Handbook of international trade. Oxford: Basil-Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Verboven, F. (1996). International price discrimination in the European car market. Rand Journal of Economics, 27(2), 240–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank seminar participants at IFN Stockholm, University of Copenhagen, Lund University and Örebro University. We are also grateful to the conference participants at ETSG in Lausanne, September 2010, CAED Conference in London, September 2010, SNEE Conference in Mölle, May 2011, National Conference of Swedish Economists in Uppsala, September 2011, EITI in Tokyo, March 2012, RES Conference in Cambridge, March 2012, and NOITS in Reykjavik, May 2012. In addition, we thank an anonymous referee for helpful comments and Hans Carlsson for his advice. Financial support from Jan Wallander and Tom Hedelius Foundation is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Karin Olofsdotter.

Appendices

Appendix 1

Table 7 Variables and definitions

Appendix 2

2.1 Estimating firm markups

The benchmark approach to estimate firms’ markups is the framework of De Loecker and Warzynski (2012), which relies on the condition of cost minimization in order to relate elasticity of output, input shares and markups. By using a robust definition of the markup as the ratio between the price and the marginal cost, they show that the markup for firm f at time t may be defined as follows:

$$ \mu_{ft} = \frac{{\theta_{ft}^{X} }}{{\alpha_{ft}^{X} }} $$
(A1)

where \( \theta_{ft}^{X} = \frac{{\delta Q_{ft} X_{ft} }}{{\delta X_{ft} Q_{ft} }} \) is the output elasticity of the variable input \( X_{ft} \) and \( \alpha_{ft}^{X} = \frac{{P_{ft}^{X} X_{ft} }}{{P_{ft} Q_{ft} }} \) is the share of expenditures on input \( X_{ft} \) in total sales.Footnote 19 While the expenditure shares are directly obtained from the data, output elasticities have to be estimated. Note however that Q ft has to be adjusted by dividing it with exp(ε), where ε is the error term from the first stage regression, in order to sweep away variation in sales due to factors unrelated to input demand changes. The approach of De Loecker and Warzynski (2012) builds on two steps. The first one is to estimate the output elasticity by estimating the production function in line with the proxy methods of Olley and Pakes (1996) and Levinsohn and Petrin (2003). Once consistent estimates of the output elasticities are obtained, the markup in (A1) can be computed.

We use the translog-value added production function as in De Loecker and Warzynski (2012) with labor as a variable input while the capital stock (based on firms’ balance sheets) is assumed to be a dynamic input. This production function is used in the first stage together with a proxy for the productivity shock captured by inverting the demand for material (raw material and intermediate goods). Hence the proxy for productivity is captured by the expenditure on material, the stock of capital and the export status of the firm (similar variables as in De Loecker and Warzynski). Using this proxy in the production function implies that we may compute the productivity term as the difference between the expected output from the first stage and the sum of all inputs (using the estimated coefficients from the first stage production function as weights). The innovation of the productivity (given the coefficients from the first stage production function) is recovered by regressing productivity on its lag and additional variables influencing the productivity (we use export status and the propensity to exit). The production function parameters are then estimated in a second stage by relying on the moments that the innovation of the productivity is uncorrelated with capital (since it is decided a period before) and the lagged number of workers (since labor reacts on productivity). This finalize the procedure of estimating the parameters of the production function, and hence we may calculate the output elasticity for labor used in order to derive markups at the firm level.

2.2 Robustness—Roeger’s approach

As a robustness check of our results, we employ the commonly used method proposed by Roeger (1995) to estimate markups.Footnote 20 This method stems from Hall (1988) who showed how the markup can be obtained from the primal Solow residual (calculated from the production function) when there is market power. This residual, however, contains a productivity term that may cause endogeneity problems when the markup is estimated. Roeger demonstrated how this problem can be taken care of by subtracting the dual Solow residual (calculated from the cost functions) from the primal residual and the method only requires nominal data on firm sales and values of input factors. Thus, to obtain markups using Roeger’s approach, the following regression is to be estimated for each sector:

$$ \Updelta Y_{ft} = \mu \Updelta X_{ft} + \varepsilon_{ft} $$
(A2)

where ΔY ft = Δln(sales) − Δln(capital costs), ΔX ft = α Lft L ft [Δln(wage costs) −Δln(capital costs)] + α Mft M ft [Δln(materical costs) −Δln(capital costs)], and α Lft L ft = labor costs share in output = (wage costs)/(sales) and α Mft M ft = material costs share in output = (material costs) / (sales). Finally, μ is the markup to be estimated.

In order to analyze how the effect of firms’ price variations are related to their markups, we interact the price variable with the input growth composite, ΔX, according to:

$$ \Updelta Y_{ft} = \mu_{ 1} \Updelta X_{ft} + \mu_{ 2} [\Updelta X_{ft} \times \, PriceStrat_{fpt} ] \, + \beta \, PriceStrat_{fpt} + \varepsilon_{ft} $$
(A3)

In (A3), μ 2 reflects how the average markup changes with the variation in firm f’s export price of product p at time t, with PriceStrat fpt denoting the firm’s price strategy for product p. Although we do not observe changes in sales and inputs at the product level, there will be several observations for multi-product firms. β denotes the direct effect of the price variable.

The results in Table 8 are similar to those based on the method by De Loecker and Warzynski. In the benchmark estimations, positive and significant markups are found in both sectors. The estimated industry markup, however, is smaller, which echoes the finding in De Loecker and Warzynski. Looking at the interaction terms, the markup varies positively with the price variable only in the food-processing industry while the correlation is negative for wholesale.

Table 8 Relationship between markup and local price strategies using Roeger’s method

About this article

Cite this article

Gullstrand, J., Olofsdotter, K. & Thede, S. Markups and export-pricing strategies. Rev World Econ 150, 221–239 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-013-0178-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-013-0178-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation