Skip to main content
Log in

Bilateral trade of cultural goods

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of World Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

International trade flows of cultural goods have grown rapidly over the last decades and their liberalization will be an important issue of future multilateral trade negotiations. In this paper, we focus on bilateral trade in cultural goods and investigate its determinants. Furthermore, we use trade in cultural goods as a proxy for countries’ cultural proximity and study if countries with proximate cultural tastes have more intense bilateral exchanges. Our estimations show a positive and significant influence of cultural flows on overall trade, suggesting that regulations fostering domestic cultural creation might have impacts going beyond what is generally expected.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Household expenditures on recreation and culture include purchases of audio-visual, photographic and computer equipment; CDs and DVDs; musical instruments; camper vans; caravans; sports equipment; toys; domestic pets and related products; gardening tools and plants; newspapers; tickets to sporting matches, cinemas and theatres; and spending on gambling (including lottery tickets) less any winnings.

  2. Cultural goods included in this (UNESCO) definition are printed matter, literature, music, visual arts, cinema, photography, radio, television, games and sporting goods.

  3. http://portal.unesco.org/culture/.

  4. François and van Ypersele (2002) provide academic justification for this view.

  5. Close to our approach is the work by Dreher et al. (2008). The authors use trade in books as a measure of countries’ cultural proximity and investigate the effects of several dimensions of globalization on economics in a time-series cross-section context. Felbermayr and Toubal (2009) is another very recent paper using bilateral votes in the Eurovision song contest to measure changes in bilateral cultural affinity over time.

  6. For a very detailed analysis of production and consumption of arts, see Throsby (1994). Here, we focus only on international trade in cultural goods.

  7. This habit formation effect is obviously not specific to cultural goods but can also be observed for goods such as alcohol, tobacco, etc., as well as for goods that may have some origin-country feature (such as wine from Tuscany, French cheese, …).

  8. See, e.g. Boisso and Ferrantino (1997), Melitz (2008), Rose (2000), Eichengreen and Irwin (1998), Wagner et al. (2002), Guiso et al. (2009) and for a review of this literature Disdier and Mayer (2007).

  9. The debate on whether genetic distance is a legitimate proxy for cultural distance is still open. Focusing on the diffusion of development, Spolaore and Wacziarg (2009) argue that genetic distance provides an ideal summary of divergence in slowly changing genealogically transmitted characteristics, including culturally transmitted traits (habits, customs, etc.) and find a positive and significant relationship between measures of genetic distance and cross-country income differences. Guiso et al. (2009) also dispute the critique of genetic distance by Giuliano et al. (2006).

  10. Our analysis focuses only on goods and does not study cultural services.

  11. http://www.cepii.fr/anglaisgraph/bdd/baci.htm.

  12. Alternative theoretical foundations of the gravity equations include very different assumptions: perfect competition with technology differences as in Eaton and Kortum (2002), monopolistic competition with different functional forms as in Melitz and Ottaviano (2008), or heterogenous firms operating in a Dixit–Stiglitz environment as in Chaney (2008). All of those however yield a strictly equivalent estimable specification for our purposes.

  13. http://www.cepii.fr/anglaisgraph/bdd/distances.htm.

  14. When this equation is estimated by a PPML estimator, the left-hand-side term is taken in levels.

  15. Recent years are available on the web: http://www.uis.unesco.org/. Previous years are taken from the statistical yearbooks of UNESCO.

References

  • Algan, Y., & Cahuc, P. (2007). The roots of low European employment: Family culture? In J. Frankel & C. Pissarides (Eds.), National bureau of economic research international seminar on macroeconomics 2005. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, J. E., & van Wincoop, E. (2003). Gravity with gravitas: A solution to the border puzzle. American Economic Review, 93(1), 170–192. doi:10.1257/000282803321455214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R., & Taglioni, D. (2006). Gravity for dummies and dummies for gravity equations. (NBER Working Paper 12516). National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.

  • Becker, G. S., & Murphy, K. M. (1988). A theory of rational addiction. Journal of Political Economy, 96(4), 675–700. doi:10.1086/261558.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boisso, D., & Ferrantino, M. (1997). Economic distance, cultural distance, and openness in international trade: Empirical puzzles. Journal of Economic Integration, 12(4), 456–484.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chaloupka, F. (1991). Rational addictive behavior and cigarette smoking. Journal of Political Economy, 99(4), 722–742. doi:10.1086/261776.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaney, T. (2008). Distorted gravity: The intensive and extensive margins of international trade. American Economic Review, 98(4), 1707–1721. doi:10.1257/aer.98.4.1707.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Disdier, A. C., & Mayer, T. (2007). Je t’aime, moi non plus: Bilateral opinions and international trade. European Journal of Political Economy, 23(4), 1140–1159. doi:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2006.09.021.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A., Gaston, N., & Martens, P. (2008). Measuring globalisation—gauging its consequences. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eaton, J., & Kortum, S. (2002). Technology, geography, and trade. Econometrica, 70(5), 1741–1779. doi:10.1111/1468-0262.00352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen, B., & Irwin, D. I. (1998). The Role of History in Bilateral Trade Flows. In J. A. Frankel (ed.), The Regionalization of the World Economy. National Bureau of Economic Research Project Report series. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  • Felbermayr, G., & Toubal, F. (2009). Cultural proximity and trade. European Economic Review (forthcoming).

  • Fieler, A. C. (2008). Non-homotheticity and bilateral trade: Evidence and a quantitative explanation. Manuscript, New York University.

  • Francois, P., & van Ypersele, T. (2002). On the protection of cultural goods. Journal of International Economics, 56(2), 359–369. doi:10.1016/S0022-1996(01)00119-2.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaulier, G., & Zignago, S. (2008). BACI: A world database of international trade at the product-level. The 1995–2004 version. (CEPII Working Paper). Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et d’Informations Internationales, Paris.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giuliano, P., Spilimbergo, A., Tonon, G. (2006). Genetic, cultural and geographical distances. (CEPR Working Paper 5807). Centre for Economic Policy Research, London.

  • Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2009). Cultural biases in economic exchange. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(3), 1095–1131. doi:10.1162/qjec.2009.124.3.1095.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hummels, D. (1999). Toward a geography of trade costs. Manuscript, University of Chicago.

  • Janeba, E. (2007). International trade and consumption network externalities. European Economic Review, 51(4), 781–803. doi:10.1016/j.euroecorev.2006.07.002.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. R. (1980). Scale economies, product differentiation and the pattern of trade. American Economic Review,, 70(5), 950–959.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marvasti, A., & Canterbery, E. R. (2005). Cultural and other barriers to motion pictures trade. Economic Inquiry, 43(1), 39–54. doi:10.1093/ei/cbi004.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maystre, N., Olivier, J., Thoenig, M., Verdier, T. (2008). Product-based cultural change: Is the village global? Manuscript, University of Geneva.

  • Melitz, J. (2008). Language and foreign trade. European Economic Review, 52(4), 667–699. doi:10.1016/j.euroecorev.2007.05.002.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melitz, M., & Ottaviano, G. I. P. (2008). Market size, trade, and productivity. Review of Economic Studies, 75(1), 295–316. doi:10.1111/j.1467-937X.2007.00463.x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2007). Factbook 2007—economic, environmental and social statistics. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olivier, J., Thoenig, M., Verdier, T. (2008). Globalization and the dynamics of cultural identity. Journal of International Economics, 76(2), 356–370. doi:10.1016/j.jinteco.2008.06.009.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Redding, S., & Venables, A. J. (2004). Economic geography and international inequality. Journal of International Economics, 62(1), 53–82. doi:10.1016/j.jinteco.2003.07.001.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose, A. K. (2000). One money, one market: Estimating the effect of common currencies on trade. Economic Policy, 30, 9–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Santos Silva, J. M. C., & Tenreyro, S. (2006). The log of gravity. Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(4), 641–658. doi:10.1162/rest.88.4.641.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schulze, G. G. (1999). International trade in art. Journal of Cultural Economics, 23(1–2), 109–136. doi:10.1023/A:1007551515187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spolaore, E., & Wacziarg, R. (2009). The diffusion of development. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(2), 469–529. doi:10.1162/qjec.2009.124.2.469.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tabellini, G. (2008). Institutions and culture. Journal of the European Economic Association, 6(2–3), 255–294. doi:10.1162/JEEA.2008.6.2-3.255.

    Google Scholar 

  • Throsby, D. (1994). The production and consumption of the arts: A view of cultural economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 32(1), 1–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • UNESCO (2000). International flows of selected cultural goods 1980–98. Paris: UNESCO Institute for Statistics.

    Google Scholar 

  • UNESCO (2005). International flows of selected cultural goods and services, 1994–2003. Montreal: UNESCO Institute for Statistics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, D., Head, K., & Ries, J. (2002). Immigration and the trade of provinces. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 49(5), 507–525. doi:10.1111/1467-9485.00245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • White, H. (1980). A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroskedasticity. Econometrica, 48(4), 817–838. doi:10.2307/1912934.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We especially appreciate the suggestions of Harmen Lehment and an anonymous referee. We thank Paola Conconi, Victor Ginsburgh, Nicolas Maystre, André Sapir, and participants at University Paris 1 seminar, RIEF Doctoral Meeting 2006, ETSG 2006 and AFSE 2006 for helpful suggestions. We acknowledge financial support from the Centre for Economic Policy Research (Research Training Network: “Trade, Industrialization and Development”) and from the French Ministry of Culture (Contract: DDAI/DEPS E0514).

Disclaimer

This paper represents the opinions of the authors. It is not meant to represent the position or opinions of the WTO or its Members, nor the official position of any staff members.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Anne-Célia Disdier.

Appendix: Depreciation of the past consumption stock of cultural goods

Appendix: Depreciation of the past consumption stock of cultural goods

The addictive stock of past consumption is defined as follows (Chaloupka 1991):

$$ A(t) = \sum\limits_{i = 0}^{t - 1} {(1 - \delta )^{t - 1 - i}C(i)} , $$

where δ is the constant rate of depreciation of the addictive stock over time and C(t) the consumption in year t. This equation can be rewritten as:

$$ A(t) = \sum\limits_{i = 0}^{t - 1} {C(i)D(i) = t\overline{CD} + t\text{cov} (C(i)D(i))} , $$

where \( D(i) = (1 - \delta )^{t - 1 - i} \) and \( \overline{CD} \) is the product of the mean value of D and the mean consumption. The covariance is assumed to be relatively small and is ignored.

Following Chaloupka (1991), we assume high depreciation rates considering that withdrawal effects shortly disappear after consumption cessation. If rates of depreciation are between 60 and 90%, remaining consumption effects last between 2 and 5 years. By comparison if δ = 20%, remaining consumption effects last more than 20 years. Results are described in Table 6. In this table, we normalize initial consumption to 1 and consider that the effects persist until remaining consumption represents only 1% of the initial one. Moreover, past consumption stock tends to stabilize after some years. We consider that the stock is stabilized if its variation from one year to another is less than 5%. If δ is set to 60%, the stock variation is equal to 4.1% between the third and fourth years. Therefore, in such case, the number of years before stabilization is 4. Similarly, if δ = 70%, the stock variation is 1.9% between the third and fourth years and the number of years before stabilization is 4. If δ = 80%, the variation is 3.3% between the second and third years and we conclude that the stock is stabilized after 3 years. In our study, we set δ to 0.7.

Table 6 Depreciation rate and consumption effects

Using these depreciation rates, we estimate gravity equations for the aggregate value of cultural goods imports. The stock of past imports is included among explanatory variables. Coefficient estimates on this stock are reported in Table 6. These estimates are not significantly affected by the value of the depreciation rate. Thus, the choice of a depreciation rate depends essentially on the expected time of influence of past consumption.

About this article

Cite this article

Disdier, AC., Tai, S.H.T., Fontagné, L. et al. Bilateral trade of cultural goods. Rev World Econ 145, 575–595 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-009-0030-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-009-0030-5

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation