Skip to main content
Log in

Financial remoteness and the net external position

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of World Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper shows that financially remote countries exhibit more positive net external positions, hence hinting at external funding problems for more remote countries. This finding is found to be stronger for emerging and developing countries. However, being located near financially very open countries, being in currency unions with creditor countries, or being highly integrated through financial and trade linkages with a ‘core’ country facilitates net external borrowing. We also find evidence that remoteness affects primarily the gross liability side of the external balance sheet and has a stronger impact on the net equity position than on the net debt position. Consequently, the paper demonstrates the important role of geographic and bilateral factors for a country’s net external wealth.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The net external position of the United States has been analysed in-depth over the last years. Gourinchas and Rey (2007) and Habib (2010), among others, find evidence for an ‘exorbitant privilege’ of the United States by running sizeable excess returns on its net external position before the crisis period. This goes along with a net foreign asset position that is less negative than suggested by the current account deficits of the United States.

  2. However, for example Huberman (2001) and Grinblatt and Keloharju (2001) propose that proximate investments can be better explained by a behavioural familiarity bias rather than by informational asymmetries.

  3. This corresponds to excluding countries from the reduced sample that are above the 80th percentile in terms of GDP per capita. All of these belong to the group of high-income countries as defined in the the World Bank’s World Development Indicators (2011) database. See Appendix 1 for a list of these countries.

  4. Australia and New Zealand are both very remote countries while also being substantial net debtors with net external positions of −61 and −89 %, respectively, over the period of 2005–2007. This circumstance supports the hypothesis of rich countries being less affected by financial remoteness. As a robustness check we also include Australia and New Zealand in the less advanced sample (based on their large net foreign liability positions), but find the results of the empirical analysis to hold nonetheless.

  5. This point will be further elaborated on in Sect. 3.3.1.

  6. Non-Ricardian behaviour means that the government’s budget constraint is not internalised by private economic agents.

  7. In addition, we included the share of natural resources in total exports as natural resource wealth can be associated with accumulated export revenue. On the other hand, it could also attract FDI inflows. Moreover, we include stock market capitalisation (as a ratio) to GDP, a domestic financial reform index from Abiad et al. (2008), and an aggregate measure of country risk. Among these variables, the financial reform index is the only one found to be significant (with a negative sign). However, the inclusion of these variables reduces the sample size substantially such that the regression results are not reported. We leave it for further research to explore for example the role of cultural factors such as differences in inter-temporal preferences.

  8. These are the United States, the United Kingdom, France, Germany, Japan, the Netherlands, Switzerland, and Ireland.

  9. In fact, very similar measures are used as robustness checks by Rose and Spiegel (2009).

  10. Based on Rose and Spiegel (2004), we use a strict currency union dummy that is equal to 1 if both countries are in a currency union.

  11. Consequently, this composite variable is zero for an economy without any contiguous countries.

  12. In line with the bilateral asset trade literature, we also construct weighting matrices based on common language between countries. However, we do not find significant coefficients for these variables.

  13. We also experiment with different weighting schemes, for example bilateral asset holdings and bilateral trade and find very similar results.

  14. This method reveals that Germany is the ‘core’ for many European countries (supplemented by Austria for Eastern European countries), the United Kingdom for many Asian countries, France for a lot of African countries, and Spain as well as the United States for Latin American countries.

  15. Here, the United States is the core country for the majority of Asian, European, and Latin American countries.

  16. For most Asian and Latin American countries, the United States is the largest export market.

  17. Due to recent updates by Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2007), we are able to include 149 countries in our analysis—compared to, for example, 61 countries for the period 1990 to 1998 in Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2002).

  18. Joint significance of the demographic variables is not found in the estimations presented in columns (2) and (8) of Table 3. This indicates that the demographic variables are of less importance for less advanced countries once we control for international financial remoteness based on pure distance measures.

  19. This is in line with Bussiere et al. (2006) who show that departures from Ricardian equivalence are especially present in liquidity constrained countries.

  20. However, the signs on the IFI and Chinn and Ito variables are negative.

    Table 4 Neighbourliness: contiguity
  21. Note that the number of observations decreases from 149 to 135, as data coverage of the CPIS database is lower than in the BIS database.

  22. More generally, the coefficient on financial remoteness is very robust to expanding the list of creditor countries. The reason is that the largest creditor countries are all located in Europe, North America, or Asia.

  23. The domestic financial reform index from Abiad et al. (2008) is found to be significant (with a negative sign), while reducing the sample to 88 observations. We leave it for further research to explore for example the role of cultural factors such as differences in inter-temporal preferences.

  24. For example, Klein et al. (2002) suggest that that FDI is information intensive, leading to problems for FDI investors to raise funding for their investments as they have more knowledge about their investment than outsiders. Theoretically, Razin et al. (1998) show that FDI investors are endowed with better information than other foreign investors.

  25. Strikingly, the demographic structure is only significant for the net debt position.

References

  • Abiad, A., Detragiache, E., & Tressel, T. (2008). A new database of financial reforms. (IMF Working Paper, No. 08/266). Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

  • Abramovitz, M. (1986). Catching up forging ahead and falling behind. The Journal of Economic History, 46(2), 385–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baicker, K. (2005). The spillover effects of state spending. Journal of Public Economics, 89(2–3), 529–544.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. (1986). Productivity growth, convergence, and welfare: What the long-run data show. American Economic Review, 76(5), 1072–85.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bank for International Settlements (BIS) (2009). Consolidated banking statistics, Basel, Switzerland.

  • Bussiere, M., Fratzscher, M., & Mueller, G. J. (2006). Current account dynamics in OECD and new EU member states: An intertemporal approach. Journal of Economic Integration, 21(3), 593–618.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Case, A. C., Hines, J. R. Jr., & Rosen, H. S. (1993). Budget spillovers and fiscal policy interdependence: Evidence from the States. Journal of Public Economics, 52(3), 285–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • CEPII (2006). GeoDist database. Paris.

  • Chinn, M. D., & Ito, H. (2008). A new measure of financial openness. Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis, 10(3), 307–320.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coval, J. D., & Moskowitz, T. J. (1999). Home bias at home: Local equity preference in domestic portfolios. Journal of Finance, 54(6), 2045–2073.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coval, J. D., & Moskowitz, T. J. (2001). The geography of investment: Informed trading and asset prices. Journal of Political Economy, 109(4), 811–841.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daude, C., & Stein, E. (2007). Longitude matters: Time zones and the location of foreign direct investment. Journal of International Economics, 71(1), 96–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fair, R., & Dominguez, K. (1991). Effects of the changing US demographic structure on macroeconomic equations. American Economic Review, 81(2), 1276–1294.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fazio, G., MacDonald, R., & Melitz, J. (2008). Trade costs, trade balances and current accounts: An application of gravity to multilateral trade. Open Economies Review, 19(5), 557–578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gourinchas, P.-O., & Rey, H. (2007). From world banker to world venture capitalist: US external adjustment and the exorbitant privilege. In R. Clarida (Eds.), G-7 current account imbalances: Sustainability and adjustment (pp. 11–55). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Grinblatt, M., & Keloharju, M. (2001). How distance, language, and culture influence stockholdings and trades. Journal of Finance, 56(3), 1053–1073.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huberman, G. (2001). Familiarity breeds investment. Review of Financial Studies, 14(3), 659–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Habib, M. M. (2010). Excess returns on net foreign assets—The exorbitant privilege from a global perspective. (ECB Working Paper No. 1158). Frankfurt, a.M.: European Central Bank.

  • Herrmann, S., & Winkler, A. (2009). Financial markets and the current account: Emerging Europe versus emerging Asia. Review of World Economics, 145(3), 531–550.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Higgins, M. (1998). Demography, national savings and international capital flows. International Economic Review, 39(2), 343–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund (IMF) (2009a). Coordinated portfolio investment survey. Washington, DC

  • International Monetary Fund (IMF) (2009b). Direction of trade statistics. Washington, DC

  • Klein, M., Peek, J., & Rosengren, E. (2002). Troubled banks, impaired foreign direct investment: The role of relative access to credit. American Economic Review, 92(3), 664–682.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane, P. R., & Milesi-Ferretti, G. M. (2001a). The external wealth of nations: Measures of foreign assets and liabilities for industrial and developing countries. Journal of International Economics, 55(2), 263–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane, P. R., & Milesi-Ferretti, G. M. (2001b). External capital structure: Theory and evidence. In: Horst Siebert (eds) The world’s new financial landscape: Challenges for economic policy (pp. 247–284). Kiel Institute of World Economics symposia and conference proceedings. Heidelberg and New York: Springer.

  • Lane, P. R., & Milesi-Ferretti, G. M. (2002). Long-term capital movements. In M. Gertler & K. Rogoff (Eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 16 (pp. 73–116). Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lane, P. R., & Milesi-Ferretti, G. M. (2007). The external wealth of nations mark II: Revised and extended estimates of foreign assets and liabilities, 1970–2004. Journal of International Economics, 73(2), 223–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane, P. R., & Milesi-Ferretti, G. M. (2008). International investment patterns. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(3), 538–549.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malloy, C. J. (2005). The geography of equity analysis. Journal of Finance, 54(6), 2045–2073.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, P., & Rey, H. (2004). Financial super-markets: Size matters for asset trade. Journal of International Economics, 64(2), 335–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld, M., & Rogoff, K. (2001). The six major puzzles in international macroeconomics. Is there a common cause? In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 15 (pp. 339–390). Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

  • Panizza, U. (2008). Domestic and external public debt in developing countries. (UNCTAD Discussion Paper No. 188).

  • Petersen, M. A., & Rajan, R. (2002). Does distance still matter? The information revolution in small business lending. Journal of Finance, 57(6), 2533–2570.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Portes, R., & Rey, H. (2005). The determinants of cross-border equity flows. Journal of International Economics, 65(2), 269–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Razin, A., Sadka, E., & Yuen, C. (1998). A pecking order theory of capital flows and international tax principles. Journal of International Economics, 44(1), 45–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose, A. K., & Spiegel, M. (2004). A gravity model of sovereign lending: Trade, default and credit. IMF Staff Papers, 51, 64–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose, A. K., & Spiegel, M. (2009). International financial remoteness and macroeconomic volatility. Journal of Development Economics, 89(2), 250–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • United Nations (2007). World population prospects: The 2006 revision, Vol. I, New York, NY.

  • World Bank (2011). World development indicators, Washington, DC.

Download references

Acknowledgments

I am grateful to Philip Lane for very helpful advice and comments. I am also thankful for comments and discussions to the editor Harmen Lehment, two anonymous referees, an anonymous referee of the ECB Working Paper Series, Michael Fidora, Doireann Fitzgerald, Marcel Fratzscher, Maurizio Habib, Christiane Hellmanzik, Paul Scanlon and conference participants at the Conference on “Intra-European Imbalances, Global Imbalances, International Banking, and International Financial Stability,” Berlin 2012, as well as seminar participants at the European Central Bank and at Trinity College Dublin. Financial support of the Irish Research Council for the Humanities and Social Sciences (IRCHSS) from 2008 to 2010 is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Martin Schmitz.

Additional information

The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of the European Central Bank.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Country sample and data sources

Country sample

Albania

Djibouti

Lao people’s Dem. Rep

Rwanda

Algeria

Dominican Republic

Latvia

Samoa

Angola

Ecuador

Lebanon

Saudi Arabia

Argentina

Egypt

Lithuania

Senegal

Armenia

El Salvador

Macedonia

Sierra Leone

Australia

Equatorial Guinea

Madagascar

Singapore

Austria

Eritrea

Malawi

Slovak Republic

Azerbaijan

Estonia

Malaysia

Slovenia

Bahrain

Ethiopia

Maldives

South Africa

Bangladesh

Fiji

Mali

Spain

Belarus

Finland

Malta

Sri Lanka

Belgium

France

Mauritania

Sudan

Belize

Gabon

Mauritius

Swaziland

Benin

Gambia, The

Mexico

Sweden

Bhutan

Georgia

Moldova

Switzerland

Bolivia

Germany

Mongolia

Syrian Arab Republic

Bosnia and Herzegovina

Ghana

Morocco

Tajikistan

Botswana

Greece

Mozambique

Tanzania

Brazil

Grenada

Namibia

Thailand

Bulgaria

Guatemala

Nepal

Togo

Burkina Faso

Guinea

Netherlands

Tonga

Burundi

Haiti

New Zealand

Trinidad and Tobago

Cambodia

Honduras

Nicaragua

Tunisia

Cameroon

Hungary

Niger

Turkey

Canada

Iceland

Nigeria

Uganda

Cape Verde

India

Norway

Ukraine

Chad

Indonesia

Oman

United Arab Emirates

Chile

Iran, Islamic Republic of

Pakistan

United Kingdom

China, P. R.: Mainland

Ireland

Panama

United States

Colombia

Israel

Papua New Guinea

Uruguay

Congo, Dem. Rep. of

Italy

Paraguay

Uzbekistan

Congo, Republic of

Jamaica

Peru

Venezuela, Rep. Bol.

Costa Rica

Japan

Philippines

Vietnam

Croatia

Jordan

Poland

Yemen, Republic of

Cyprus

Kazakhstan

Portugal

Zambia

Czech Republic

Kenya

Qatar

 

Cote d’Ivoire

Korea

Romania

 

Denmark

Kyrgyz Republic

Russia

 

Most advanced countries (in terms of GDP per capita)

Australia

Finland

Japan

Spain

Austria

France

Korea

Sweden

Bahrain

Germany

Netherlands

Switzerland

Belgium

Greece

New Zealand

United Arab Emirates

Canada

Iceland

Norway

United Kingdom

Cyprus

Ireland

Qatar

United States

Denmark

Israel

Singapore

 

Equatorial Guinea

Italy

Slovenia

 

Data sources

Variables

Source

(Net) external position

Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2007)

GDP per capita

World Bank—WDI

Demographic variables

United Nations (2007): World Population Prospects: The 2006 Revision

Public debt

Panizza (2008) and National Sources

Distance and contiguous dummy

CEPII (2006)

Time difference

http://www.timeanddate.com/

Currency union dummy

Rose and Spiegel (2004)

Capital account openness

Chinn and Ito (2008)

Bilateral bank claims

BIS (2009)

Bilateral portfolio holdings

IMF (2009a)

Bilateral exports

IMF (2009b)

Appendix 2: Demographic specification

Our demographic specification follows Fair and Dominguez (1991) and Higgins (1998), and was introduced as a determinant of net external positions by Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2002). We divide the population into J = 12 age cohorts and the age variables enter the net foreign assets equation as ∑ 12 j=1 α j p jt where p jt is the population share of cohort j in period t and ∑ 12 j=1 α j  = 0. We make the restrictions that the coefficients lie along a cubic polynomial

$$ \alpha_{j}=\gamma_{0} + \gamma_{1}j + \gamma_{2}j^{2} + \gamma_{3}j^{3} $$

The zero-sum restriction on the coefficients implies that

$$ \gamma_{0}=-\gamma_{1}(1/J)\sum_{j=1}^{12}j-\gamma_{2}(1/J) \sum_{j=1}^{12}j^{2} -\gamma_{3}(1/J)\sum_{j=1}^{12}j^{3} $$

In turn, we can estimate γ1, γ2, γ3 by introducing the age variables into the specification as

$$ \gamma_{1}DEM_{1t} + \gamma_{2}DEM_{2t} + \gamma_{3}DEM_{3t} $$

where

$$ \begin{aligned} DEM_{1t}&=\sum_{j=1}^{12}jp_{jt}-(1/J)\sum_{j=1}^{12}j \sum_{j=1}^{12}p_{jt}\\ DEM_{2t}&=\sum_{j=1}^{12}j^{2}p_{jt}-(1/J)\sum_{j=1}^{12}j^{2} \sum_{j=1}^{12}p_{jt}\\ DEM_{3t}&=\sum_{j=1}^{12}j^{3}p_{jt}-(1/J)\sum_{j=1}^{12}j^{3} \sum_{j=1}^{12}p_{jt} \end{aligned} $$

About this article

Cite this article

Schmitz, M. Financial remoteness and the net external position. Rev World Econ 150, 191–219 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-013-0168-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-013-0168-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation