Skip to main content
Log in

The macroeconomic impact of COVID-19 on occupations

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Portuguese Economic Journal Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We adopt a pandemic-macroeconomic model to simulate the macroeconomic impact of COVID-19 on various occupations under both laissez-faire and government lockdown scenarios. We integrate a SIR model of virus transmission into a simplified neoclassical model and categorize occupations into two groups based on their ability to work remotely. Subsequently, we assess the shock impact of the pandemic on GDP, consumption, and working hours of flexible and rigid occupations. We find that these three variables declined during the pandemic, yet the consumption varied among individuals with different health status. The labour market experienced a recession, with workers in flexible occupations experiencing a relatively milder impact compared to those in rigid occupations. A larger proportion of remote work mitigated the recessionary effects, although it accentuated the disparities between occupations' income and working hours. The implementation of lockdown policies detrimentally affects welfare, similar to the pandemic itself, but the impact on flexible and rigid occupations differs from that in a laissez-faire scenario.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Data Availability

The data supporting the findings of this study are openly available from the Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S. Department of Commerce (https://www.bea.gov/) and the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (https://www.bls.gov/). The index for the degree of flexibility and essentiality that we developed is openly available in RM Del Rio-Chanona et al. (2020) and Dingel and Neiman (2020). Further details can be obtained from the corresponding author, X. Li, upon reasonable request.

Notes

  1. In the study conducted by Kaplan et al. (2020), the optimal proportion of workplace hours within the overall market hours is given by \(\frac{{v_{l} (D)^{ - \eta } }}{{v_{l} (D)^{ - \eta } \;+\; \phi^{\eta } }}\), where \(v_{l} (D)^{{}}\) denotes the additional disutility of workplace hours due to the virus.

  2. For the detailed results in different level of \(\kappa\), please refer to Appendix 2.

References

  • Aguiar M, Hurst E (2007) Measuring trends in leisure: The allocation of time over five decades. Q J Econ 122(3):969–1006

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alvarez FE, Argente D, Lippi F (2020) A simple planning problem for covid-19 lockdown (No. w26981). National Bureau of Economic Research

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Baker SR, Farrokhnia RA, Meyer S, Pagel M, Yannelis C (2020) How does household spending respond to an epidemic? Consumption during the 2020 COVID-19 pandemic. Rev Asset Pricing Stud 10(4):834–862

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baqaee D, Farhi E (2020) Supply and demand in disaggregated Keynesian economies with an application to the Covid-19 crisis (No. w27152). National Bureau of Economic Research

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Barrero JM, Bloom N, Davis SJ (2020) COVID-19 is also a reallocation shock (No. w27137). National Bureau of Economic Research

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bodenstein M, Corsetti G, Guerrieri L (2022) Social distancing and supply disruptions in a pandemic. Quant Econ 13(2):681–721

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brynjolfsson E, Horton JJ, Ozimek A, Rock D, Sharma G, TuYe HY (2020) COVID-19 and remote work: an early look at US data (No. w27344). National Bureau of Economic Research

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Chopra A, Devereux MB, Lahiri A (2022) Pandemics through the lens of occupations. Can J Econ/revue Canadienne D’économique 55:540–580

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Rio-Chanona RM, Mealy P, Pichler A, Lafond F, Farmer JD (2020) Supply and demand shocks in the COVID-19 pandemic: an industry and occupation perspective. Oxf Rev Econ Policy 3:S94–S137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dingel JI, Neiman B (2020) How many jobs can be done at home? J Public Econ 189:104235

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Eichenbaum MS, Rebelo ST, Trabandt M (2020) Epidemics in the Neoclassical and New-Keynesian models (No. w27430). National Bureau of Economic Research

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Eichenbaum MS, Rebelo S, Trabandt M (2021) The macroeconomics of epidemics. Rev Financ Stud 34(11):5149–5187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faria-e-Castro M (2021) Fiscal policy during a pandemic. J Econ Dyn Control 125:104088

    Article  MathSciNet  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  • Guerrieri V, Lorenzoni G, Straub L et al (2022) Macroeconomic implications of COVID-19: can negative supply shocks cause demand shortages? Am Econ Rev 112(5):1437–1474

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Han J, Meyer BD, Sullivan JX (2020) Income and poverty in the COVID-19 pandemic (No. w27729). National Bureau of Economic Research

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan G, Moll B, Violante GL (2020) The great lockdown and the big stimulus: tracing the pandemic possibility frontier for the US (No. w27794). National Bureau of Economic Research

    Google Scholar 

  • Kermack WO, McKendrick AG (1927) A contribution to the mathematical theory of epidemics. Proc R Soc London Ser A Contain Pap Math Phys Char 115(772):700–721

    ADS  Google Scholar 

  • Pueyo T (2020) Coronavirus: why you must act now. Politicians, community leaders and business leaders: what should you do and when

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Xinru Li.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Computing the first-order conditions

This appendix summarizes the equations used to compute the competitive equilibrium of the benchmark SIR-macro model. We take the first-order conditions for the key variables.

We take the first-order conditions for \(n_{f,t}^{s} ,n_{q,t}^{s} ,n_{f,t}^{i} ,n_{q,t}^{i} ,n_{f,t}^{r} ,n_{q,t}^{r}\):

$$\theta n_{f,t}^{s} = \lambda_{t}^{b} w_{f,t} + (\frac{1 - \kappa }{{(\phi^{f} - 1)\kappa + 1}})^{2} \lambda_{t}^{\tau } \pi_{2} (I_{t} N_{f,t}^{i} )$$
$$\theta n_{q,t}^{s} = \lambda_{t}^{b} w_{q,t} + (\frac{1 - \kappa }{{(\phi^{q} - 1)\kappa + 1}})^{2} \lambda_{t}^{\tau } \pi_{3} (I_{t} N_{q,t}^{i} )$$
$$\theta n_{f,t}^{i} = \lambda_{t}^{b} w_{f,t}$$
$$\theta n_{q,t}^{i} = \lambda_{t}^{b} w_{q,t}$$
$$\theta n_{f,t}^{r} = \lambda_{t}^{b} w_{f,t}$$
$$\theta n_{q,t}^{r} = \lambda_{t}^{b} w_{q,t}$$

Combined with the SIR model in households, the first-order conditions for \(s_{t + 1} ,i_{t + 1} ,r_{t + 1}\) are:

$$\begin{gathered} \ln c_{t + 1}^{s} - \frac{\theta }{2}(n_{f,t + 1}^{s} )^{2} - \frac{\theta }{2}(n_{q,t + 1}^{s} )^{2} + \lambda_{{t{ + }1}}^{\tau } [\pi_{1} c_{{t{ + }1}}^{s} (I_{{t{ + }1}} C_{{t{ + }1}}^{i} ) + (\frac{1 - \kappa }{{(\phi^{f} - 1)\kappa + 1}})^{2} \pi_{2} n_{{f,t{ + }1}}^{s} (I_{{t{ + }1}} N_{{t{ + }1}}^{i} ) \hfill \\ +\; (\frac{1 - \kappa }{{(\phi^{q} - 1)\kappa + 1}})^{2} \pi_{3} n_{{q,t{ + }1}}^{s} (I_{{t{ + }1}} N_{{t{ + }1}}^{i} ) + \pi_{4} I_{{t{ + }1}} ]{ + }\lambda_{{t{ + }1}}^{b} \left[ {w_{f,t + 1} n_{f,t + 1}^{s} + w_{q,t + 1} n_{q,t + 1}^{s} - c_{t + 1}^{s} } \right] - \lambda_{t}^{s} /\beta + \lambda_{t + 1}^{s} = 0 \hfill \\ \end{gathered}$$
$$\begin{gathered} \ln c_{t + 1}^{i} - \frac{\theta }{2}(n_{f,t + 1}^{i} )^{2} - \frac{\theta }{2}(n_{q,t + 1}^{i} )^{2} + \lambda_{{t{ + }1}}^{b} \left[ {w_{f,t + 1} n_{f,t + 1}^{i} + w_{q,t + 1} n_{f,t + 1}^{i} - c_{t + 1}^{i} } \right] - \lambda_{t}^{i} /\beta \hfill \\ +\; \lambda_{t + 1}^{i} (1 - \pi_{r} - \pi_{d} ) + \lambda_{{t{ + }1}}^{r} \pi_{r} = 0 \hfill \\ \end{gathered}$$
$$\ln c_{t + 1}^{r} - \frac{\theta }{2}(n_{f,t + 1}^{r} )^{2} - \frac{\theta }{2}(n_{q,t + 1}^{r} )^{2} + \lambda_{t + 1}^{b} (w_{f,t + 1} n_{f,t + 1}^{r} + w_{q,t + 1} n_{q,t + 1}^{r} - c_{t + 1}^{r} ) - \lambda_{t}^{r} /\beta + \lambda_{t + 1}^{r} = 0$$

The first order condition for \(\tau_{t}\) is:

$$\lambda_{t}^{i} = \lambda_{t}^{\tau } + \lambda_{t}^{s}$$

Appendix 2: Robustness with respect to \(\kappa\)

Figure 6 shows that when \(\kappa = 0.3\), working hours decrease by 14.33 percent in flexible occupations and by 15.43 percent in rigid occupations. Hourly wages increase by 9.58 percent in flexible occupations and 10.72 percent in rigid occupations. Labour income experiences a decline of 6.12 percent in flexible occupations and 6.35 percent in rigid occupations.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Response of working hours, wages, labour income in different occupations (k = 0.3)

Figure 7 shows that under \(\kappa = 0.5\), working hours decline by 11.9 percent in flexible occupations and 15.21 percent in rigid occupations. Hourly wages increase by 7.49 percent in flexible occupations and 10.83 percent in rigid occupations. Moreover, labour income decreases by 5.3 percent in flexible occupations and 6.02 percent in rigid occupations.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Response of working hours, wages, labour income in different occupations (k = 0.5)

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Li, X. The macroeconomic impact of COVID-19 on occupations. Port Econ J (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10258-023-00249-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10258-023-00249-y

Keywords

JEL classification code

Navigation