Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Does wealth inequality reduce the gains from trade?

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of World Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper refines and tests the hypothesis that the impact of opening to trade on a country’s economic growth is affected by the inequality of its distribution of wealth. Analysis of panel data on 44 developing countries between 1960 and 2000 suggests that the difference in growth rates between the period an economy is open and the period it is closed depends inversely on the degree of wealth inequality prior to opening. There is evidence to suggest that access to credit and lack thereof may lie behind these results, thus highlighting a new aspect of the role of financial development.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Inequality has also been found to affect growth through political economy, social and political instability and health channels, although this last one remains debated (see Deaton 2003).

  2. These variables also control for changes in the savings rate between the two periods and thus make redundant the inclusion of the difference in investment rates between the two periods. As a sensitivity test, changes in investment will be included as an additional control, although doing so does not alter the results.

  3. The countries included in the sample are: Argentina, Barbados, Bolivia, Brazil, Cameroon, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, El Salvador, Ghana, Guatemala, Honduras, Indonesia, Israel, Jamaica, Jordan, Kenya, Malaysia, Mali, Mauritius, Mexico, Mozambique, Nepal, Nicaragua, Niger, Panama, Paraguay, Peru, Philippines, Romania, Singapore, South Africa, South Korea, Sri Lanka, Taiwan, Trinidad and Tobago, Tunisia, Turkey, Uganda, Uruguay, Venezuela and Zambia.

  4. Using land inequality as a proxy for wealth inequality may be criticised on the grounds that, if land is heterogeneous in terms of productivity, a competitive land rental market and free entry will lead to land inequality but no wealth inequality because lower-productivity land will be concentrated into larger holdings (Lipton et al. 2009). While this problem can be solved by regressing land inequality on average farm size, from Vollrath (2007), and then using the residuals of such regression as the measure of inequality, in this sample no significant relationship between land inequality and average farm size is found.

  5. Following the identification strategy by Acemoglu et al. (2001), the log of the early settlers’ mortality rate is also considered as a measure for the quality of institutions. The argument for using this latter measure is that Europeans adopted very different policies in different colonies, with different associated institutions, depending, at least partly, on whether Europeans could settle in the colony. In places where Europeans faced high mortality rates, they could not settle and they were more likely to set up worse (extractive) institutions. This legacy of early institutions has persisted to the present. However, early settlers’ mortality rates are time invariant and therefore cannot be used as a standalone variable, but can be used as an instrument for changes in the Civil Liberties Index. Results show that this is not an informative instrument and, therefore, all the regressions that include the early settlers’ mortality rate are not reported.

  6. A dummy variable from this variable (dbmp) is constructed following the cutoff point considered by Sachs and Warner (1995), equal to 1 if a country in a certain year has a black market exchange rate premium <20% and 0 otherwise. Including this variable does not alter the results significantly when the OLS estimator is used, while the IV approach is not feasible because the coefficient estimated in a single regression of changes in dbmp between t and t − 1 on the level of dbmp at t − 2 is not statistically significant. For the same reason, the rate of inflation—a proxy for macroeconomic management, like the black market premium—cannot be used in the IV approach. Thus, these additional results are not reported.

  7. Two other measures were used in additional regressions, private credit by deposit money banks to GDP and private credit by deposit money banks and other financial institutions to GDP, but the results do not differ significantly and are, therefore, not reported.

  8. Casual evidence supports this claim since many Latin American countries with high levels of land inequality opened to trade after the 1980’s debt crisis hit the region (Goldberg and Pavcnik 2007).

  9. Eliminating five or more years before and after liberalisation worth of data makes the sample too small to be able to make statistical inference.

  10. Additional regressions, available upon request, have been run by replacing T n with a vector of dummy variables for regional categories. These regressions confirm that a country’s attitude towards trade liberalisation may be influenced by its neighbours, yet they do not show any correlation between the year of liberalisation and the level of land inequality.

  11. The analysis of value chains is interesting insofar as they are driven by changes at the global level but have impacts at the local level in terms of employment and poverty.

References

  • Acemoglu, D. (2003). Patterns of skill premia. Review of Economic Studies, 70(2), 199–230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91(5), 1369–1401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion, P., Caroli, E., & Garcia-Penalosa, C. (1999). Inequality and economic growth: The perspective of the new growth theories. Journal of Economic Literature, 37(4), 1615–1660.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, E. (2005). Openness and inequality in developing countries: A review of theory and recent evidence. World Development, 33(7), 1045–1063.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bacchetta, M., & Jansen, M. (2003). Adjusting to trade liberalization: The role of policy, institutions and WTO disciplines. Geneva: World Trade Organization.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J., & Lee, J. W. (2001). International data on educational attainment: Updates and implications. Oxford Economic Papers, 53(3), 541–563.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Levine, R. (2000). A new database on financial development and structure. World Bank Economic Review, 14, 597–605.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bekaert, G., Harvey, C. R., & Lundblad, C. (2001). Does financial liberalization spur growth? (NBER Working Paper 8245). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Belsley, D., Kuh, E., & Welsch, R. (1980). Regression diagnostics: Identifying influential data and sources of collinearity. New Jersey: Wiley.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ben-David, D., & Loewy, M. B. (2000). Knowledge dissemination, capital accumulation, trade, and endogenous growth. Oxford Economic Papers, 52(4), 637–650.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bensidoun, I., Jean, S., & Sztulman, A. (2011). International trade and income distribution: Reconsidering the evidence. Review of World Economics/Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 147(4), 593–619.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, S., & Ravallion, M. (2000). How did the world’s poorest fare in the 1990s? (Policy Research Working Paper Series 2409). Washington, DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deaton, A. (2003). Health, inequality, and economic development. Journal of Economic Literature, 41(1), 113–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deininger, K., & Olinto, P. (2000). Asset distribution, inequality, and growth. (Policy Research Working Paper Series 2375). Washington, DC: The World Bank.

  • Engerman, S. L., & Sokoloff, K. L. (2002). Factor endowments, inequality, and paths of development among new world economics. (NBER Working Paper 9259). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Engerman, S. L., & Sokoloff, K. L. (2005). Colonialism, inequality, and long-run paths of development. (NBER Working Paper 11057). Cambridge, MA: Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Foellmi, R., & Oechslin, M. (2010). Market imperfections, wealth inequality, and the distribution of trade gains. Journal of International Economics, 81(1), 15–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankema, E. (2006). The colonial origins of inequality: Exploring the causes and consequences of land distribution. (Research Memorandum GD-81). University of Groningen: Groningen Growth and Development Centre.

  • Freedom House (2007). Freedom in the world 2007: The annual survey of political rights and civil liberties. Washington, DC: Freedom House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Zeira, J. (1993). Income distribution and macroeconomics. Review of Economic Studies, 60(1), 35–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., Moav, O., & Vollrath, D. (2004). Land inequality and the origin of divergence and overtaking in the growth process: Theory and evidence. (Working Paper 2003–04). Providence, RI: Department of Economics, Brown University.

  • Global Financial Data (2008). GF Database. San Juan Capistrano, CA: Global Financial Data.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldberg, P. K., & Pavcnik, N. (2007). Distributional effects of globalization in developing countries. Journal of Economic Literature, 45(1), 39–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1991). Trade, knowledge spillovers, and growth. European Economic Review, 35(2–3), 517–526.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1993). Innovation and growth in the global economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann, R., Pritchett, L., & Rodrik, D. (2005). Growth accelerations. Journal of Economic Growth, 10(4), 303–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heston, A., Summers, R., & Aten, B. (2006). Penn World Table Version 6.2. Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University of Pennsylvania.

  • Jenkins, R. (2005). Globalization, production and poverty. (WIDER Research Paper 2005/40). University of United Nations: World Institute of Development Economics Research.

  • Krueger, A. O., & Berg, A. (2003). Trade, growth, and poverty: A selective survey. (IMF Working Paper 03/30). Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

  • Lipton, M. (2009). Land reform in developing countries: Property rights and property wrongs. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lipton, M., Eastwood, R., & Newell, A. (2009). Small farms. In: Evenson, R., & Pingali, P. (eds), Handbook of agricultural economics—agricultural development: farm policies and regional development, (Vol. 4, chap 5). Amsterdam: North-Holland.

  • Lopez, H., & Serven, L. (2009). Too poor to grow. (Policy Research Working Paper Series 5012). Washignton, DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsuyama, K. (2000). Endogenous inequality. Review of Economic Studies, 67(4), 743–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCulloch, N., Winters, L. A., & Cirera, X. (2002). Trade liberalization and poverty: A handbook. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morrissey, O., Mbabazi, J., & Milner, C. (2002). Inequality, trade liberalisation and growth. (Working Paper 102/02). University of Warwick: Centre for the Study of Globalisation and Regionalisation.

  • Ravallion, M. (2003). The debate on globalization, poverty, and inequality : Why measurement matters. (Policy Research Working Paper Series 3038). Washington, DC: The World Bank.

  • Rodríguez, F., & Rodrik, D. (2001). Trade policy and economic growth: A skeptic’s guide to the cross-national evidence. In: Bernanke, B. S., & Rogoff, K. (eds), NBER macroeconomics annual 2000, (Vol. 15, NBER Chapters, pp 261–338). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A., & Trebbi, F. (2004). Institutions rule: The primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development. Journal of Economic Growth, 9(2), 131–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, J., & Warner, A. (1995). Economic reform and the progress of global integration. (Working Paper 1733). University of Harvard: Harvard Institute of Economic Research.

  • The World Bank (2005). Economic growth in the 1990s: learning from a decade of reform. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, V., Wang, Y., & Fan, X. (2002). A new dataset on inequality in education: Gini and Theil indices of schooling for 140 countries, 1960–2000. Washignton, DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Topalova, P. (2004). Trade liberalization and firm productivity: The case of India. (IMF Working Paper 04/28). Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

  • Tornell, A. (1998). Reform from within. (NBER Working Paper 6497). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Vollrath, D. (2007). Land distribution and international agricultural productivity. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 89(1), 202–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vollrath, D., & Erickson, L. (2007). Land distribution and financial system development. (IMF Working Paper 07/83). Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wacziarg, R., & Welch, K. H. (2008). Trade liberalization and growth: New evidence. World Bank Economic Review, 22(2), 187–231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wood, A. (1994). North–South trade, employment and inequality: Changing fortunes in a skill-driven world. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I thank Adrian Wood for many helpful comments and discussions. I am also grateful to Christopher Adam, Christopher Bowdler, Alasdair Smith, Tony Venables, Alan Woodland and seminar participants at the Gorman Workshop at the University of Oxford, at the ESRC Development Economics Conference at the University of Sussex and at the Conference on Poverty Traps at the University of Naples Parthenope for useful comments. I gratefully acknowledge that part of this research was financially supported by an Australian Research Council grant to Professor Alan Woodland. All errors are mine.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mauro Caselli.

About this article

Cite this article

Caselli, M. Does wealth inequality reduce the gains from trade?. Rev World Econ 148, 333–356 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-012-0119-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-012-0119-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation