1 Introduction

Although there is a lot of empirical evidence on the fact that pollution and health expenditures influence mortality,Footnote 1 the studies on evironmental policy examine externalities related to fertilityFootnote 2, mortalityFootnote 3 or private health expendituresFootnote 4 separately. The purpose of this document is to consider all those externalities in the same setup together with public health care. To do so, we apply optimal tax theory to a dynamic fertility choice model where production-related pollution is lethal, but where the families and the government can decrease mortality by spending on health care.

Harford (1997, 1998) examines optimal taxation in a model where altruistic parents determine the number of their children and population growth deteriorates the environment, decreasing an individual’s welfare. He shows that to decentralize the social optimum, the Pigouvian tax on pollutants must be supported by a parental tax on the number of children. Jöst and Quaas (2010) examine optimal taxation in a fertility choice model where emissions generate welfare-harming pollution. They prove that the externalities must be corrected by two Pigouvian taxes: one on emissions and the other on the number of children or the size of the family. Harford (1997, 1998), assume a constant lifetime for an individual, while Jöst and Quaas (2010) assume a constant mortality rate (and consequently, a constant expected lifetime) for the whole population. In this document, the mortality rate is considered as an endogenous variable that depends on pollution along with private and public health care.

Jöst and Quaas (2010) assume furthermore that emissions are directly used as an input in production without costs. Consequently, there is no price for that input and no laissez-faire equilibrium in the economy without a tax on emissions. In this document, that problem is solved by considering emissions as a by-product of productive inputs that are extracted from the nature at a real cost.

Gomez (2001) and Baudin (2011) examine taxation in a fertility choice model where the families can reduce mortality by health expenditures. Both of them show that if private health expenditures generate positive externality, then it can be optimal to tax them.Footnote 5 Because the public sector plays a major role in health care in most advanced countries, in this document, public services are considered as an alternative way of controlling that externality: private health care is a mortality-decreasing private good with no externality; but public health care can be either a public good whose average supply per individual decreases the mortality rate of the whole population, or a publicly-provided private good. This changes the whole setup: the problem is to discover the optimal supply of public health care and the supporting set of tax instruments by which the social optimum can be decentralized.

The evolution of the mortality rate is considered in many documents, but through the dynamics of some other state variable. Grossman (1972), and Erlich and Chuma (1990) introduce health as a mortality-decreasing state variable. Chakraborty (2004) assumes that the probability of an individual’s survival depends on health capital that is augmented by public investment. Dalgaard and Strulik (2014) consider human aging as a process where the deficits of health are a state variable that increases the probability of death. In this document, pollution and health care are assumed to influence the mortality rate directly, through a dynamic process.

The remainder of this study is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the structure of the economy, including the behavior of the firms. Sections 3 derives the social optimum by a model of the social planner (called the government), while Section 4 considers the optimal behavior of the representative family that determines its saving, fertility and private health care, taking the taxes, public health care and the stock of pollution as given. The comparison of the equilibria of the government and the family yields optimal policy rules for a market economy. Section 5 summarizes the results.

2 The economy as a whole

2.1 The goods market

In the model, time t is continuous and T is the initial time. There is one tradable good that is chosen as the numeraire in the model. It is assumed that pollutants B – which are called carbon energy in this study, for convenience – are extracted from the nature at a constant marginal cost q in terms of the numeraire good. Then, the market price for carbon energy is equal to q.

The output Y of the good is used in consumption C, private health care H, public health care G, the extraction costs of carbon energy, qB, the depreciation of capital K at the constant rate \(\mu \in (0,1)\), and investment in new capital, \(\frac{dK}{dt}\):

$$\begin{aligned} Y=C+H+G+qB+\mu K+\frac{dK}{dt},\quad K(T)=K_T, \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where \(K_T\) is capital K at initial time T.

It is convenient to define the macroeconomic variables and the labor input in production, L, in proportion to population N as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} c\doteq \frac{C}{N},h\doteq \frac{H}{N},k\doteq \frac{K}{N}, g\doteq \frac{G}{N},y\doteq \frac{Y}{N},b\doteq \frac{B}{N},\ell \doteq \frac{L}{N}. \end{aligned}$$
(2)

Output Y is produced from capital K, labor L and carbon energy B according to neoclassical technology with constant returns to scale. Then, by (2), the per individual output y can be defined as a concave and linearly homogeneous function of per individual inputs (\(k,\ell ,b\)):

$$\begin{aligned}&y(k,\ell ,b),\quad y_k\doteq \frac{\partial y}{\partial k}>0,\quad y_\ell \doteq \frac{\partial y}{\partial \ell }>0,\quad y_b\doteq \frac{\partial y}{\partial b}>0 . \end{aligned}$$
(3)

2.2 The government’s budget

Let f be the fertility rate, i.e., the number of newborns relative to population N. The government controls the economy by public health care G and the taxes \(\tau _f\) and \(\tau _b\) on fertility fN and carbon energy B, and balances its budget by the poll tax \(\tau _n\) on population N. This defines the budget constraint \(\tau _n N+{\tau _f}fN+\tau _bq B=G.\)

2.3 Firms

The representative firm maximizes its profit \(\Pi\) by its inputs of capital K, labor L and carbon energy B subject to technology (3), given population N, the wage w, the interest rate r, and the price q and the tax \(\tau _b\) on carbon energy B [cf., (2) and (3)]:

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi&\doteq \max _{K,L,B}\bigl [Y-wL-rK-(q+\tau _b)B\bigr ]=N\max _{k,\ell ,b}\bigl [y(k,\ell ,b)-w\ell -rk-(q+\tau _b)b\bigr ]_. \end{aligned}$$
(4)

Because the per individual production function (3) yields constant returns to scale, then, in equilibrium, the profit \(\Pi\) is zero and the marginal products of capital, labor and carbon energy, \(y_k\), \(y_\ell\) and \(y_b\), are equal to the interest rate r, the wage w and the producer’s unit cost of carbon energy, \(q+\tau _b\), respectively:

$$\begin{aligned}&\Pi =0, \quad r=y_k,\quad w=y_\ell ,\quad y_b=q+\tau _b. \end{aligned}$$
(5)

2.4 Pollution and population growth

The extraction and use of carbon energy B generates emissions in one-to-one proportion. Emissions B in turn accumulate the stock of pollution P as follows [cf., (2)]:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dP}{dt}=B-\xi P=bN-\xi P,\quad \xi >0,\quad P(T)=P_T, \end{aligned}$$
(6)

where the constant ξ is the natural absorbtion rate of pollution P.

At every moment of time t, each individual has a given stock of resources that can be allocated between labor \(\ell\) and child rearing. Consequently, there is a transformation curve so that the individual has to sacrifice more and more labor \(\ell\) to have one more child. Because pollution-induced illnesses decrease the individual’s resources, pollution P shifts that transformation curve downwards. Thus, the fertility rate f is a decreasing function of both labor input \(\ell\) and pollution P. The growth rate of population N is then equal to the fertility rate f minus the mortality rate m as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{1}{N}\frac{dN}{dt}=f(\ell ,P)-m,\quad L(T)=L_T,\quad f_\ell \doteq \frac{\partial f}{\partial \ell }<0,\quad f_P\doteq \frac{\partial f}{\partial P}<0. \end{aligned}$$
(7)

By (2) and (7), the change of capital per individual, \(s\doteq \frac{dk}{dt}\), is determined as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}&s\doteq \frac{dk}{dt}=\frac{d}{dt}\biggl (\frac{K}{N}\biggr ) =\frac{1}{N}\frac{dK}{dt}-\frac{K\,}{N^2}\frac{dN}{dt}=\frac{1}{N}\frac{dK}{dt}-(f-m)k,\quad k(T)=k_T. \end{aligned}$$
(8)

2.5 Mortality

Pollution P is a negative public good that increases mortality for all individuals simultaneously.Footnote 6 Private health care H is a private good: its input to a single individual, h, decreases only that individual’s mortality rate m. Public health care G can be a public good as well, but then it is assumed to be proportional to population to maintain its efficiency. Hence, public health care per individual, g, decreases every individual’s mortality rate m simultaneously. Alternatively, public health care per individual, g, can be defined as a publicly-provided private good. Because the variables (Pgh) affect mortality over time with lags, the determination of the mortality rate m can be specified as the following error-correcting process [cf., (2)]:

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{dm}{dt}=\gamma [M(P,g,h)-m],\quad {\gamma }\in (0,1),\quad m(T)=m_T,\quad M_P\doteq \frac{\partial M}{\partial P}>0,\nonumber \\&M_h\doteq \frac{\partial M}{\partial h}<0,\quad M_g\doteq \frac{\partial M}{\partial g}<0,\quad {M\;strictly\;convex\;in\;(g,h),} \end{aligned}$$
(9)

where M is the long-run mortality rate and \(\gamma\) a constant adjustment parameter.Footnote 7

2.6 Utility

If an individual’s probability of death depended explicitly on the individual’s age, then the economy would become a non-autonomous system that depends explicitly on time. Because such a system does not have a steady state, it can be solved only numerically, but not symbolically by the standard methods of optimal control theory. To avoid this problem, we use the classical fertility choice model:Footnote 8 the basic unit is not an individual, but a dynastic family – i.e., a sample of the whole population – that is able to keep its mortality and fertility rates stable over time.

In line with Razin and Ben-Zion (1975), Becker (1981), Galor and Weil (1996) and Stelter (2016), endogenous fertility is based on the following three assumptions. First, the parents are selfish.Footnote 9 Second, children are a kind of consumption good in their parents’ preferences. Finally, every individual’s time horizon is limited by death, but, because the probability of dying is known, that individual discounts his/her expected utility over time. In Appendix 1, it is shown that these three assumptions lead to the following utility function for the representative family in the economy:Footnote 10

$$\begin{aligned}&\int _{T}^{\infty }U\bigl (c(t),f\bigl (\ell (t),P(t)\bigr )\bigr )e^{[\rho +m(t)]({T}-t)}dt, \quad U_c\doteq \frac{\partial U}{\partial c}>0, \quad U_f\doteq \frac{\partial U}{\partial f}>0, \end{aligned}$$
(10)

where c is consumption per individual, f the fertility rate [cf., (7)], \(\rho >0\) the constant rate of time preference for an individual who could live forever and \(\rho +m\) is the effective rate of time preference for an individual that faces the mortality rate m.

2.7 Transformation from real into virtual time

Because the mortality rate m is an endogenous variable, it must eliminated from the discount factor of the utility function (10) by Uzawa’s (1968) transformation

$$\begin{aligned} \theta (t)=[\rho +m(t)]t\;\text {with}\;dt = \frac{d\theta }{\rho +m(\theta )}. \end{aligned}$$
(11)

Because \(\theta ({T})=[\rho +m(T)]{T},\) \(\theta (\infty )=\infty\) and \(\frac{dt}{d\theta } = \frac{1}{\rho +m(\theta )}>0\) hold true, one can define \(\theta (t)\) as an alternative virtual time variable and set the variables in terms of it. With the transformation (11), the utility function (10) and the evolution of the state variables, (6)-(9), are changed from real time t into virtual time \(\theta\) as follows:

$$\int _{\theta (T)}^{\infty }\frac{U\bigl (c(\theta ),f\bigl (\ell (\theta ),P(\theta )\bigr )\bigr )}{\rho +m(\theta )}e^{\theta (T)-\theta }d\theta ,\quad U_c>0,\quad U_f>0; \nonumber$$
(12)
$$\frac{dN}{d\theta }=\frac{f\bigl (\ell (\theta ),P(\theta )\bigr )-m(\theta )}{\rho +m(\theta )}N(\theta ),\quad N(T)=N_T,\quad f_\ell<0,\quad f_P<0$$
(13)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{dm}{d\theta }=\gamma \frac{M\bigl (P(\theta ),g(\theta ),h(\theta )\bigr )-m}{\rho +m(\theta )},\quad m(T)=m_T,\quad 0<\gamma <1,\quad M_P>0,\end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned}&M_h<0,\quad M_g<0,\quad \text {M strictly convex in (g,h)}, \end{aligned}$$
(14)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{dk}{d\theta }=\frac{s(\theta )}{\rho +m(\theta )},\quad k(T)=k_T, \end{aligned}$$
(15)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{dP}{d\theta }=\frac{b(\theta )N(\theta )-\xi P(\theta )}{\rho +m(\theta )},\quad P(T)=P_T,\quad 0<\xi <1. \end{aligned}$$
(16)

3 The government

3.1 Optimal behavior

To obtain the first-best optimum, it is assumed that the government can control the economy by the per individual amounts of the change of capital, \(s\doteq \frac{dk}{dt}\), labor input \(\ell\), public health care g, private health expenditures h and carbon energy b. Noting (1), (2), (3), (5), (7) and (8), consumption per individual, c, can be derived as a function the government’s controls (\(s,\ell ,g,h,b\)) and state variables (mkP) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}&s=\frac{1}{N}\frac{dK}{dt}-(f-m)k=y-c-h-g-qb+(m-f-\mu )k \Leftrightarrow \nonumber \\&c(s,\ell ,g,h,b,m,k,P)\doteq y(k,\ell ,b)-s-h-g-qb+[m-f(\ell ,P)-\mu ]k\;\text {with}\nonumber \\&\,\frac{\partial c}{\partial b}\, =y_b-q=\tau _b, \frac{\partial c}{\partial \ell }=y_\ell -kf_\ell =w-kf_\ell ,\frac{\partial c}{\partial s}=\frac{\partial c}{\partial h}=\frac{\partial c}{\partial g}=-1,\nonumber \\&\frac{\partial c}{\partial m}=k\;\text{and}\;\frac{\partial c}{\partial k}=y_k+m-f-\mu =r+m-f-\mu . \end{aligned}$$
(17)

In Appendix 2, the marginal cost of pollution P – when the long-run mortality rate M, population N, capital stock K, emissions B, public health care G and labor input per individual, \(\ell\), are held constant – is derived as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \varepsilon&=N\biggl |\frac{M_P}{M_h}\biggr |-K\biggl |\frac{\partial f}{\partial P}\biggr |=-N\underbrace{\frac{M_P}{M_h}}_{-}+K\underbrace{\frac{\partial f}{\partial P}}_{-}. \end{aligned}$$
(18)

Because of two opposing effects, the sign of this marginal cost is ambiguous. On the one hand, an increase in pollution P increases the long-run mortality rate by the amount \(M_P\), compelling the families to increase their private health care by the amount \(|N{M_P}/{M_h}|\). On the other hand, pollution P decreases the fertility rate by the amount \(\bigl |\frac{\partial f}{\partial P}\bigr |\), reducing investment in new machines for the newborns by the amount \(K\bigl |\frac{\partial f}{\partial P}\bigr |\). It is assumed that the positive effect through the long-run mortality rate M dominates over the negative effect through the fertility rate f, so that \(\epsilon >0\). Otherwise, we would obtain the unlikely case that pollution is not a social loss.Footnote 11

It is convenient to define the social cost of pollution, \(\eta\), as the value of the flow of the marginal cost of pollution, \(\varepsilon\), discounted by the sum of the natural absorbtion rate of pollution, \(\xi\), and the effective rate of time preference, \(\rho +m\):

$$\begin{aligned} \eta \doteq \frac{\varepsilon }{\xi +\rho +m}>0. \end{aligned}$$
(19)

The faster the stock of pollution disappears (i.e., the higher \(\xi\)) or the higher an individual’s effective rate of time preference, ρ+m, is, the less worried the individuals are about pollution P and the lower the social cost of pollution, \(\eta\), is.

The government maximizes the representative family’s welfare (12) by its controls (\(s,\ell ,g,h,b\)) subject to consumption per individual, (17), and the evolution of population N, the mortality rate m, capital per individual, k, and pollution P, (13)-(16). The value function for the government’s program at initial time T is then

$$\begin{aligned} \Psi (m,k,N,P,{T})\doteq \max _{{\bigl ({s}({T}),\ell (T),h(T),g(T),b(T)\bigr )}{s.t. (17),(13)-(16)}} \int _{\theta (T)}^{\infty }\frac{U\bigl (c(\theta ),f\bigl (\ell (\theta ),P(\theta )\bigr )\bigr )}{\rho +m(\theta )}e^{T-\theta }d\theta . \end{aligned}$$
(20)

3.2 Equilibrium conditions

Following Dixit and Pindyck (1994), the Bellman equation for the government’s program (20) is constructed as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}&\Psi =\max _{{\bigl ({s}({T}),\ell (T),h(T),g(T),b(T)\bigr ) s.t. (17)}}\Upsilon \bigl (s,\ell ,h,b,m,k,N,P,T\bigr ) \text {with} \end{aligned}$$
(21)
$$\begin{aligned}&\Upsilon \bigl (s,\ell ,h,g,b,m,k,N,P,T\bigr ) \doteq \frac{U}{\rho +m}+\frac{\partial \Psi }{\partial N}\frac{dN}{d\theta }+\frac{\partial \Psi }{\partial P}\frac{dP}{d\theta }+\frac{\partial \Psi }{\partial k}\frac{dk}{d\theta }+\frac{\partial \Psi }{\partial m}\frac{dm}{d\theta } \nonumber \\&=\frac{1}{\rho +m}\biggl \{U\bigl (c,f(\ell ,P)\bigr )+\frac{\partial \Psi }{\partial N}[f(\ell ,P)-m]N+\frac{\partial \Psi }{\partial P}(bN-\xi P)\nonumber \\& +\frac{\partial \Psi }{\partial k}s +\frac{\partial \Psi }{\partial m}\gamma [M(P,g,h)-m]\biggr \}. \end{aligned}$$
(22)

The maximization of the function (22) by controls subject to the consumption function (17) yields the first-order conditions (cf., Appendix 3)

$$M_g=\frac{U_c}{\gamma }\biggl / \frac{\partial \Psi }{\partial m},$$
(23)
$$M_h=\frac{U_c}{\gamma }\biggl / \frac{\partial \Psi }{\partial m},$$
(24)
$$U_c=\frac{\partial \Psi }{\partial k},$$
(25)
$$\tau _b=\frac{\partial c}{\partial b}=-\frac{N}{U_c}\frac{\partial \Psi }{\partial P},$$
(26)
$$\frac{U_f}{U_c}+\frac{w}{f_\ell }-k=-\frac{N}{U_c}\frac{\partial \Psi }{\partial N}.$$
(27)

Because \(\Upsilon\) is concave in controls (\(s,\ell ,h,g,b\)), the government’s equilibrium is unique.

From (23) and (24) it follows that \(M_g=M_h\). Then, the marginal effects of H and G on M(Pgh), when P and N are held constant, are given by \(M_h\frac{\partial h}{\partial H}=\frac{M_h}{N}<0\) and

$$M_g\frac{\partial g}{\partial H}=\frac{M_g}{N}=\frac{M_h}{N}=M_h\frac{\partial h}{\partial H}<0.$$

This result can be rephrased as follows:

Proposition 1

Public health care G must be extended up to the level at which its marginal efficiency in decreasing the long-run mortality rate M, \(-M_g\frac{\partial g}{\partial H}\), is equal to that of private health care H, \(-M_h\frac{\partial g}{\partial H}\), given pollution P and population N.

Because both private and public health care are produced from the final good to decrease the mortality rate, efficiency requires that their marginal effects are equal.

3.3 Solution

The solution of dynamic programming is based on finding a proper specification for the value function (20). In Appendix 4, the following function is found:

$$\begin{aligned}&\Psi (m,k,N,P,{T}),\quad \frac{\partial \Psi }{\partial P} =\frac{U_c}{\rho +m}\frac{\xi \tau _b-\epsilon }{N},\quad \frac{\partial \Psi }{\partial N}=-\frac{\tau _bU_c}{\rho +m}\frac{b}{N}, \nonumber \\&\frac{\partial \Psi }{\partial m} =\frac{1}{\rho +m}\biggl [U_f+U_c\biggl (k-\frac{1}{M_h}\biggr )\biggr ]-\frac{U}{(\rho +m)^2}. \end{aligned}$$
(28)

Noting (19) and (28), condition (26) becomes

$$\begin{aligned}&\tau _b=-\frac{N}{U_c}\frac{\partial \Psi }{\partial P}=\frac{\varepsilon -\xi \tau _b}{\rho +m}\Leftrightarrow (\xi +\rho +m)\tau _b=\varepsilon \Leftrightarrow \tau _b=\frac{\varepsilon }{\xi +\rho +m}=\eta >0. \end{aligned}$$

This result can be rephrased as follows:

Proposition 2

The optimal tax on carbon energy is equal to the social cost of pollution, \(\tau _b=\eta >0\).

4 The representative family

4.1 Saving

The representative family takes pollution P, the tax \(\tau _n\) on population N, the tax \(\tau _f\) on fertility fN, public health care per individual, g, the wage w for labor L and the interest rate r paid to capital K as given. Because capital K is the only asset in the model, investment \(\frac{dK}{dt}\) in capital K is equal to saving:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dK}{dt}&=wL+rK-C-H-(\tau _n N+{\tau _f}fN)-\mu K, \end{aligned}$$
(29)

where wL is labor income, rK capital income, C consumption, H private health care, \(\tau _n N+{\tau _f}fN\) the family’s tax expenditures and \(\mu\) the constant rate of depreciation for capital K.

The family determines the change of its capital per individual, \(s=\frac{dk}{dt}\), labor input per individual, \(\ell\), and health expenditures per individual h subject to the evolution of its mortality rate m, (14), and that of its capital per individual, k, (15). By (2), (7), (8) and (29), consumption per individual, c, is a function of the family’s controls (\(s,\ell ,h\)), state variables (mk), and exogenous variables (\(P,g,\tau _n,\tau _f,w,r\)) (cf., Appendix 5):

$$\begin{aligned}&c=\widetilde{c}(s,\ell ,h,m,k,P,g,{{\tau _n}},\tau _f,w,r),\quad \frac{\partial \widetilde{c}}{\partial m}=-k,\quad \frac{\partial \widetilde{c}}{\partial s}=\frac{\partial \widetilde{c}}{\partial h}=-1,\nonumber \\&\frac{\partial \widetilde{c}}{\partial \ell }=w-(k+\tau _f)f_\ell ,\quad \frac{\partial \widetilde{c}}{\partial k}=m-f+r-\mu . \end{aligned}$$
(30)

4.2 Optimal behavior

The representative family maximizes its utility (12) by its controls (\(s,\ell ,h\)) subject to its consumption per individual, (30), the evolution of its mortality rate, (14), and its capital per individual, (15), given its exogenous variables (\(P,\tau _n,\tau _f,g,w,r\)). This defines the value function at initial time T as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}&\Phi (m,k,P,\tau _n,\tau _f,w,r,g,{T})\doteq \max _{{\bigl (s(T),\ell (T),h(T)\bigr )} \text {s.t. (30),(14),(15)}} \int _{\theta (T)}^{\infty }\frac{U\bigl (c(\theta ),f\bigl (\ell (\theta ),P(\theta )\bigr )\bigr )}{\rho +m(\theta )}e^{\theta ({T})-\theta }d\theta . \end{aligned}$$
(31)

The family’s program (31) is independent of the family size N.

The Bellman equation for the family’s program (31) is given by

$$\begin{aligned}&\Phi (m,k,P,\tau _n,\tau _f,w,r,g,{T}) =\max _{{\bigl (s(T),\ell (T),h(T)\bigr )}\text {s.t. (30),(14),(15)}}\Lambda (s,\ell ,h,m,k,P,\tau _n,\tau _f,w,r,g,{T})\;\text{with} \nonumber \\&\Lambda (s,\ell ,h,m,k,P,\tau _n,\tau _f,w,r,g,{T}) \doteq \frac{U}{\rho +m}+\frac{\partial \Phi }{\partial k}\frac{dk}{d\theta }+\frac{\partial \Phi }{\partial m}\frac{dm}{d\theta }\nonumber \\&=\frac{1}{\rho +m}\biggl \{U+\frac{\partial \Phi }{\partial k}s+\gamma \frac{\partial \Phi }{\partial m}\bigl [M(P,g,h)-m\bigr ]\biggr \}. \end{aligned}$$
(32)

The maximization of the function (32) by the controls (\(s,\ell ,h\)) subject to the family’s consumption function (30) yields the first-oder conditions (cf., Appendix 6)

$$\begin{aligned}&M_h=\frac{U_c}{\gamma }\biggl /\frac{\partial \Phi }{\partial m}, \end{aligned}$$
(33)
$$\begin{aligned}&\, U_c=\frac{\partial \Phi }{\partial k}, \end{aligned}$$
(34)
$$\begin{aligned}&\tau _f=\frac{1}{f_\ell }\frac{U_f}{U_c}+\frac{w}{f_\ell }-k. \end{aligned}$$
(35)

Because \(\Lambda\) is strictly concave in the controls (sfh), that equilibrium is unique.

4.3 Solution

The solution of dynamic programming is based on finding a specification for the value function (31). In Appendix 7, the following function is found:

$$\begin{aligned}&\Phi (m,k,P,\tau _n,\tau _f,w,r,g,{T}),\quad \frac{\partial \Phi }{\partial k}=\frac{\partial \Psi }{\partial k},\quad \frac{\partial \Phi }{\partial m}=\frac{\partial \Psi }{\partial m}. \end{aligned}$$
(36)

Inserting the partial derivatives in (36) into the family’s first-order conditions (33) and (34) yields the government’s first-order conditions (24) and (25).

The optimal parental tax \(\tau _f\) can be derived from (28), Proposition 2, the government’s first-order condition (27) and the family’s first-order condition (35) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}&\tau _f=\frac{1}{f_\ell }\frac{U_f}{U_c}+\frac{w}{f_\ell }-k=-\frac{N}{U_c}\frac{\partial \Psi }{\partial N}=\frac{\tau _bb}{\rho +m}=\frac{b\eta }{\rho +m}>0. \end{aligned}$$

This result can be rephrased as follows:

Proposition 3

The optimal parental tax per newborn, \(\tau _f\), is equal to the product of carbon energy per individual, b, and the social cost of pollution, \(\eta\), discounted by an individual’s effective rate of time preference, \(\rho +m\).

The product of carbon energy per newborn (= carbon energy per individual) and the social cost of pollution, \(b\eta\), characterizes the social cost of a newborn through pollution at a moment of time. The parental tax per newborn, \(\tau _f\), must be equal to the value of the social cost of a newborn over time, \(b\eta\), discounted an individual’s effective rate of time preference, \(\rho +m\).

5 Concluding remarks

In this document, optimal public policy is constructed for a market economy with the following institutions. Firms produce output from labor, capital and pollutants. Families determine their saving, fertility and private health expenditures. Emissions are a by-product of the extraction and use of pollutants. The mortality rate depends on pollution and both private and public health care dynamically, with lags. The government can use linear taxes and public health care to control the economy.

In the literature, the authors that combine endogenous fertility with environmental problems commonly recommend corrective Pigouvian taxes, but assuming in their models that the mortality rate (or longevity) is exogenous and there is no health care.Footnote 12 Furthermore, Gomez (2001) and Bauldin (2011) suggest that if there is externality in health care, then it can be optimal to tax private health expenditures. In this document, the main results are the following. If public health care can be introduced to take care of externality in health care, then private health expenditures should not be taxed or subsidized. If public health care uses the same inputs as private health care, then its expansion is welfare improving up to the level at which its marginal efficiency in decreasing the mortality rate is equal to that of private health care, given pollution and population. With this health care policy, two taxes – one on newborns and the other on pollutants – are sufficient to decentralize the social optimum. These stabilize the population and eliminate the externality due to pollution.

To construct the optimality rules for the taxes on newborns and pollutants, information on two concepts is needed. The first of these is the marginal cost of pollution on the assumption that the long-run mortality rate, population, capital stock, emissions, public health care and labor input relative to population are held constant. The second is the social cost of pollution, i.e., the value of the flow of the marginal cost of pollution, discounted by the sum of the natural absorbtion rate of pollution, the mortality rate and the rate of time preference. The optimal tax on pollutants is equal to the social cost of pollution. The optimal parental tax per newborn is equal to the product of carbon energy per newborn and the social cost of pollution, discounted by the sum of the mortality rate and the rate of time preference. These result can be explained as follows. The greater the mortality rate, the rate of time preference or the natural absorbtion rate of pollution, the less worried the families are about future pollution. Consequently, the social optimum can be decentralized by smaller corrective taxes.