Introduction

Aging populations and demographic change challenge the financial stability of public pension systems. Therefore, many countries reform their pension systems and prolong work lives to increase contributions and to reduce the number of benefit recipients. However, an increasing retirement age might have adverse effects in other areas of the welfare state, specifically for the health care system. Previous studies (e.g. [1, 3, 31, 37]) have documented that a prolonged working life can have negative health effects for individuals.Footnote 1 Yet, so far there exists no clear evidence how these negative health consequences affect health care costs. To assess the overall fiscal effects of pension reforms, this information is crucial.

This paper uses unique data that cover outpatient care and associated costs to quantify the health care costs of a sizable increase in the retirement age.Footnote 2 The data include the universe of individuals insured through the German public health care system (almost 90% of the German population) and comprise a ten-year observation period (2009–2018). In addition to the overall health cost effect of the pension reform, the data also allow us to quantify separate cost effects for different medical specialist categories.

We exploit a sizable cohort-specific pension reform that abolished an early retirement scheme for all women born after 1951. The reform provides a clean quasi-experimental setting as it induces a substantial discontinuity in retirement behavior for two adjacent cohorts. We use this discontinuity in a difference-in-differences (DiD) estimation. This framework accounts for cohort and seasonality effects and allows us to identify the causal effect of the pension reform on health care costs. Specifically, similar to previous studies (e.g. [3, 36]), we define a treatment group (women born between October 1951 and March 1952) and a control group (women born between October 1950 and March 1951) and compare the health care costs of these groups over time.

Our results show that outpatient care costs significantly increase by about 2.9% (about 16 euro per individual) in the age group directly affected by the increase in the retirement age (60–62). Moreover, we also find expectation effects for women at the age of 59 and indirect post-employment effects for women between 63 and 65. We further show that the cost increase is mainly driven by utilization of the following specialist groups: Ophthalmologists, general practitioners (GPs), oral and maxillofacial surgery, neurology, orthopedics, and radiology. The absolute effect is largest for GPs (about 3.5 euro) and thereby contributes about 25% to the increase in the overall costs. While the effects are significant and meaningful on the individual level, we show that the increase in health care costs are modest relative to the positive fiscal effects of the pension reform. Specifically, we estimate an aggregate increase in the health costs of about 7.7 million euro for women aged 60–62 and born in 1952. The corresponding estimate of the net effects of the pension reform for the tax and transfer system including social security amounts to about 4 billion euro [18].

Thus, from an aggregate perspective, our results of an increase in the health care costs do not provide strong evidence against an increase in the retirement age. However, the increase of costs on the individual level shows that positive fiscal effects of a longer working life can be counteracted by potential negative health consequences for individuals. Moreover, our cost estimate focuses on the public health care costs and abstracts from individual disutility or other disadvantages due to worse health as well as other societal costs such as a decrease in labor productivity or an increase in sickness absence at work. For political decisions on retirement ages, such factors also need to be taken into account.

There exists a large literature on the health effects of retirement and pension reforms:Footnote 3 some studies are based on survey data and explore effects of retirement on mental, physical or general health (e.g. [1, 2, 4, 11, 14, 15, 20, 21, 32]). Others use administrative data and consider mortality (e.g. [10, 16, 30]) or health care usage and diagnoses as outcome variables (e.g. [3, 22, 24, 31, 34]). The evidence of this literature is mixed and strongly depends on the pension reformFootnote 4 and the health outcomesFootnote 5 considered. Often broad health measures disguise effects of pension reforms on specific health outcomes. For example, using the same data source, Barschkett et al. [3] show that the reform considered in this study specifically affects mental health, musculoskeletal diseases, and obesity. They find prolonging working life increases the prevalence of all mentioned diagnoses. The underlying reasons for the association between (mental) health and retirement may by mani-folded: different stress-levels in and out of the labor force, changes in social contacts and mobility/movement are some examples.

Despite this sizable literature on health outcomes, there is only little evidence on the effects of pension reforms on public health care costs. Two examples are studies looking at pension reforms that delayed retirement with mixed evidence. Shai [37] finds negative health effects of continued working and an increase in health care consumption in Israel. In contrast, Perdrix [35] shows the opposite effect for France: she finds that later retirement leads to lower health care consumption. Associated with the lower number of doctor visits, she also finds lower expenditure.Footnote 6

Our paper is structured as follows: In “Institutional background” section, we describe the German pension and health care systems. “Data” section provides an overview on the data and “Empirical strategy” section explains the empirical strategy. In “Results” section, we describe the results and compare the additional costs for health care to the overall fiscal effects of the 1999 pension reform. “Conclusion” section concludes.

Institutional background

In this section, we provide a brief overview on the relevant institutions of the German pension system and discuss the 1999 pension reform, which induced an exogenous increase in the early retirement age for women born after 1951. Moreover, we describe the German health care system.

Pension system

The German public pension system covers roughly 90% of the workforce.Footnote 7 Pension benefits account for about two-thirds of gross income of the elderly. The system is financed by a pay-as-you-go (PAYG) scheme and has a strong contributory link. The statutory pension age (SRA) was 65 for cohorts born before 1947. It is raised stepwisely to age 67 and fully phased in for all cohorts born in 1964 or later. For the 1951 cohort, the SRA was 65 and 5 months, for those born in 1952 it was 65 and 6 months. People qualify for this regular old-age pension after five years of pension contributions.

Women born before 1952 could retire before the SRA (with permanent deductions) at the age of 60 via the pension for women. The 1999 reform abolished this pathway to retirement for cohorts born after 1951. Effectively, the reform raised the early retirement age (ERA) for most women from 60 to 63, which implies an extension of the working life of three years. The eligibility criteria of the pension for women were: (i) at least 15 years of pension insurance contributions; and (ii) at least 10 years of pension insurance contributions after the age of 40. About 60% of all women born in 1951 were eligible for the old-age pension for women [17].Footnote 8

Health care system

German residents are required to have health insurance.Footnote 9 About 90% of the population is insured in the public health care system.Footnote 10 People who opt out of the public system need to insure themselves in a private health insurance plan. Importantly, the insurance status is not affected by entry in retirement. Individuals with a public health insurance during the working life remain in this insurance during retirement.

Public health insurance is financed primarily through mandatory contributions by employers and employeesFootnote 11, along with tax revenues. The public insurance offers insurance for non-contributing family members (family insurance). For individuals who receive unemployment benefits, the unemployment agency covers the contributions. For retirees, the pension insurance co-finances the contributions.

In Germany, publicly insured patients do not need to advance the costs of insured health care services. Instead, medical service providers settle their accounts via their regional Association of Statutory Health Insurance Physicians. Price and quantity parameters in the health care system are negotiated on a yearly basis by the National Association of Statutory Health Insurance Physicians and the National Association of Statutory Health Insurance Funds as well as their regional counterparts (see “Appendix A: prices and quantities in the German health care system” section).

Data

We use administrative data covering the period of 2009 to 2018. The data stem from the database of claims of all publicly insured individuals in Germany as collected by the National Association of Statutory Health Insurance Physicians (KBV). For the analysis we use information on all insured women born between 1950 and 1952.Footnote 12 In addition to the group of women around the cutoff date of the pension reform (women born in late 1951 and in early 1952), we construct a control group consisting of women born late in 1950 and early in 1951.

The data include information for each patient about services and associated costs that medical specialists billed. For each patient the data contain yearly aggregated costs and costs that are specific to medical specialists.Footnote 13 In other words, each patient constitutes an entry for each year in the data set including information about the aggregated costs as well as the specific costs for each of the medical specialists.Footnote 14 The final data set includes about 500,000 women per birth cohort resulting in 1.5 million women overall. While the data includes detailed information on health outcomes and health costs, the data provide no information on important demographic variables such as education, employment status or income. Therefore, we cannot study the heterogeneous costs effects of the pension reform.

Empirical strategy

We estimate the effect of an increase in the retirement age on health care costs using a DiD estimation strategy. The medical literature (e.g. [8, 13]) documents that month of birth can affect health. Despite the set-up calling for an RDD approach, we prefer the DiD strategy as this allows us to account for seasonality. Specifically, following [36] and [3], we define a control group (women born between October 1950 and March 1951) and a treatment group (women born between October 1951 and March 1952). Women born between January and March are considered to be born after the cutoff. Thus, the interaction term between treatment group and being born after the cutoff estimates the effect of the pension reform. Importantly, the sample only includes individuals born between October 1951 and March 1952 as well as between October 1950 and March 1951, respectively. Thus, birth months between March and October are not included in the sample. This way, we avoid comparing birth months that are rather far away from the reform cutoff in January.

We account for correlation between observations of the same individual or individuals born in the same month, and use robust standard errors clustered by month of birth. In the subgroup analysis (costs by medical specialist), we additionally adjust the standard errors for multiple hypotheses testing using the Bonferroni-correction.

More formally, we estimate the following equation:

$$\begin{aligned} y_{it} = \alpha + \beta _0 Cohort_i + \beta _1 Month_i + \beta _2 Cohort_i \times Month_i + Z_{it}\delta + \varepsilon _{it} \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where \(Cohort_i\) indicates whether individual i was born between October 1951 and March 1952. The indicator is zero if individual i was born between October 1950 and March 1951. \(Month_i\) is the reform indicator that is one if individual i was born between January and March and zero otherwise. \(Cohort_i \times Month_i\) is the interaction between the two indicator variables and turns one for every woman born from January 1952 on. Thus, the interaction term marks the individuals who are affected by the reform. In addition, we account for age effects captured in \(Z_{it}\).

The distribution of health costs for the pre-reform cohort (born 1951) at age 59 and 60 (Fig. 1) shows a strong non-linear pattern. While 20–25% of patients produce zero costs per year, about 50% of patients produce between 100 and 600 Euros costs annually. Due to the non-linearity in the aggregated costs variable and the high share of patients with zero cost we estimate in the main analysis two different models and analyze the effects on the extensive margin and the intensive margin. We estimate the extensive margin in a linear probability model (LPM) in which the outcome variable \(y_{it}\) indicates if patients produce costs greater than zero in a given year. For the intensive margin we focus only on positive values and define the outcome \(y_{it}\) as the logarithm of the total cost. We also estimate the effect of the overall costs including both the intensive and the extensive margin using the linear costs as an outcome variable. When estimating the effect of the reform on specialist-specific costs, we only focus on the linear model and combine the intensive and extensive margin.Footnote 15

Fig. 1
figure 1

Source: KBV, own calculations

Cost distributions at age 59 and 60 (birth cohort 1951). The left figure presents the costs distribution of women aged 59 years born in 1951. The right figure presents the costs distribution of women aged 60 years born in 1951. Costs are fee-adjusted.

To identify a causal effects in a difference-and-difference estimator the standard assumptions need to hold. First, the intervention needs to be unrelated to the outcomes at baseline. Since treatment and control group are determined by birthday this assumption is not problematic in our setting. For the same reason the composition of treatment and control group is stable and there are no spillover effects. Secondly, we provide graphical evidence that the parallel trends assumption holds (parallel trends in the outcomes of treatment and control group prior to the intervention) in the “Appendix C: Robustness” section.

Results

Before we turn to the discussion of the estimation results, we present graphical evidence on the effect of the pension reform on health care costs. Figure 2 shows the average health care costs per year for women aged 60–62 for each birth month.Footnote 16 In the left panel we show the raw data. The right hand side presents the adjustedFootnote 17 health care costs (in fees of year 2009). The vertical lines represent the cutoff date January 1, 1952. For the interpretation, it is important to account for fee changes, since in every year relevant parameters of the health care system are adjusted (see “Appendix A: prices and quantities in the German health care system” section). Therefore, in the fee-adjusted health care costs, the jump between years is smaller. Still, we observe variation in the costs between the months of birth which are related to the seasonality pattern of health (e.g. [8, 13]). In the regression analysis, we account for the fee variation and seasonality using adjusted health care costs and using the DiD framework.

Importantly, at the cut-off, we observe the largest jump in health care costs: the fee-adjusted costs increase by about 25 euro per person after the cut-off date which corresponds to a relative increase of about 5%. This is first evidence that the increase in the retirement age leads to a sizable increase in health care costs. In the following, we turn to the estimation results of the DiD specification to empirically assess this reform effect.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Source: KBV, own calculations

Annual health care costs with and without fee adjustment (1950–52). The left figure presents the average health care costs per year of women between age 60 and 62 for each birth month. The right figure presents the fee-adjusted average health care costs per year (in 2009 fees) of women between age 60 and 62 for each birth month. The vertical lines represent the cutoff date (01/1952).

We estimate the effect of the pension reform on health care costs on the intensive and extensive margin for different age groups. In Table 1 we focus on the intensive margin. In the first Column, we present the results for all women aged 59–65. In Column 2, we focus only on women aged 59. Women in this age group were not directly affected by the reform, since retirement via the pension for women was not possible before the age of 60. However, [3] document sizable expectation effects of the 1999 pension reform for several health outcomes, which might affect heath care costs. In Column 3, we consider women aged 60–62. Finally, in Column 4 the results for women aged 63–65 are presented. These results can be interpreted as post-employment effects since women from the treatment and the control group both have the option to retire.

Table 1 DiD: price adjusted annual costs (in logs)

The estimation results confirm the graphical evidence: We find that the pension reform, i.e. the shift in the retirement age from 60 to 63, increases health care costs (Table 1). In all specifications (except for 63–65 year old women), the interaction effect that measures the causal effect of the reform, is positive and significant at the 1% or 0.1% level. Specifically, for women aged 59–65 (Column 1), the estimates suggest that the annual health care costs increase on average by about 2.2%. According to the linear specification (Table 3 in the “Appendix B: additional results” section) this corresponds to an increase of about 14 Euros per person. Note, this effect is smaller than suggested by the graphical evidence, which is due to the seasonality pattern that we account for in the DiD estimation.Footnote 18 The effect size over the different age groups is similar. The sizable effect for women aged 59 of over 3% underlines the importance of the expectation effect. At the same time, the insignificant effect on health care costs of women aged 63–65 implies that the pension reform did not lead to persistent increases in health care costs. However, the linear specification (“Appendix B: additional results” section) suggests a significant increase of about 11 Euros for this age group.

In Table 2 we turn to the extensive margin. The results suggest that the increase in healthcare costs can be mostly attributed to increases at the intensive margin. In other words, the additional costs are mainly produced by the group of women with positive costs in absence of the reform. Apart from the age group of 59 year old women, we do not find evidence that the reform induced women to switch from zero healthcare costs to non-zero healthcare costs.

In Fig. 5 we extend the analysis and account directly for the non-linear cost structure documented in Fig. 1. Specifically, we re-estimate the model with 100 different indicator variables for which we increase the threshold in ten euro increments and present the reform coefficients and confidence intervals. The first coefficient is identical to the extensive margin. Overall, the coefficients have a similar magnitude over the cost distribution but at higher costs the point estimates tend to be smaller but in general they are still significant.

Table 2 DiD: extensive margin

We provide empirical evidence for our identification strategy in “Appendix C: Robustness” section. First, the pre-reform time trends for the treatment and the control groups for the aggregated healthcare costs are very similar (Fig. 6) and, second, the estimates of a placebo test are not significant (Table 6 for the log-specification and Table 7 for the extensive margin). Specifically, for the placebo test we use the same empirical specification but artificially shift the design by one year and assign the cohort born in the first quarter 1951 as the treatment group after the hypothetical reform.

Results by medical specialist

In a next step, we analyze to which specialist care utilization the overall increase in costs can be attributed. This analysis provides insights into whether the increased prevalence of certain diagnoses goes along with increased utilization of the relevant specialists. We present the results for health care costs for the 28 different medical specialists that are classified in the data. To correct for multiple hypothesis testing, we adjust the standard errors using a Bonferroni-correction. Figure 3 shows the point estimates and 95% confidence bands for the specialists for whom we find significant effects. Costs are fee-adjusted with the same fee index as the overall costs. The complete results for all specialists can be found in the “Appendix B: additional results” section in Table 4 (general fee adjustment) and Table 5 (adjusted for specialist-specific fees).

Panel (a) shows the results for 59–65 year old women. The increase in the retirement age leads to a significant increase in costs for six specialist groups: Ophthalmologists, GPs, oral and maxillofacial surgery, neurology, orthopedics and radiology. The absolute effect is largest for GPs (about 3.5 euro) and thereby contributes about 25% to the increase in the overall costs. In terms of relative price increases, the effects are largest for oral and maxillofacial surgery, neurology, and radiology.

Panel (b) depicts the results for women at age 59 and the bottom left (Panel (c)) and right panel (Panel (d)) for women aged 60–62 years and 63–65 years, respectively. The results for the 59 year olds suggest, that the increase in the overall costs is mainly driven by increases in the utilization of GP and neurology care. For women aged 60–62 years, we find significant increases in the costs for eight specialists: Obstetricians/gynecologists, otolaryngologist, oral and maxillofacial surgery, neurology, orthopedics, psychiatry, and radiology. In absolute terms, the effects are largest for orthopedics (2.1 euro), radiology (1.3 euro) and obstetricians/gynecologists (1.2 euro). Relatively speaking, the rise in costs for oral and maxillofacial surgery, neurology and psychiatry are largest. The costs for specialists decreases due to the reform by 0.1 euro. Similarly to the 59 year old, the increase in overall costs for the 63–65 year old seems to be driven by increased utilization of mainly two specialist groups: GPs and radiology.

Overall, and across the different age groups the results show a relatively clear pattern. We find the strongest increase in the costs for neurology, psychiatry, radiology, GPs, orthopedics and oral and maxillofacial surgery. Based on the data it is not possible to directly identify the mechanism why the costs in the different categories increase. However, the evidence about the effects of the pension reform on health outcomes [3] allows us to draw indirect conclusions about the mechanisms. [3] document a significant increase in mental health, musculoskeletal diseases, and obesity. Moreover, they find an increase in the number of doctor visits. The increase in mental health can explain the cost effects in neurology and psychiatry which can be related to more frequent doctor visits, diagnostics and treatments. The increase in the costs for orthopedics and radiology are consistent with the finding that musculoskeletal diseases increase. Obesity is often related to mental health and has direct effects on musculoskeletal diseases. Therefore, the increase in obesity is likely to be a driver of the costs effects in the discussed categories. It is difficult to explain the costs effects in oral and maxillofacial surgery based on the mentioned diagnoses. One potential reason for the positive effect of a longer working life on the costs in oral and maxillofacial surgery is that employers may cover part of expensive surgery. The cost effects for the GP can be explained since patients often consult the GP before the specialist.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Source: KBV, own calculations

Significant DiD results by medical specialist. There is a new (“Neurologie”) and an old (“Nervenheilkunde”) term for the specialist “Neurology”. Figures show the statistically significant coefficients (with 95% confidence interval) of the DiD regressions on the specialist specific costs. Standard errors are Bonferroni corrected for multiple hypothesis testing. Panel a includes estimates for women aged 59–65 years, panel b for women aged 59 years, panel c for women aged 60–62 years and panel d for women aged 63–65 years.

Costs and revenues of the pension reform reform

In this section we put our findings into perspective and compare the additional health care costs to the overall fiscal effects of the 1999 pension reform. As shown by [17] the pension reform had a strong negative effect on retirement and a large positive effect on employment as well as on unemployment and inactivity. Specifically retirement rates of affected women decreased by about 25 percentage points. Inactivity and unemployment increased by about ten percentage points, employment by more than 14 percentage points. [18] estimate the related short-term effects on government revenues and expenditures which include changes in income taxation, transfer payments and in the social security system. Focusing only on the 1952 cohort and ages 60–62, the net effect of the reform amounts to four billion euro.

Relative to this sizable net effect, the additional aggregated health care costs are modest. As documented in Table 3 we find an average increase in health expenditures for women aged 60–62 of about 16 euro per year.Footnote 19 The cohort size of women born 1952 is about 540,000. Applying the average cost effect and assuming that about 90% of women are covered by the public health care system (see “Institutional background” section), the overall health care costs related to the pension reform amount to about 7.7 million euro per year in the short run. Thus, relative to the fiscal net effect of four billion euro, the health care costs amount to less than 2%. This cost effect is a lower bound as our data only covers outpatient care. Yet, since the pension reform mainly affected mental health, musculoskeletal diseases, and obesity [3] health care costs related to outpatient care are—at least in the short run—of central importance.

Conclusion

In this paper, we document that an increase in the retirement age leads to a significant increase in health care costs. To identify the causal effect of the increase in the retirement age, we exploit a cohort-specific pension reform which increased the early retirement age by three years between women born in two adjacent cohorts. The analysis is based on data that include the universe of individuals insured through the German public health care system (almost 90% of the German population) and comprises a ten-year observation period (2009–2018). Our results show that health care costs increase overall by about 2.9% for women in the age group directly affected by the increase in the retirement age (60–62). Moreover, we find expectation effects for women at the age of 59 and indirect post-employment effects for women between 63 and 65. In addition, we show that the cost increase is mainly driven by increased utilization of the following specialist groups: ophthalmologists, general practitioners (GPs), neurology, orthopedics and radiology. The absolute effect is largest for GPs (about 3.5 euro) and thereby contributes about 25% to the increase in the overall costs.

While the effects are significant and meaningful on the individual level, we show that the increase in health care costs are modest relative to the positive fiscal effects of the pension reform. Specifically, we estimate an aggregate increase in the outpatient costs of about 7.7 million for women aged 60-62 and born in 1952. Relative to the corresponding estimate of the net effects of the pension reform of about four billion euro [18] this translates into a relative effect of less than 2%.

Thus, from an aggregate perspective, our results of an increase in the health care costs do not provide strong evidence against an increase in the retirement age. However, the increase of costs on the individual level support the findings of previous studies focusing on individual health outcomes, that positive fiscal effects of a longer working life can be counteracted by potential negative health consequences for individuals. Our cost estimation focuses on the public health care costs and abstracts from individual disutility or other disadvantages due to worse health as well as other societal costs such as a decrease in labor productivity or an increase in sickness absence at work. For political decisions on retirement ages, such non-monetary factors also need to be taken into account.