Skip to main content
Log in

Municipal consolidation and local government behavior: evidence from Japanese voting data on merger referenda

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Economics of Governance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The empirical literature investigating the role of key features of local governments regarding decisions on consolidation tends to use a dummy dependent variable that takes 1 if both adjacent local governments decide to merge and 0 if one of them does not approve consolidation. Under this estimation method, however, it is difficult to know which governments refused to consolidate, as consolidation was not realized. The current study empirically tests the effects of economies of scale, population size, heterogeneity of preferences, and financial factors on municipal preferences for consolidation. It uses voting data from Japanese local referenda to identify preferences of specific individual municipalities, thus allowing a richer examination of local government behavior. The results obtained herein are as follows. Municipalities that could enjoy large economies of scale from consolidation prefer consolidation, while large and small municipalities are likely to merge. Moreover, municipalities receiving large unconditional grants from the central government are unlikely to merge.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The costs and benefits of decentralization were first formalized by Oates (1972).

  2. Several works have reported the role of key features influencing municipal consolidation in Japan, including population size and area, fiscal conditions, and heterogeneity of income (e.g., Hirota 2007; Miyashita and Nakazawa 2009; Miyazaki 2006; Nishikawa 2002; Weese 2008).

  3. Brink (2004) also employed voting data on municipal partition to estimate key factors affecting municipal boundary reform. However, the study comprised only 24 observations owing to the lack of boundary reform cases in Sweden. Further, the length of the data employed ranged from 1978 to 1999, a period so long that socioeconomic conditions might have changed during that time. Additionally, the study used data pertaining to local referenda on municipality partitioning, in contrast with most empirical works that have studied the mergers of school districts or local governments.

  4. Some studies state that Japanese unconditional grants are calculated following the nonarbitrary formula, and thus, they may be considered as lump sum transfers (Mochida 2006; Reschovsky 2007).

  5. Note that though it is usual for unconditional grants to be reduced after consolidation due to the alteration of population size in related municipalities, the amounts of unconditional grants merged municipalities could take have remained unchanged for the grace period (10 years) granted after consolidation. Because this scheme is very similar to the assumption of fixed lump sum transfers in theoretical analysis, the theory of this study could be adequately tested by this estimation.

  6. MIC is the abbreviation of the Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications (henceforth, MIC).

  7. See, for example, Akizuki (2001) and Mochida (2001, 2006).

  8. Formerly, the range of tax rates local governments could set was limited. See, for example, Mochida (2006, p. 164).

  9. The central government uses specific grants to guide the implementation of these projects through budget controls and as a means to stimulate the economy and reduce interregional income inequality.

  10. A vertical fiscal imbalance indicates differences in the balance of tax revenues and expenditures between the central and local governments, respectively; a regional fiscal imbalance refers to the differences in fiscal capacities of local governments.

  11. See Mochida (2006) and Reschovsky (2007).

  12. See, for example, CLAIR (2009), MIC (2006a, p. 41), and Yokomichi (2007).

  13. However, municipal mergers have not been made compulsory by law in Japan. Rather, consolidations have taken place more voluntarily than in the past (Yokomichi 2007).

  14. The referendum data were originally constructed as follows. First, municipalities holding a consolidation referendum were identified using Digital Archives of Mergers (henceforth, DAM) (MIC 2006b). As the DAM only covers the cases in which a consolidation was realized after a referendum, the other local referendum cases were identified from the homepage(s) operated by the municipalities or merger consultation committees, and other documents describing the merger committees, such as newspaper articles. Second, based on the list created in the first step, information pertaining to the referenda was obtained from the sources used in the first step. All of the municipalities employed in the estimation are listed in Online Resource 1 with the referendum data, such as date of election, number of the other consolidation partners, and approval rates.

  15. The total number of referenda (426) is close to that reported by the MIC (2010b) (418), and thus, almost all referenda cases are covered. The difference in numbers can be explained by the fact that the MIC counted some referenda as a single case when two or more referenda were held for an identical consolidation plan, whereas the author counted each referendum in such cases separately.

  16. Outliers have some particular characteristics, such as consolidation including enclaves and isolated islands, where large amounts of subsidies are often supplied by the central government. Because such municipalities likely differ from others, they are omitted from the sample.

  17. For the per unit cost depending on population, see, for example, Alesina et al. (2004), Andrews et al. (2002), Brasington (1999, 2003b), and Duncombe and Yinger (2007).

  18. The effect of transfers on consolidation incentives is also ambiguous. As seen in the second term of (8), utility gain from consolidation for municipality \(i\) depends on the relative sizes of the populations, median incomes, and lump sum transfer across municipalities. Except for population, large or small relations in income and transfer between municipalities \(i\) and \(j\) are not assumed, thus implying that it is ambiguous whether utility gain arises from consolidation with lump sum transfers.

  19. Figure 2 in Miyazaki (2013) depicted the log of expenditure against that of the population in 2000, suggesting that the log of per capita cost is U-shaped for Japan.

  20. On the one hand, inspired by Ellingsen’s (1998) majority voting model of separation/consolidation, Brasington (2003a) split the sample into larger and smaller communities, and showed that a larger district, which could be the decisive voter after consolidation, preferred to merge.

  21. Difference in residents’ preferences for public services is frequently reflected in socioeconomic elements like income and race.

  22. See Appendix B in Miyazaki (2013) for calculation methods of the median income.

  23. Hinnerich (2009) found that a local government with a strong tendency to free ride increases its per capita debt before annexation.

  24. Besides, in the context of the political business cycle, Johansson (2003) showed that intergovernmental grants are used as a device to win votes.

  25. To precisely examine the impacts of intergovernmental transfers, the effects on consolidation preference of a grace period for unconditional grants of merged municipalities and additional unconditional grants to cover local bond interests and principal need to be controlled for in this regression. The additional unconditional grants for local bond redemption seem to influence the issue of local bonds associated with consolidation, but part of the variation in accumulated local bonds can be controlled for by the variable Diff in accumulated debt.

          On the other hand, setting a grace period for unconditional grants may exert an effect on the relationship between the grants and consolidation preference. During the grace period, which continues for 10 years, merged municipalities can receive the same amount of unconditional grants as they would have had they not merged, while it is usually expected that unconditional grants are reduced after consolidation, because the grants are calculated taking into account economies of scale in public service provision. This means that during the grace period, the theoretical prediction that the amounts of grants municipalities take will remain unchanged irrespective of consolidation status holds, thus suggesting that this regression model, which is derived from the theory, makes it possible to examine the association between consolidation preference and lump sum grants.

  26. Note, however, that both specific and unconditional grants are, to be precise, not lump sum grants. Specific-purpose grants in Japan are said to be decided in accordance with the allocation standard, which while being objective, is set by bureaucratic institutions (Reed 2001). Unconditional grants, or the Local Allocation Tax in Japan, play the role of the fiscal equality transfer system and are allocated according to a formula based on the difference in basic expenditure needs and fiscal capacities of local governments (e.g., Mochida 2006). Therefore, municipality consolidations have usually given rise to a reduction in unconditional grants, because fiscal expenditure needs are calculated considering economies of scale. As per the 1999 amendment to the SLMM, however, unconditional grants for those municipalities that had merged by FY 2006 were calculated as if consolidation had not taken place for a certain time (e.g., CLAIR 2009), implying that unconditional grants are forecasted as remaining unchanged after consolidation. Therefore, unconditional grants are more likely to have the properties of a lump sum grant than a specific grant.

  27. See Table 3 in Miyazaki (2013) for annual descriptive statistics for approval rates of referenda.

  28. Financial support for mergers was reviewed nearly annually from 1999 through 2006 in order to spur municipal mergers.

  29. In effect, the national government had devised a plan to restrict the functions of small municipalities, as reported by Prof. Nishio of the Local Government Investigation Committee in 2002 (known as “Nishio shian” in Japanese). Besides, the national government reduced unconditional grants through a series of reforms in intergovernmental transfers during 2004–2006 (“Sanmi Ittai Kaikaku” in Japanese). It also changed the method to calculate grants for the scheme, wherein grants for small municipalities were substantially reduced. Moreover, a questionnaire survey for relevant persons, including mayors, provides evidence that some small municipalities are motivated to consolidate after knowing of the plan (e.g., Workshop on Regional System and Town and Village 2008, p. 40–41).

  30. Akizuki (2001) called this Japanese central-local relationship “controlled decentralization,” under which the central government designs and controls many governmental functions, such as policing and education, by using various channels, such as personnel exchanges between national and local governments and distribution of grants. It is well known that although local expenditure accounts for about 60 % of general government expenditure in Japan, part of the local expenditure is not under the local government’s control, because part of local revenue is provided by the central government. The central government can stipulate usage of a part of local expenditure by law and provides guidance to the local administration (Akizuki 2001; Mochida 2006).

  31. In Japanese, the creation of a new municipality is called “Shinsetsu gappei,” while the absorption of a municipality is called “Hennyu gappei.”

References

  • Akizuki K (2001) Partnership in controlled decentralization: local governments and the ministry of home affairs. In: Muramatsu M, Iqbal F, Kume I (eds) Local government development in post-war Japan. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 63–84

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Spolaore E (1997) On the size and number of nations. Q J Econ 112:1027–1056

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Spolaore E (2003) The size of nations. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Baqir R, Hoxby C (2004) Political jurisdictions in heterogeneous communities. J Polit Econ 112:348–396

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrews M, Duncombe W, Yinger J (2002) Revising economies of size in American education: Are we any closer to a consensus? Econ Educ Rev 21(3):245–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Austin DA (1999) Politics vs. economics: evidence from municipal annexation. J Urban Econ 45:501–532

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley T, Coate S (2003) Centralized vs. decentralized provision of local public goods: a political economy approach. J Public Econ 87:2611–2637

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton P, Roland G (1997) The break-up of nations: a political economy analysis. Q J Econ 112:1057–1089

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brasington D (1999) Joint provision of public goods: the consolidation of school districts. J Public Econ 73:373–393

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brasington D (2003a) Size and school district consolidation: Do opposites attract? Economica 70:673–690

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brasington D (2003b) Snobbery, racism, or mutual distaste: What promotes and hinders cooperation in local public good provision? Rev Econ Stat 85(4):874–883

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brink A (2004) The break-up of municipalities: voting behavior in local referenda. Econ Gov 5:119–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • CLAIR (Council of Local Authorities for International Relations) (2009) Municipal Mergers in Japan, CLAIR Fact Sheet

  • Duncombe W, Yinger J (2007) Does school district consolidation cut costs? Educ Financ Policy 2(4):341–375

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dur R, Staal K (2008) Local public good provision, municipal consolidation, and national transfers. Reg Sci Urban Econ 38:160–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellingsen T (1998) Externalities vs. internalities: a model of political integration. J Public Econ 68:251–268

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferris J, Graddy E (1988) Production choices for local government services. J Urban Aff 10:273–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon N, Knight B (2009) A spatial merger estimator with an application to school district consolidation. J Public Econ 93:752–765

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinnerich BT (2009) Do merging local governments free ride on their counterparts when facing boundary reform? J Public Econ 93:721–728

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirota H (2007) Shichoson no Sentaku Kodo to Gappei Yoin no Kensho (Verification of Municipal Incorporation with Discrete Choice Model). Keikakugyosei 30(4):75–81

    Google Scholar 

  • Johansson E (2003) Intergovernmental grants as a tactical instrument: some empirical evidence from Swedish municipalities. J Public Econ 87:883–915

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konishi S (2003) Shichoson Gappei to Chiho Zaisei Seido, Shichoson no Zaisei Un-ei (Municipal Consolidation, the System of Local Public Finance, and Municipality’s Financial Management). Jichi Kenkyu 79(9):22–49

    Google Scholar 

  • Lockwood B (2002) Distributive politics and the costs of centralization. Rev Econ Stud 69:313–337

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meng C-L, Schmidt P (1985) On the cost of partial observability in the bivariate probit model. Int Econ Rev 25(1):71–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MIC (Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications) (2000) Kokusei Chosa (Population Census of Japan)

  • MIC (2002a–2005a) Shichoson Kessan Jokyo Shirabe (Settlement of Municipality Finances)

  • MIC (2002b–2005b) Shichoson Zei Kazei Jokyo Tou no Shirabe (Taxation of Municipal Taxes)

  • MIC (2005c) White Paper on Local Public Finance

  • MIC (2006a) White Paper on Local Public Finance

  • MIC (2012) White paper on local public finance

  • MIC (2006b) Digital archives of mergers (DAM). (http://www.gappei-archive.soumu.go.jp/)

  • MIC (2010b) Heisei no Gappei ni Tsuite (On Heisei Municipality Consolidation)

  • Miyashita T, Nakazawa K (2009) Gappeigoikeisei Cost no Jissho Bunseki (Empirical Analysis of Cost for Consensus Building). ZaiseiKenkyu 5:254–275

    Google Scholar 

  • Miyazaki T (2006) Kouritsuteki Jichitai ni yoru Houtei Gappei Kyogikai no Secchi (Creation of Merger Conferences by Cost-efficient Municipalities). JCER Econ J 54:20–38

    Google Scholar 

  • Miyazaki T (2013) Municipal consolidation and local government behavior: evidence from japanese voting data on merger referenda. Discussion Paper Series A, No. 588, Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University

  • Mochida N (2001) Taxes and transfers in Japan’s local finances. In: Muramatsu M, Iqbal F, Kume I (eds) Local government development in post-war Japan. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 85–111

    Google Scholar 

  • Mochida N (2006) Local government organization and finance: Japan. Public sector governance and accountability series. World Bank, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson M (1990) Decentralization of the subnational public sector: an empirical analysis of the determinants of local government structure in metropolitan areas in the U.S. South Econ J 57(2):443–457

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nishikawa M (2002) Shichoson Gappei no Seisaku-hyoka (Policy evaluation of municipal consolidation). JCER Econ J 46:61–79

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates W (1972) Fiscal federalism. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development) (2005) Economic surveys: Japan. OECD, Paris

  • Poirier D (1980) Partial observability in bivariate probit models. J Econom 12:209–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reed S (2001) Impersonal Mechanisms and Personal Networks in the Distribution of Central Grants to Local Governments in Japan. In: Muramatsu M, Iqbal F, Kume I (eds) Local Government Development in Post-War Japan. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 112–131

    Google Scholar 

  • Reschovsky A (2007) Compensating local governments for differences in expenditure needs in a horizontal fiscal equalization program. In: Boadway R, Shah A (eds) Intergovernmental fiscal transfers. The World Bank, Washington DC, pp 397–424

    Google Scholar 

  • Sorensen R (2006) Local government consolidations: the impact of political transaction costs. Public Choice 127:75–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weese E (2008) Political mergers as coalition formation: evidence from Japanese municipal amalgamations. Global COE Hi-Stat Discussion Paper Series 017, Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University

  • Workshop on Regional System and Town and Village (2008) Heisei no Gappei wo Meguru Jittai to Hyoka Zenkoku Chosonkai (Evaluation for Heisei Great Municipal Merger). Zenkoku Chosonkai. (http://www.zck.or.jp/teigen/gappei-ma.pdf)

  • Yokomichi K (2007) The development of municipal mergers in Japan. COSLOG Up-to-date documents on local autonomy in Japan No. 1, Council of Local Authorities for International Relations (CLAIR)

Download references

Acknowledgments

I would like to thank Ben Lockwood, Katsuyoshi Nakazawa, Masashi Nishikawa, two anonymous referees, and the seminar participants at the 67th Congress of the International Institute of Public Finance (IIPF) held at Ann Arbor, Michigan, the 2011 Japanese Economic Association Spring Meeting at Kumamoto Gakuen University, the seminar at Doshisha University, and the 67th meeting of the Japanese Institute of Public Finance at Shiga University for their helpful comments. I am also grateful to the editor, Amihai Glazer, for his valuable suggestions toward revising this paper. This work was supported by the JPSP Grant-in-Aid for Young Scientists (B) 22730256 and the Joint Usage and Research Center, Institute of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Takeshi Miyazaki.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 86 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Miyazaki, T. Municipal consolidation and local government behavior: evidence from Japanese voting data on merger referenda. Econ Gov 15, 387–410 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-014-0145-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10101-014-0145-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation