1 Introduction

Vaccination is one of the greatest discoveries of modern medicine. Thanks to vaccines, diseases such as poliomyelitis, tetanus, smallpox, diphtheria, and rubella have been eradicated in many countries. Furthermore, vaccination has recently been shown to reduce the incidence of some other diseases, for example, human papillomavirus (HPV) infection (Takla et al. 2018), meningitis (Buonomo et al. 2022), and some forms of cancer. The public health benefits brought by such discoveries are so important that several countries have even devised mandatory childhood vaccination policiesFootnote 1,Footnote 2 .Committees on Vaccination have been constituted in many countries to plan communication campaigns in favor of vaccination, such as the (STIKO) in Germany by Robert Koch-InstitutFootnote 3 and the European Centre for Disease Prevention and ControlFootnote 4 have done.

However, people often do not perceive the importance of vaccines, either because some of the diseases that were eradicated are no longer visible or because their effects may show up only after long periods. In case a given vaccination is not mandatory, without memory of the damage the related disease can cause, the perceived risks of vaccination among some people have begun to outweigh their perceived benefits (Omer et al. 2009; Buonomo et al. 2013). Some people focus only on the risk of side effects, which for them appears to be extremely high compared to the risk associated with contracting the disease, (Salmon et al. 2006). Furthermore, vaccine efficacy has recently been debated by skeptics who try to spread the idea that vaccines are ineffective and even dangerous (see, e.g., Shim et al. (2013), Carrillo and Lopalco (2012), and Hotez (2017)).

In turn, media, such as magazines, television, the Internet, and social networks, often present news related to vaccines without submitting them to strict verification by scientific and health authorities. Sometimes, they spread alarming news without any foundation, in the worst cases even claiming an association between vaccines and serious diseases. Just to mention, even though Andrew Wakefield’s claim about a causal relation between vaccines and autism was refuted by the scientific community; see Taylor et al. (2014), such a conjecture has caused a decline in vaccination coverage, especially in certain countries.

Due to these fake news, some diseases were taken too lightly and gave rise to the vaccine hesitancy effect; see, e.g., Bozzola et al. (2018) and White et al. (2023). Shim et al., Shim et al. (2013), assert that if the great benefits to society of measles vaccination are to be maintained, the public must be educated about these benefits in order to increase public confidence. When organizing vaccine administration, national health systems must consider many aspects, and in the last decade the issue of correct communication about the vaccination campaign has become crucial. The authors observe that the effectiveness of vaccination programs can be jeopardized by public misperceptions of vaccine risk. They illustrate “the importance of public education on vaccine safety and infection risk to achieve vaccination levels that are sufficient to maintain herd immunity.”

In this paper, we study the effect of a vaccination advertising campaign in supporting countries to increase the coverage of measles, rubella, and other vaccines. The idea arises from a recent report by the World Health Organization (WHO), which underscores the impact of the COVID-19 pandemic on surveillance and immunization efforts. The report highlights that the suspension of immunization services has decreased the estimates of immunization coverage for many infectious diseases. In fact, during the last three years, the COVID-19 pandemic stopped surveillance and immunization efforts, putting many children at risk for preventable diseases. “Approximately 25 million infants missed at least one dose of the measles vaccine through routine immunization in 2021.”Footnote 5 Globally low immunization rates increased the chances of outbreaks and endanger unvaccinated children. The World Health Organization just decided to work towards regional measles elimination by strengthening immunization programs (e.g., Measles and rubella strategic framework: 2021-2030) and implementing effective surveillance systems.

Perceiving the same need for a focused public educational system, this paper aims to formalize in a mathematical context the problem of planning a pro-vax communication campaign to convince people to get vaccinated. In what follows, we assume that the vaccination we are dealing with is not mandatory.

Our research questions are as follows.

  • How does negative word of mouth affect the evolution toward herd immunity?

  • How can the pro-vax communication campaigns of the national health-care system and of pharmaceutical firms speed up such an achievement?

  • How can a proper pro-vaccination campaign sustain the vaccination efficiency of the national health-care system?

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In Sect. 2 we briefly review the literature and position our contribution. In Sect. 3 we introduce our model for a controlled evolution of the unvaccinated population, together with the cost functionals associated with such an attempt. We formalize the problem in a differential game framework. In Sect. 4 we determine the optimal communication strategies that constitute the associated steady-state feedback Nash equilibrium. Section 5 presents some sensitivity analysis of the solution together with interpretations of the results. Section 6 concludes.

2 Brief literature background

A consistent stream of literature tackles the issue of controlling infectious diseases based on epidemic models, in particular, on behavioral Susceptible-Infected-Recovered (SIR) models. In the book Manfredi and d’Onofrio (2013) a vast literature on vaccination and other influences of human behavior on the spread of infectious diseases is presented. A detailed report reviewing models that account for behavioral feedback and / or the spatial / social structure of the population can be found in Wang et al. (2016). More recent publications among the same stream of literature are e.g. d’Onofrio and Manfredi (2020) and Buonomo et al. (2022). An interesting approach to the vaccination problem in the context of game theory is tackled in Shim et al. (2013), where a game-theoretic model of disease transmission and vaccination is formalized as a population game. Here, the game-theoretic epidemiological analysis performed can yield insights into the interplay between anti-vaccine behavior, vaccine coverage, and disease dynamics. More recently in Matusik and Nowakowski (2022) a game-theoretical approach has been used to model the control of COVID-19 transmission, always in the context of SIR dynamics.

The so-called word-of-mouth effect plays a crucial role in the spread of antivax beliefs. Bauch in Bauch (2005) studies the strategic interaction between individuals when they decide whether or not to vaccinate, using an imitation dynamic game. The role of word of mouth in voluntary vaccination planning is presented in Bhattacharyya et al. (2015), where the synergetic feedback between word of mouth and the epidemic dynamics controlled by voluntary vaccination is analyzed. The authors present an epidemiological model with a social learning component that incorporates the reciprocal influence of population groups, as well as the feedback that can occur from the incidence of diseases. They model this social interaction through a game-theoretical framework using the concept of payoff, adapted from applications of Game Theory to Economics.

Just because anti-vax behavior is often associated with word of mouth, rather than with scientific data and information, it seems interesting to tackle the problem not necessarily from an epidemiological point of view but from a sociological point of view. Therefore, the communication approach derived from the theory of dynamic advertising models, described in Huang et al. (2012), suggests a correct communication policy to defeat the spread of the anti-vax movement. In a communication framework, El Ouardighi et al. in El Ouardighi et al. (2016) consider two different types of word of mouth: negative (or adverse) and positive (or favorable) according to the different reactions of satisfied and dissatisfied customers. The authors stress how negative word of mouth is more influential than positive, especially for brands with which potential customers are not familiar, and this could be the case for the vaccine issue.

Within the literature stream based on dynamic advertising models, Grosset and Viscolani (2021) formulate and solve an optimal control problem to determine a provaccination communication campaign that contrasts the effect of antivaccination word of mouth, with the objective of minimizing the care cost induced by unvaccinated people and the cost resulting from the communication campaign. The authors propose an upper bound to the final number of unvaccinated people to guarantee herd immunity. In such a model the programming interval is fixed, while in Grosset and Viscolani (2020) the authors study a variable-final-time optimal control problem to stress the importance of reaching the given herd immunity threshold, rather than reducing costs in a fixed-length programming period.

In Buratto et al. (2020), a model for the aforementioned national health problem is proposed using a linear-quadratic differential game in a finite time horizon. The model aspires to understand how an optimal interaction between the communication campaigns of the healthcare system and of a pharmaceutical firm that produces a given vaccine can help increase vaccination coverage. The healthcare system wants to minimize the number of unvaccinated people at a minimum cost. The pharmaceutical firm aims to maximize its profits while reducing the number of unvaccinated people.

This paper belongs to the last group of models presented above, named Communication models, where the focus is on the communicative approach and considers the “educational plan to vaccination” as a possible communication strategy that can be planned by both the national healthcare system and pharmaceutical firms. References cited above Grosset and Viscolani (2020, 2021), and Buratto et al. (2020)) ssume that the unvaccinated population, affected by negative word of mouth, diverges to infinity if it is not supported by a pro-vaccine campaign. Here, we adopt a more realistic dynamics where the à-régime number of unvaccinated people is increased by the adverse action of anti-vax negative word of mouth and converges to a finite value, which can be deduced from the annual report published by the World Health Organization (WHO).Footnote 6

Moreover, the literature cited above considers only finite-time horizon optimal control problems, while in this paper, being interested in a long-term plan for the provaccination campaign, we consider the plan over an infinite horizon.

We study the interaction between the communication campaigns of the healthcare system and of a pharmaceutical firm that produces a vaccine for a given disease, formulating a differential game played à la Nash. We use the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman approach to determine a Markovian-Nash equilibrium. In recent years, with the introduction of big data solutions, healthcare management can rely on accurate and up-to-date reports. Mobile contact track & trace apps, recently urged by the Covid-19 emergency, provide constant information on the number of vaccinated (and consequently of unvaccinated) individuals.Footnote 7 Therefore, feedback strategies based on the number of unvaccinated are not only credible but also more reliable than Open-Loop ones, as the former are time-consistent. It is commonly known, as reported also in Della-Marca and d’Onofrio (2021), that in health economics, it is preferable, whenever possible, to control a system by means of a feedback-based strategy, which aims to minimize the economic and human burden of some health-related phenomena. On the basis of these considerations, we look for communication strategies that constitute a Markovian Nash equilibrium.

3 The model

We assume that the population to which vaccination is devoted is stationary. The dynamics we analyze describes the evolution of the unvaccinated population, as is done in the related literature cited above (see Grosset and Viscolani (2020, 2021), and Buratto et al. (2020)).

For this purpose, let x(t) be the number of unvaccinated individuals at time t, and let \(x_0\) be its value at the initial time.

The World Health Organization annually publishes data related to global trends and the total number of reported cases of vaccine-preventable diseases (VPD).Footnote 8 In an idealistic vaccination system, the number of unvaccinated should decrease and tend to zero (neglecting people who cannot be vaccinated due to more serious immunodeficences). However, it can be observed from WHO’s data that there is always a significantly high average number of unvaccinated. This residual number of unvaccinated can be attributed to the presence of antivax action. On the other hand, in each time unit, a fixed percentage of the unvaccinated population voluntary gets the vaccine, convinced by peers and networks, or even by the spread of the disease. We can formalize this type of scenario with the following dynamics of the unvaccinated people

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{x}(t)&= w - r x(t). \end{aligned}$$
(1)

The term \(w>0\) represents the constant number of people that at a given time may be considered as new-unvaccinated, because they’ve just entered into the subset of population ought to be vaccinated and did not get the vaccine. The reasons for such a decision can be varied, including the negative information about vaccines and vaccination that no-vax movement spreads throughout a word-of-mouth mechanism. For simplicity, in what follows we will call the parameter w a word-of-mouth parameter.

The parameter \(r>0\) represents the instantaneous vaccination rate. It measures the intensity of vaccination and in some way it describes the efficiency of the national vaccination system: the faster the national healthcare system in the vaccination issue, the higher r. From the dynamics we can observe that the number of unvaccinated increases with w,  however, it decreases due to the effect of spontaneous vaccinations. Unlike in Grosset and Viscolani (2021), where the number of unvaccinated tends to explode in the absence of a communication action, due to negative word of mouth, here we assume, in a more realistic formalization, that the unvaccinated group converges to a finite positive value. Indeed, as t goes to infinity in dynamics (1), the number of unvaccinated tends to the following à-régime level

$$\begin{aligned} {\widehat{x}}_{SS}=\frac{w}{r}. \end{aligned}$$
(2)

This value, which increases in w and decreases in r,  is in any case finite, and it corresponds to the nonnegative residual of unvaccinated people that can be deduced by the annual World Health Organization report.

However, as Wang et al. stress in Wang et al. (2016), there are scenarios in which voluntary vaccination is not sufficient to provide herd immunity. If word of mouth w is too high or the effectiveness of vaccination r is too low, then \({\widehat{x}}_{SS}\) may be too large; far from the level requested for herd immunity. This issue may become too expensive for the national healthcare system to sustain; therefore, a pro-vaccination communication campaign is needed.

In this paper, we formulate a dynamic model assuming to be exactly in the situation in which the negative word of mouth is so high that a pro-vaccination campaign is necessary. Since we are interested in the scenario where communication is necessary, in what follows we will assume that the parameter w is greater than a given threshold, which guarantees nontrivial equilibrium strategies. The value of such a threshold will be specified later in the next section.

We assume that both the national healthcare system (S) and the pharmaceutical firm (F) are independently planning their own communication campaign to promote vaccination. Let \(\phi _S(t)\in U_S\) and \(\phi _F(t)\in U_F\) be the pro-vax advertising efforts of the national healthcare system and the pharmaceutical company, respectively. We assume that feasible communication strategies are non-negative and reasonably bounded. In what follows, we assume that the upper bounds for such strategy functions are sufficiently high. This will permit us to concentrate on the characteristics of non-trivial inner solutions. Let \(\delta _S,\delta _F > 0\) be the effectiveness of the two communication intensities, as in Buratto et al. (2020). The evolution of the unvaccinated is affected by these controls according to the following dynamics

$$\begin{aligned} {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \dot{x}(t)= w - r x(t) - \delta _S \phi _S(t) - \delta _F \phi _F(t), \\ x(0)=x_0. \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(3)

At first glance, we can observe that if the number of unvaccinated x is zero at a given time, then a positive communication effort may drive the state function below zero, and this would not be meaningful. However, it will be proved that under optimal conditions, given our assumption of a significantly high value for the variable w, the positivity of the state function is ensured.

After describing the dynamics, let us focus on the payoff functions of the two players. The national healthcare system and the pharmaceutical firm both seek to minimize their respective costs associated with the number of unvaccinated individuals, along with reducing their communication costs. For any \(t\ge 0,\) we assume the following cost flows for the two players respectively

$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm {C_S(t)}=\frac{\beta }{2}x^2(t)+\frac{\kappa _S}{2}\phi _S^2(t),\qquad \mathrm {C_F}(t)=\theta x(t)+\frac{\kappa _F}{2}\phi _F^2(t) \end{aligned}$$
(4)

For what concerns the costs due to the number of unvaccinated individuals, from the national healthcare system point of view, the number of unvaccinated individuals affects national healthcare costs because a relevant percentage of them need medications and sometimes even hospitalization. While in Grosset and Viscolani (2020, 2021) these costs are assumed to be proportional to the number of unvaccinated people and therefore linear in the variable x, in our model we assume that national healthcare costs are quadratic and convex, formalized by the term \(\frac{\beta }{2}x^2(t)\) (with \(\beta >0),\) to underscore the significant expenses associated with hospital therapy. Furthermore, this assumption highlights the crucial point that vaccine refusal not only puts those who decline vaccination at risk but also increases the chances of disease transmission for people who interact with unvaccinated individuals. A similar quadratic assumption for national health system costs due to the number of unvaccinated has also been considered in Buratto et al. (2020), where a linear-quadratic differential game is formulated and solved, although in a finite time horizon.

From the pharmaceutical firm point of view, the number of unvaccinated affects the revenue of the pharmaceutical firm, although in a different way. Assuming \(\theta >0\) to be the unit profit of a given vaccine, the consequent missed revenue for each unsold vaccine is here formalized as the linear cost \(\theta x(t).\)

Finally, both players sustain the communication costs associated to their pro-vax advertising efforts, here assumed to have the following quadratic and convex formulation \(\frac{k_S}{2}\phi _S^2(t)\) and \(\frac{k_F}{2}\phi _F^2(t)\) (with \(k_S>0\) and \(k_F>0)\) for the healthcare system and the firm respectively.

All the models cited above neglect the cost of vaccination, as we also do; nevertheless, few papers in the related literature evaluate vaccination costs; among them, we mention the real option approach used in Favato et al. (2013).

We consider the problem over an infinite horizon. In such a setting, taking into account the dynamics (3), and discounting the costs \(C_S(t)\) and \(C_F(t)\) in (4), we formulate the following differential game played à la NashFootnote 9

healthcare System (S)

 

pharmaceutical Firm (F)

\(\displaystyle {\min _{\phi _S\in \ U_S}\int _0^{+\infty }\!\! e^{-\rho t}\left( \frac{\beta }{2}x^2(t)+\frac{\kappa _S}{2}\phi _S^2(t)\right) dt}\)

 

\(\displaystyle {\min _{\phi _F\in \ U_F}\int _0^{+\infty }\!\! e^{-\rho t}\left( \theta x(t)+\frac{\kappa _F}{2}\phi _F^2(t)\right) dt}\)

$$\begin{aligned} {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \dot{x}(t)= w - r x(t) - \delta _S \phi _S(t) - \delta _F \phi _F(t), \\ x(0)=x_0. \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(5)

The table below collects the meaning of the parameters:

\(\rho\)

discount rate (\(\rho >0\))

\(\beta\)

health care and social cost (\(\beta >0\))

\(\theta\)

missed profit due to each unsold vaccine (\(\theta >0\))

\(\kappa _S,\kappa _F\)

communication cost parameters (\(\kappa _S,\kappa _F>0\))

w

word-of-mouth coefficient (\(w>0\))

r

instantaneous constant vaccination rate,

\(\delta _S,\delta _F\)

pro-vax communication effectiveness (\(\delta _S,\delta _F>0\))

It is interesting to observe the asymmetry of the game due to the different types of costs associated with the unvaccinated group. This asymmetry will emerge in the different forms of the value functions of the two players and, consequently, in the equilibrium strategies of (S) and (F), respectively. The problem above is formulated over an infinite horizon and is autonomous (because there is no other explicit time dependence in its formulation, apart from the discount factors). Therefore, we are interested in looking for a stationary solution. Stationarity means that each player’s strategy is determined as a function of the state variable only: \(\phi ^*_j(x)\) \(j\in \{S,F\}\) as stated in Dockner et al. (2000), p.210.

4 The solution (Markovian nash equilibrium)

We are interested in feedback advertising strategies based on the number of unvaccinated individuals, so we look for a Markovian Nash equilibrium that, being the game autonomous, turns out to be subgame perfect (Dockner et al. 2000, p.105).

Proposition 1

The Markovian Nash Equilibrium Feedback strategies that represent the pro-vax communication strategies are

$$\begin{aligned}&\phi ^*_S(x)= \frac{1}{\delta _S}(\eta -(\rho +r ))\left[ x+\left( w-\frac{\delta ^2_F\theta }{\kappa _F\eta }\right) /\eta \right] , \end{aligned}$$
(6)
$$\begin{aligned}&\phi ^*_F(x)=\frac{\delta _F\theta }{\kappa _F\eta }, \end{aligned}$$
(7)

where

$$\begin{aligned} \eta&= \sqrt{\left[ \frac{\rho }{2}+r \right] ^2+\beta \frac{\delta _S^2}{\kappa _S}}+\frac{\rho }{2}. \end{aligned}$$
(8)

Proof

See Appendix 1. \(\square\)

It can be immediately observed that \(\phi _F^*(\cdot )\) is strictly positive (being \(\delta _F, \theta , k_F>0,\) and \(\eta>\rho +r>\rho >0\)). Furthermore, \(\phi _F^*(\cdot )\) does not depend on x,  therefore it constitutes a degenerate feedback strategy. It represents the constant positive communication contribution of the pharmaceutical firm to contrast the antivax action.Footnote 10 From now on, we will denote it by \(\phi ^*_F.\) As an economic interpretation, since the firm is interested in minimizing its missed profits due to unvaccinated, its optimal communication strategy is adopted at a positive constant rate, independently of the number of unvaccinated individuals.

Remark 1

For what concerns the communication strategy of the national healthcare system \(\phi _S^*(\cdot )\), it is easy to prove that \(\phi ^*_S(x)>0\) for all feasible x,  since \(\eta>\rho +r >0.\) Observing that if \(w>\frac{\delta _F^2 \theta }{\kappa _F \eta },\) then \(\phi ^*_S(x)>0\) for all \(x\ge 0,\) we can conclude that if the negative word of mouth is so high that it compromises herd immunity, as assumed in the problem formulation, then the national healthcare system needs to support the firm’s pro-vaccination campaign.

4.1 Steady state

These kinds of problems are known in the literature as “Discounted Autonomous Infinite Horizon Models” (DAM), (Grass et al. 2008, p.159). The main computational effort to solve optimal control models of this type is calculating the stable manifolds of the occurring saddles. Let us substitute the optimal strategies (6) and (7) in the dynamics of the unvaccinated individuals, then we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{x} (t) = w - r x(t)-\delta _S\phi ^*_S(x) -\delta _F\phi ^*_F= -(\eta -\rho )x(t)+\frac{(\rho + r)}{\eta }\left( w -\frac{\delta _F^2 \theta }{{\kappa _F \eta }}\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(9)

Proposition 2

The steady-state number of unvaccinated people, while adopting the optimal pro-vax communications turns out to be

$$\begin{aligned} x_{SS} = \frac{(\rho +r )\left( w-\frac{\delta ^2_F\theta }{\kappa _F\eta }\right) }{\eta (\eta -\rho )}. \end{aligned}$$
(10)

Proof

Differentiating the dynamics in (9), we obtain the optimal state trajectory

$$\begin{aligned} x^*(t)=x_{SS}+(x_0-x_{SS})e^{-(\eta -\rho )t}=x_{SS}(1- e^{-(\eta -\rho )t})+x_0 e^{-(\eta -\rho )t}. \end{aligned}$$
(11)

It is easy to verify that \(x^*(t)\ge 0\) for any starting point \(x_0\ge 0\) and, since \(\eta > \rho ,\) the state converges to the stable positive steady state \(x_{SS}\) in (10). \(\square\)

As expected, the steady-state level of unvaccinated individuals under the actions of pro-vax communication campaigns of the two involved players increases with negative word of mouth w,  and it is lower than the à-régime unvaccinated level observed in (2) without pro-vax communications. In fact, for any set of values of the problem parameters, it holds

$$\begin{aligned} x_{SS} \le {\widehat{x}}_{SS}=\frac{w}{r}. \end{aligned}$$
(12)

As a result, in case the word of mouth is too high, then the joint effects of the pro-vax communication campaigns (6) and (7) may contribute to lower the number of unvaccinated and to bring it down to the stationary level (10). This will help to reach herd immunity.

5 Sensitivity analysis and simulations

In the previous section, we obtained the analytical form for the strategies that constitute the stationary Markovian Nash equilibrium of the pro-vax communication game and the associated steady-state level of unvaccinated people. The simple dependence of the solution on some of the parameters that characterize the problem allows us to perform a sensitivity analysis.

In Table 1, we report the existing monotonicity properties, when analytically computable, of the equilibrium strategies at the steady state, of the steady state level of the unvaccinated, and of the optimal costs for the two players. For the reader’s convenience, since the optimal solution contains the constant \(\eta ,\) in the first column of the table, the dependencies of the constant \(\eta\) on all the analyzed parameters are also included. The arrows indicate either increasing monotonicity (\(\nearrow\) ) or decreasing monotonicity (\(\searrow\)), while the lines “−" mean constant behavior.

Table 1 Sensitivity analysis with respect to main parameters

Impact of Word-of-Mouth Effectiveness w (Table 1)

Parameter w takes into account the word-of-mouth effects on the evolution of the unvaccinated people. Here we assume, as stated in the previous section, that the negative word of mouth is so high that it requires nonzero pro-vax communications, more precisely \(w>\frac{\delta _F^2 \theta }{\kappa _F \eta }\).

The effect of the negative word of mouth w drives the national healthcare system to increase its pro-vax communication strategy (\(\phi ^*_S\)), with increased associated costs. Moreover, as expected, the steady state number of unvaccinated (\(x_{SS}\)) increases in w. These results are in line with the ones obtained in Buratto et al. (2020), where the final level of unvaccinated people x(T) is increasing in the word-of-mouth parameter. Another expected result is that both players have increased costs as anti-vax word of mouth increases. However, it becomes interesting to note that the optimal pharmaceutical strategy \(\phi ^*_F\) is not dependent on w;  the firm conducts its communication campaign independently of word of mouth because its cost is not an effective loss, but a missed income.


Impact of vaccine unit profit \(\theta\) (Table 1)

Parameter \(\theta\) represents the unit profit of a vaccine and is considered as the virtual cost of each unsold vaccine. From Table 1 we can observe that the higher the unit profit, the higher the strategy communication of the firm (\(\phi ^*_F\)) and consequently its cost. With a higher pro-vax campaign, the steady state level of unvaccinated individuals (\(x_{SS}\)) decreases. At the same time, the national healthcare system can count on the firm’s action, so, as strategic substitutes do, it can reduce its communication campaign (\(\phi ^*_S\)) and, therefore, its total cost.


Impact of communication effectiveness and marginal costs (\(\delta _{F},\) \(\kappa _{F}\)) of the firm (Table 1)

It is straightforward to prove that \(\phi ^*_F\) increases in \(\delta _{F}\) and decreases in \(\kappa _{F}\): The more effective (or less costly) the firm pro-vax campaign, the more intensive it will be. This result is typical for dynamic advertising models Huang et al. (2012): each optimal communication strategy increases in its corresponding communication efficacy and decreases in its corresponding marginal cost. Moreover, since both strategies act jointly to decrease the number of unvaccinated people, they are strategic substitutes, so that each optimal communication strategy decreases with the communication efficacy of the other player and increases with the communication marginal cost of the other player. In particular, \(\phi ^*_S\) is decreasing in \(\delta _{F}\): The more effective the firm’s pro-vax campaign, the less the national healthcare system needs to implement its own pro-vax communication. Finally, the steady state (\(x_{SS}\)) computed in (10) decreases in \(\delta _{F},\) while it increases in the marginal cost \(\kappa _{F}.\)


Impact of communication strategies to communication effectiveness and marginal costs (\(\delta _{S},\) \(\kappa _{S}\)) of national health-care system (Table 2)

Let us observe in Table (2) that \(\eta\) is increasing in \(\delta _{S}\) and decreasing in \(\kappa _{S},\) therefore \(\phi ^*_F\), which is decreasing in \(\eta\) (see (7)), turns out to be decreasing in \(\delta _{S}\) and increasing in \(\kappa _{S}.\) Furthermore, \(\phi ^*_S\) turns out to be decreasing in \(\kappa _{S},\) while no kind of monotonicity nor regularity can be verified with respect to \(\delta _{S},\) (a “no” appears in the corresponding cell of Table 2).

Table 2 Sensitivity analysis with respect to \(\delta _S\) and \(\kappa _S\)

Sensitivity of communication strategies to social cost \(\beta\) and vaccination rate r (Table 3)

The parameter \(\beta\) represents the social cost for the national healthcare system. Analytical results in Table 3 highlight how a severe social cost motivates the healthcare system to increase its pro-vaccination campaign, thus allowing the pharmaceutical firm to reduce its own.

Table 3 Sensitivity analysis with respect to \(\beta\) and r

The parameter r represents the vaccination rate, in other words the efficiency of the national vaccination system. Analytical results highlight how an increase in the efficiency of vaccination in the national healthcare system allows the pharmaceutical firm to lighten its own communication campaign. On the other hand, no kind of monotonicity can be analytically proved in the national health-care system communication effort with respect to r.


Numerical analysis of the steady state

The dependence of the steady state \(x_{SS}\) with respect to the parameters \(\delta _{S},\) \(k_S,\) \(\beta ,\) and r cannot be proved analytically, therefore, we performed some numerical simulations fixing, for each analysis, \(n-1\) parameters and letting one parameter vary within its feasible values (such as to guarantee non-zero advertising strategies).Footnote 11 In the following Figs. 1, 2, 3, 4, it is evident, as analytically proven in (12), that in the long run, the steady-state number of unvaccinated people while adopting pro-vaccination communication (\(x_{SS}\) - solid lines) is smaller compared to the values à-régime without such communication policies (\(\widehat{x}_{SS}\) - dotdashed lines).

All the simulations conducted demonstrate a consistent pattern, specifically a quasi-concave shape characterized by an initial convex-concave increase followed by a subsequent decrease. We can interpret these results by noting the presence of a threshold effect: Only sufficiently high values of the parameter with respect to which the analysis is carried out make it possible for the national health-care system to reduce the number of unvaccinated individuals to the extent necessary to achieve herd immunity.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Steady state \(x_{SS}\) w.r.t. \(\delta _{S}\) (\(w= 0.1, \theta = 0.1, \kappa _S=4, \delta _F=0.6, \kappa _F=0.8, \rho =0.05, \beta =0.3, r=0.1\))

Fig. 2
figure 2

Steady state \(x_{SS}\) w.r.t. \(\kappa _{S}\) (\(w= 0.1, \theta = 0.1, \delta _S=0.6, \delta _F=0.6, \kappa _F=0.8, \rho =0.05, \beta =0.3, r=0.1\))

Fig. 3
figure 3

Steady state \(x_{SS}\) w.r.t. \(\beta\) (\(w= 0.1, \theta = 0.1, \delta _S=0.6, \kappa _S=4,\delta _F=0.6, \kappa _F=0.8, \rho =0.05, r=0.1\))

Fig. 4
figure 4

Steady state \(x_{SS}\) w.r.t. r (\(w= 0.1, \theta = 0.1, \delta _S=0.6, \kappa _S=4,\delta _F=0.6, \kappa _F=0.8, \rho =0.05, \beta = 0.3)\)

It should be noted in Fig. 4 that the dotdashed line, representing the à-régime unvaccinated level \({\widehat{x}}_{SS}\) without the pro-vax communications, is not constant (as the corresponding dotdashed lines in the previous figures) because \({\widehat{x}}_{SS},\) defined in (2), decreases in r. Furthermore, the gap between the two lines is large in correspondence to small values of r. This permits to conclude that if the national healthcare system is characterized by a low vaccination rate, then investing in effective and targeted communication strategies becomes crucial in order to significantly slow down the number of unvaccinated individuals and mitigate the potential consequences.

6 Conclusion

Vaccination can reduce the incidence of many diseases, but unfortunately, a negative word of mouth based on fake news recently caused a decline in vaccination coverage in many countries. This phenomenon has increased the residual level of unvaccinated people reported each year by the World Health Organisation. In this paper, we tackle the problem of planning a pro-vaccination communication campaign to convince hesitant individuals to get vaccinated, so as to reduce the residual level of unvaccinated people.

We formulate and solve an asymmetric differential game model over an infinite horizon. Two players are involved in the provaccination communication campaign: the national healthcare system and a pharmaceutical firm. The Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman approach is used to determine the optimal communication strategies that constitute a Markovian-Nash equilibrium for the game. The two players act as strategic substitutes; the smaller the healthcare system campaign, the higher the firm’s one. Sensitivity analyzes are performed with respect to the parameters of the problem to study their impact on the equilibrium strategies and steady-state solutions.

Let us answer the research questions declared in the Introduction: Our model confirms that the national healthcare system needs to increase its investment in vaccine communication to contrast the effect of negative antivax word of mouth and to aim at herd immunity. On the other hand, the firm’s pro-vaccine communication campaign is not affected by negative word of mouth.

The proposed model also includes the vaccination rate as an index that characterizes the efficiency of the national healthcare system. As far as we are aware, such a parameter is not taken into account in the related literature. Our results show that immunization can be obtained either by increasing vaccination efficiency, i.e., vaccinating at a high rate, or implementing a well-planned pro-vaccination communication campaign. These results emphasize the importance of the “Immunization Agenda 2030 Measles & Rubella Partnership” \((M \& RP)\)Footnote 12 led by the American Red Cross, United Nations Foundation, Centers for Disease Control and Prevention (CDC), Gavi, the Vaccines Alliance, the Bill and Melinda French Gates Foundation, UNICEF and WHO, to achieve the IA2030 measles and rubella specific goals.

These results also confirm the importance of national healthcare management in maintaining a sufficiently high vaccination rate or, at least, in designing an efficient provaccination campaign.

Different extensions of this work can be envisioned. The first considers the game played à la Stackelberg, where the leader may be the national healthcare system and the follower the pharmaceutical company. A specific analysis of the cases where the optimal communication strategy can turn out to be zero is an idea that deserves investigation in order to take into account the various types of costs that the national healthcare system must bear.

The important role that parameter r plays in the results may suggest considering the vaccination rate as a decision variable to be optimally set by the national healthcare system together with the communication campaign for vaccination.

It can be interesting to analyze the stochastic evolution of the number of unvaccinated people. This goal could be obtained by introducing a stochastic effect in communication campaigns and changing the ordinary differential equation (3) into a stochastic one (see Wang et al. 2016).